Download The Quantity Theory of Money (review) Page 1 of 2

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Inflation wikipedia , lookup

Steady-state economy wikipedia , lookup

Business cycle wikipedia , lookup

Fiscal multiplier wikipedia , lookup

Monetary policy wikipedia , lookup

Virtual economy wikipedia , lookup

Modern Monetary Theory wikipedia , lookup

Nouriel Roubini wikipedia , lookup

Transformation in economics wikipedia , lookup

Real bills doctrine wikipedia , lookup

Deflation wikipedia , lookup

Đổi Mới wikipedia , lookup

Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup

Quantitative easing wikipedia , lookup

Money wikipedia , lookup

Nominal rigidity wikipedia , lookup

Non-monetary economy wikipedia , lookup

Japanese asset price bubble wikipedia , lookup

Helicopter money wikipedia , lookup

Money supply wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Monetary and Fiscal Policy
Monetary Policy: The Mainstream
The Quantity Theory of Money (review)
Page 1 of 2
So I just bought some groceries and I got this dollar in change and it says Lucy on it. Now I have no idea who Lucy is,
but Lucy, wherever she may be, has made me think about the fact that any given dollar bill gets spent and re-spent
and spent again in the economy in the process of our goods and services changing hands. It makes me think about
the relationship between money and real goods and services. What’s the connection and this is really an important
question because it’s at the heart of the question of whether the Fed can really influence the economy or not. Here’s
the question. What’s the relationship between paper money, which is nominal, that is, imaginary, and real goods and
services, that is, stuff that we actually buy at the store that satisfies our wants and needs. Is there a connection
between the nominal economy, the money economy and the real economy, and if so, what is it?
Well, we’re going to start right now with a very pessimistic look at this relationship and this comes from the classical
economists, the heirs of Adam Smith. The classical economists are the people who gave us supply and demand
diagrams and prices that adjust instantly to clear markets. In the view of the classical economists, there is no
relationship between the nominal economy and the real economy. Money is neutral. If you increase the money
supply, all you do is increase the price level; you don’t change the real quantity of goods and services. You don’t
change the standard of living. You don’t change employment or output or investment or any of the real variables in
the economy. All you do is increase prices proportionally. Let’s see where the classical economists got that
conclusion.
We go back to this equation that explains the relationship between money, prices and real output in the economy.
This is called the quantity equation. And the quantity equation is quite intuitive. It says that all the shopping that’s
done in our economy, the gross domestic product has got to be paid for somehow with the money supply. Whenever
you go shopping, you pay for whatever you get with cash or checks and that’s the money supply. Now the money
supply in our economy is 1.4 trillion dollars and the gross domestic product is about 13 trillion dollars. That
means that every dollar bill circulating in our economy on average is being spent and re-spent nine times during the
year to make this equation balance. All the shopping has to be paid for and since the money supply is less than the
gross domestic product, that means dollars are spent and re-spent, and the rate of re-spending is called velocity.
Well, the classical economists said, “Look, consider this reasoning. If the velocity of money is constant, then any
increase in the money supply shows up as either an increase in the price level or an increase in real output.”
However, real output is governed by the speed limit of the economy, that is, there’s full employment output and if you
try to have more output than full employment, prices go right up and if you try to have less employment than full
output, then you’ve got slack in the economy and wages and prices fall. So if you believe that wages and prices
adjust instantly to keep supply and demand in balance, if you're a classical Adam Smith schooled economist who
believes that prices do all the work in the economy adjusting up and down to make supply and demand balance, then
you believe that any change in the money supply is going to immediately feed in to a change in prices with no change
in the real economy. This is what’s meant by the statement “money is neutral.” If we say that money is neutral, we’re
speaking from a classical point of view. Increasing the money supply by 10 percent only increases the price level by
10 percent with no change in real output. Nothing changes. Output, investment, employment, all that stuff that we
really care about, the whole real economy, the economy of goods and services remains unchanged. The change in
the money supply influences only nominal variables. This is what’s called the classical dichotomy. The world of
money is completely separate from the world of goods and services, that is, the real economy is disconnected from
the monetary economy. Now that’s a very extreme position and most economists nowadays believe that changes in
the money supply, at least in the short run, can influence output, as well as prices. But in the long run, the classical
position holds, that is, even the models that we use nowadays that allow some latitude for money to affect output, in
the long run all of the affect goes into a change in prices and we’ll see that shortly.
But first, let me give you an example of what a timed series would look like following a change in the money supply.
Suppose we’re in a world where the money supply can have an influence on output in the short run. And this is
certainly the case, I mean, in 1992 when the Federal Reserve had encouraged banks to lend more money to
businesses and end the credit crunch that followed the banking crisis of the 80’s. What happened was interest rates
fell and businesses began borrowing and beefing up their capital stock, building more factories and buying more
equipment. So in the short run with the increase in money supply, there was an increase in output. Here’s what it
Monetary and Fiscal Policy
Monetary Policy: The Mainstream
The Quantity Theory of Money (review)
Page 2 of 2
looked like. The Fed was clipping along here with the money supply at a fixed rate and notice here I'm using
movement along the horizontal axis to indicate the passage of time. So time passes as this line flows to the right.
And here we are with the Fed making the decision to increase the money supply, let’s say by 40 percent. So the Fed
increases the money supply and this new money supply just clips along for the rest of time. Well, what’s going to
happen in the economy? What would really happen is that output would begin to increase because of the availability
of credit. Businesses can borrow easier, interest rates are lower and output increases, but then at some point prices
begin to increase and when they do, the demand for money increases and with the increase in demand for money,
interest rates rise, people stop spending as much, consumers don’t like the higher prices because it shrinks the real
value of their wealth and foreigners stop buying our stuff because other goods from other countries are less
expensive. So the rise in prices then choke output back to its full employment level and output goes along. There’s
been a temporary blip here, a little stimulus to the economy from the monetary policy, but nothing enduring. In fact,
what happens is prices clip along at their regular rate and then with the increase in money supply, prices begin rising
and they rise until they get to their new level which is going to be proportionally equal to the increase in the money
supply. So if the money supply goes up by 40 percent, then in the long run prices are also going to rise by exactly the
same amount, 40 percent, and output is going to be unchanged. That’s because output in the long run has to respect
the speed limit and then if we’re above the speed limit, prices are going to rise until we’ve dropped back to the speed
limit as we’ve seen in our other models.
So how long does this process take? How much of an increase in output are we going to get? Listen, even if it
doesn’t last forever, it’s better than nothing, right? Can monetary policy have an affect in the short run even if it can’t
have an affect in the long run? Well, that depends. It depends on quickly people digest the future. If people are
forward looking, forming rational expectations of what’s to come, they’re not going to be fooled at all. This increase in
the money supply, they know, if going to very quickly create inflation, in fact, they may even act in anticipation by
raising their prices now. They say, “Oh-oh, money supply up 40 percent, that means prices are going up 40 percent.
I better raise my prices now.” Labor unions negotiate for higher wages, people try to raise their prices so they’re not
caught behind with their rivals raising the prices before them and what we might get is an instantaneous adjustment of
prices with no period of higher income at all. This is the extreme view in which monetary policy can have no effect,
not even in the short run. If expectations are rational, we’re more likely to have the case here represented by the
dotted lines where all the adjustment is instantly on the side of prices with no change in real output at all.
So back to our original question. Can money make a difference in the real economy? Can a change in the money
supply influence output, employment and investment? And the answer is it depends. In the long run clearly not. The
nominal economy in the long run influences only the nominal economy. In the short run, however, it’s possible that
only to the extent that people do not perfectly digest the future, don’t perfectly change their behavior in response to
what they see coming to the extent that they do, money has no affect at all. It’s perfectly neutral. But to the extent
that people are fooled, they’re slow to change their expectations, money can in the short run have an effect on the real
economy.