Download THE “UNORTHODOX” MONETARY POLICY OF THE CENTRAL

Document related concepts

Foreign-exchange reserves wikipedia , lookup

Bank for International Settlements wikipedia , lookup

International monetary systems wikipedia , lookup

Currency intervention wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
 THE “UNORTHODOX” MONETARY POLICY OF
THE CENTRAL BANK OF THE REPUBLIC OF
TURKEY:
DOES IT WORK?
Master Thesis
BASAK BARCIN
Supervised by Mr Evren Ors
September 2012
1 BURSİYERE AİT BİLGİLER
Ad / Soyad
Referans Numarası
BAŞAK BARÇIN
Sözleşme Numarası
Sektör (Kamu, Üniversite veya Özel
Sektör)
JM -148EN
TR2009/0135.0202/054
ÜNİVERSİTE
Bursiyerin Bağlı Olduğu Kurum / Birim /
GALATASARAY ÜNİVERSİTESİ /
İli
EKONOMİ / İSTANBUL
Bursiyerin Bağlı Olduğu Kurumdaki
Ünvanı
Öğrenim Gördüğü Dil
ÖĞRENCİ
İNGİLİZCE
Çalışma Alanı (İlgili Müktesebat Başlığı.
Örn: Çevre, Ulaştırma, vb.)
E-posta (Birden fazla belirtilebilir.)
FİNANSAL HİZMETLER
[email protected]
JEAN MONNET BURS PROGRAMI KAPSAMINDA ÖĞRENİM GÖRÜLEN
PROGRAMA AİT BİLGİLER
Öğrenim Görülen Akademik Yıl
2011 – 2012
(Örn: 2009 – 2010, 2010 – 2011)
Üniversite
HEC PARIS
Ülke / Şehir
FRANSA, PARİS
Fakülte / Bölüm
HEC PARIS / FİNANS BÖLÜMÜ
Programın Adı
MSc in Finance (Business Track) / Masters
(Örn: LLM in European Law, Msc. in
in International Finance
Economics vb.)
Programın Türü (MA, MSc, kısa süreli
MSc
araştırma programı, vs.)
Programın Başlangıç / Bitiş Tarihleri
07/09/2011 – 31/08/2012
Öğrenim Süresi (ay)
12 ay
“THE “UNORTHODOX” MONETARY
Tez / Araştırma Çalışmasının Başlığı
POLICY OF THE CENTRAL BANK OF
2 THE REPUBLIC OF TURKEY:
DOES IT WORK?
Danışmana / Baş
Araştırmacıya Ait
Bilgiler
Ad / Soyad
EVREN ORS
E-posta
[email protected]
3 INFORMATION ABOUT THE SCHOLAR
Name / Surname
Reference No.
BASAK BARCIN
Contract No.
Sector (Public, University or Private
Sector)
Scholar’s Affiliation / Department / City
JM – 148EN
GALATASARAY UNIVERSITY /
ECONOMICS / ISTANBUL
STUDENT
Language of Instruction
ENGLISH
E.g. Environment, Transportation, etc.)
E-mail (More than one e-mail might be
specified.)
02/054
UNIVERSITY
Scholar’s Title
Field of Study (Related Acquis Chapter.
TR2009/0135.02 –
FINANCIAL SERVICES
basak [email protected]
INFORMATION ABOUT THE EDUCATION PROGRAMME
Academic Year
2011 - 2012
(e.g. 2009 – 2010, 2010 – 2011)
University
HEC PARIS
Country / City
FRANCE / PARIS
Faculty / Department
HEC PARIS / FINANCE DEPARTMENT
Name of the Programme
MSc in Finance (Business Track) / Masters
(e.g. LLM in European Law, Msc. in
in International Finance
Economics vb.)
Type of the Programme (MA, MSc, short
MSc
study, etc.)
Start / End Dates of the Programme
07/09/2011 – 31/08/2012
Duration of Education (months)
12 MONTHS
THE “UNORTHODOX” MONETARY
Title of the Dissertation / Research Study
POLICY OF THE CENTRAL BANK OF
THE REPUBLIC OF TURKEY:
4 DOES IT WORK?
Information about the
Advisor / Principal
Researcher
Name / Surname
EVREN ORS
E-mail
[email protected]
5 TEZ/ARAŞTIRMA RAPORU ONAY SAYFASI
Başlığı
THE “UNORTHODOX” MONETARY POLICY OF THE CENTRAL BANK OF THE
REPUBLIC OF TURKEY:
DOES IT WORK?
olan ve
BAŞAK BARÇIN
tarafından sunulmuş olan tezi/araştırma raporunu inceledim ve kabul edilmeye değer
buldum.
24/10/2012
[Tez danışmanının ya da baş araştırmacının Adı ve Soyadı]
[İmza]
Prof. Evren Ors
HEC PARIS
6 THESIS/RESEARCH REPORT APPROVAL PAGE
I have examined the dissertation/research report entitled
THE “UNORTHODOX” MONETARY POLICY OF THE CENTRAL BANK OF THE
REPUBLIC OF TURKEY:
DOES IT WORK?
presented by
BASAK BARCIN
and hereby certify that it is worthy of acceptance.
24/10/2012
[Name and Surname of the thesis advisor or principal researcher]
[Signature]
Prof. Evren Ors
HEC PARIS
7 TABLE OF CONTENTS
LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS ........................................................................................ 9
LIST OF FIGURES ...................................................................................................... 10
LIST OF TABLES ........................................................................................................ 10
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS ......................................................................................... 11
ÖZET ............................................................................................................................. 12
ABSTRACT................................................................................................................... 13
INTRODUCTION ........................................................................................................ 14
1. CENTRAL BANKS AND MONETARY POLICY ............................................ 15
1.1. CENTRAL BANKS ........................................................................................... 16
1.1.1. Functions ...................................................................................................... 16
1.1.2. Objectives ..................................................................................................... 17
1.1.3. Central Bank Independence ......................................................................... 21
1.2. MONETARY POLICY ...................................................................................... 25
1.2.1. Goals of Monetary Policy ............................................................................ 25
1.2.2. Monetary Policy Tools ................................................................................. 29
1.2.3. The Conduct of Monetary Policy: Choosing and Using the Right Monetary
Policy Instrument .................................................................................................... 31
1.2.4. Transmission of Monetary Policy through the Banking System .................. 34
2. MONETARY POLICY STRATEGIES OF THE CENTRAL BANK OF THE
REPUBLIC OF TURKEY ........................................................................................... 37
2.1. MONETARY POLICY APPLICATION BETWEEN 1980 – 2010 .................. 37
2.2. THE UNORTHODOX MONETARY POLICY IN APPLICATION: 2010 PRESENT ................................................................................................................... 58
2.3. EFFECTS AND OUTCOMES OF THE UNORTHODOX MONETARY
POLICY ...................................................................................................................... 68
3. EVALUATION OF THE CBRT’S UNORTHODOX MONETARY POLICY . 80
3.1. GLOBAL EVALUATİON OF THE POLİCY PERFORMANCE ....................................... 81
3.2. EMPİRİCAL RESEARCH: INTERVİEWS ................................................................... 85
3.3. CRİTİCAL ANALYSİS OF THE CBRT’S UNORTHODOX MONETARY POLİCY ......... 93
CONCLUSION ............................................................................................................. 98
BIBLIOGRAPHY ....................................................................................................... 100
8 LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
BRSA: Banking Regulation and Supervision Agency
CAD: Current Account Deficit
CBRT: Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey
ECB: European Central Bank
EM: Emerging Markets
Fed: US Federal Reserve
FX: Foreign Exchange
GDP: Gross Domestic Product
GNP: Gross National Product
MPC: Monetary Policy Committee
MTP: Medium-term Program
OMO: Open Market Operations
R&D: Research and Development
QE: Quantitative Easing
TL: Turkish Lira
9 LIST OF FIGURES
Figure 1: Weight of Central Bank Objectives in Central Bank Laws ................................................... 18 Figure 2: Monetary Policy Objectives of Central Banks ....................................................................... 19 Figure 3: Correlation Between Average Inflation and Central Bank Independence (Alesina and
Summers, 1993, p155) .......................................................................................................................... 22 Figure 4: Correlation Between Average Real GNP growth and Central Bank Independence
(Alesina and Summers, 1993, p156) ..................................................................................................... 23 Figure 5: 2002-2005 Inflation Targets and Realizations ....................................................................... 54 Figure 6: Capital Flows to Emerging Markets ...................................................................................... 57 Figure 7: Accumulated Foreign Flows to Turkish Equity & Debt Markets .......................................... 59 Figure 8: Current Account Balance ....................................................................................................... 60 Figure 9: Turkey’s CAD as a % of GDP ............................................................................................... 60 Figure 10: Policy Rates and TL Required Reserve Ratios .................................................................... 62 Figure 11: Main Sources of Current Account Deficit Finance .............................................................. 63 Figure 12: Interest Rates and CPI Expectations in Turkey ................................................................... 64 Figure 13: Transmission Mechanism of the Unorthodox Monetary Policy .......................................... 65 Figure 14: Market O/N & Policy Rates ................................................................................................. 66 Figure 15: Market Liquidity .................................................................................................................. 68 Figure 16: Total Loan Growth Rates .................................................................................................... 70 Figure 17: CBRT Reserves ................................................................................................................... 72 Figure 18: Contribution of Consumption in Growth ............................................................................. 75 Figure 19: Performance of TL & EM Currencies vs. USD since August 2011 .................................... 79 Figure 20: Credit Growth in Turkey ..................................................................................................... 80 Figure 21: Annual CAD Level of Turkey (mn USD) ........................................................................... 82 Figure 22: Funding of the CAD (mn USD) ........................................................................................... 83 Figure 23: Annual Inflation ................................................................................................................... 84 Figure 24: Inflation Expectations .......................................................................................................... 85 Figure 25: Reserve Requirements and Open Market Operations (OMO) (mn TL) ............................... 95 LIST OF TABLES
Table 1: Macro-Economic Data for Turkey between 1980 and 1988 ................................................... 41 Table 2: Macro-Economic Data for Turkey between 1989 and 1994 ................................................... 44 Table 3: Macro-Economic Data for the 1995-1999 Period in Turkey ................................................... 48 Table 4: Macro-Economic Targets of Transition to Strong Economy Program and Realizations ........ 51 Table 5: Inflation and Growth Figures Realized Between 2005 and 2009 ............................................ 55 10 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
I would like to thank my academic supervisor Mr Evren Ors for his guidance, support
and encouragement during this research. I would specially like to thank the Jean
Monnet Scholarship Programme, and also the Turkish Ministry for European Union
Affairs for their exceptional support during my master’s education at HEC Paris. I
would like to further thank Orhan Ozalp, Aybars Sezgen, Alper Topaloglu, Atagun
Kilic and Edip Gedizlioglu for participating in the interviews and helping me in my
research by providing fruitful resources and suggestions.
11 ÖZET
Son bes yil icerisinde, konut finansman sistemindeki kriz ve Euro bolgesinde yasanan
borc krizi butun dunyada merkez bankalarini fiyat istikrari kadar finansal istikrara
odaklanmaya yoneltti. Merkez bankalari bu iki hedefi es zamanli basarmak icin
yenilikci yontemler arayisina girdiler ve yeni para politikalarina ve araclarina
yoneldiler, cunku geleneksel yontemler istenilen amaca ulasmakta yetersiz kaliyordu.
Turkiye Cumhuriyeti Merkez Bankasi, kuresel ekonomik ve finansal krizlerin negatif
etkilerini onlemek amaciyla, alisilmisin disinda bir para politikasi tasarlayan ve
yururluge koyan ilk merkez bankalarindan biri olmustur. Bu cerceve dahilinde, Turkiye
Cumhuriyeti Merkez Bankasi, bir yandan ana hedefi olan fiyat istikrarini saglarken,
kredi arz ve buyumesini kisitlandirmayi ve cari islemler acigini saglikli seviyelere
indirmeyi hedeflemistir. Bu cerceve dahilinde alinan onlemler arasinda, gecelik
repolarla birlikte haftalik repolar, faiz koridoru ve munzam karsilik oranlari gibi,
yenilikci para politikasi araclari bulunmaktadir. Bu tez, Turkiye Cumhuriyeti Merkez
Bankasi’nin uygulamis oldugu alisilmisin disinda para politikasinin yururluge
girmesinin altinda yatan sebepleri, nasil tasarlandigini ve uygulandigini, ve yururluge
girdigi gunden gunumuze kadar olan performansini incelemektedir.
12 ABSTRACT
The subprime mortgage crisis and the Eurozone debt crisis that took place during the
last five years pushed central banks around the world to concentrate on financial
stability along with price stability. Central bankers searched for innovative methods to
achieve their dual objectives simultaneously, and shifted towards unconventional
monetary policy mix and instruments since the traditional approaches proved
insufficient in providing the desired outcome. The Central Bank of the Republic of
Turkey (CBRT) is among the first institutions to design and implement an
unconventional approach in order to limit the negative impacts of the global economic
and financial crises. Within this unconventional framework, CBRT aimed to preserve
financial stability through limiting the credit supply and growth, and bringing the
current account deficit to healthier levels, whilst keeping price stability as its primary
objective. The macroprudential measures within this framework composed of
innovative policy tools such as weekly repos along with overnight repos, interest rate
corridor and reserve requirement ratios. This paper examines the reasons underlying the
CBRT’s unorthodox monetary policy mix, its design and operating scheme, and
evaluates its performance since implementation until today.
Keywords: Unorthodox Monetary Policy, Current Account Deficit, Credit Supply,
Reserve Requirements, Interest Rate Corridor, Financial Stability, Macroprudential
Measures
13 INTRODUCTION
The global economic outlook has seen major changes in the last five years. Starting with
the subprime mortgage crisis in the United States in 2007, intensified with the Eurozone
debt crisis in late 2009, key advanced economies entered severe recessions, which
consequently had a significant impact on emerging countries. Turkey was one of the
affected countries since its economy is very much intertwined with Europe.
Central banks, observing these negative developments in the global economy, started to
intervene the economy and decreased interest rates to stir economic activity. Federal
Reserve decreased its policy rate to 0% levels from 5.25%, European Central Bank
decreased its key interest rate to 0.75% from 3.75%, while the Central Bank of the
Republic of Turkey decreased its policy rate, between late 2008 and 2010, to 6.25%
from 17.50%. However, these reductions in interest rates and further quantitative easing
schemes did not provide the expected improvement; yet, it created a massive amount of
capital inflows to emerging countries in search of higher yields.
These massive amounts of foreign capital inflows were very dangerous for a country
like Turkey, which had an important current account deficit problem (CAD being
almost 8% of GDP) for the last 30 years. They would render the country vulnerable to
external economic shocks since a sudden halt in these capital inflows would
significantly affect the already delicate funding scheme of the current account deficit.
These capital inflows would further cause a remarkable expansion in the credit supply
and overheat the economy. Thus, to prevent the adverse effects of these capital inflows
and keep them under control, CBRT designed a new, and “unorthodox”, monetary
policy mix late 2010; while it remained determined to its primary objective of reducing
inflation, it started to focus on financial stability at the same time, meaning that it
implicitly adopted a dual mandate whose components are hard to reconcile.
This paper will first explain the functions and objectives of a central bank and the
monetary policy instruments in order to achieve these objectives. In the second chapter,
monetary policy programs applied by the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey since
1980 will be presented. Then, the reasons why the CBRT designed and implemented
14 this unorthodox monetary policy, its design and operating scheme will be explained.
Last section of the second chapter will assess the effects of this unorthodox policy mix
on other monetary policy tools and CBRT’s dual objectives of price stability and
financial stability. In the final chapter, the performance of this unconventional monetary
policy will be assessed, with the contribution of the interviews that are done with the
treasury departments of major banks in Turkey and with the fixed income portfolio
managers and the strategist of the second biggest asset management firm in Turkey, in
order to understand what are market participants’ expectations. The thesis will conclude
with a critical analysis concerning this unorthodox monetary policy, which will be
followed by a conclusion.
1. CENTRAL BANKS AND MONETARY POLICY
Central banks are the national authorities in charge of monetary policy. Their actions
affect interest rates, the amount of credit, and the money supply, all of which have
direct impacts on both the financial system and the overall economy (Mishkin, 2010,
p.315). Central banks play a crucial role in maintaining the health of the financial
system and the economy. Especially after the recent crises, their role has become even
more significant and important.
In order to fully understand and analyze the impacts of the central banks’ actions on the
financial system and the economy, we need to first understand what are the objectives
and functions of the central banks, the goals of monetary policy and the tools to
implement these policies. We take a look at how these monetary policies are conducted
and transmitted through the financial system, and further touch on central bank
independence. Whilst doing this study, we will cover the Central Bank of the Republic
of Turkey, together with the two major central banks in the world: the Fed (US Federal
Reserve) and the European Central Bank (ECB). We will compare the structural
differences and similarities between these banks to get a holistic view about how central
banks function.
15 1.1. CENTRAL BANKS
1.1.1. Functions
Central banks initially started out as the government’s bank and added various other
functions throughout time. Today, a modern central bank not only manages the
monetary policy, but also provides an array of services to commercial banks, serving as
the bankers’ bank (Cecchetti, 2008, p.352).
As a state’s bank, the central bank has a monopoly on the issuance of currency. It
creates money: the central bank can control the availability of money and credit in a
country’s economy. It is mostly achieved by adjusting short-term interest rates. This
activity is what we refer to as monetary policy. Central banks use monetary policy to
sustain economic growth and maintain low levels of inflation. For example, an
expansionary monetary policy, through lower interest rates, raises both growth and
inflation over the short run, while tighter or restrictive monetary policy reduces them1
(Cecchetti, 2008, p.352).
As the bankers’ bank, the most important jobs of the central bank are;
-
to provide liquidity to banks during times of financial stress,
-
to manage the payments system, and
-
to oversee commercial banks and the financial system (Cecchetti, 2008, p.353).
Other very important function of a central bank is its capacity to act as the “lender of
last resort”. The central bank’s ability to create money means that it can make loans
when no one else can, including during a crisis. To avoid any possible liquidity
shortage, the central bank can lend reserves or currency to sound banks. The central
bank makes the whole financial system more stable by ensuring that sound banks and
financial institutions can continue to operate and by avoiding the spread of bank-runs
when confidence in the banking system fails (Cecchetti, 2008, p.353).
1
Mechanics of monetary policy will be described in the later sections. www.tcmb.gov.tr 3
http://www.ecb.europa.eu/mopo/intro/objective/html/index.en.html 4
http://www.federalreserveeducation.org/about-­‐the-­‐fed/structure-­‐and-­‐functions/monetary-­‐policy/ 2
16 It is also equally important to understand what a central bank does not do. First, a
central bank may monitor and participate in fixed income markets, yet it does not
control securities markets. Second, the central bank does not control the government’s
budget. It serves the government in the same way that a commercial bank serves a
business or an individual. The treasury or the finance ministry manages fiscal policy,
and the central bank provides them a set of services that make such management
possible (Cecchetti, 2008, p.355).
Thus, we can recapitulate the functions of a modern central bank as follows:
As the State’s Bank,
-
Controls the availability of money and credit through interest rate targets and
open market operations.
As the Bankers’ Bank,
-
Guarantees that sound banks can do business by lending to them, especially
during crises.
-
Oversees financial institutions to ensure confidence in their soundness.
-
Could operate a payments system for interbank payments (Cecchetti, 2008,
p. 355).
1.1.2. Objectives
Today, there is an emerging trend towards specifying central banks’ objectives, rather
than only assigning functions. However, numerous central bank functions are still not
guided by legally stated objectives. The figure below shows that objectives related to
monetary policy have a significant weight in central bank laws than the objectives
related to other functions (BIS, 2009, p. 21).
Accordingly, we can classify central banks’ objectives as follows;
-
Monetary policy objectives
-
Financial stability objectives
-
Payment system objectives.
We will now analyze these objectives further in detail.
17 Figure 1: Weight of Central Bank Objectives in Central Bank Laws
Monetary Policy Objectives: Price stability, defined as low and stable inflation, is
viewed as the most important objective of monetary policy. Policymakers are now
increasingly aware of the social and economic costs of inflation and concerned with
maintaining a stable price level. Price stability is desirable because high inflation creates
uncertainty in the economy, makes it difficult to plan for the future, which might lead to
a lower economic growth (Mishkin, 2010, p. 315 -316).
“Price stability is usually the dominant monetary policy objective specified in
legislation. In most cases it is a singular objective or is superior to other
macroeconomic objectives specified in the law (as is made clear, for example, in
mandates such as those requiring central bank support for the government’s general
economic policy without prejudice to the central banks’ primary price stability
objective) (BIS, 2009, p. 21).”
Many countries have indicated price stability as the primary goal for central banks,
since it is crucial to the long-run health of the economy. Mandates that put the goal of
price stability first and state that the other goals will follow if it is achieved are called
18 hierarchical mandates. They are the directives governing the behavior of the European
Central Bank (ECB) and the Central Bank of Republic of Turkey (CBRT). In contrast,
dual mandates try to achieve two co-equal objectives; for example, price stability and
maximum employment for the Federal Reserve (Mishkin, 2010, p. 319 -320).
We can observe, in the table below, that price stability is the dominant or one of the
dominant legal objectives in 33 of the 45 central banks listed (BIS, 2009, p. 21).
Figure 2: Monetary Policy Objectives of Central Banks
19 Financial stability objectives: Majority of central banks presume that they have a
policy responsibility for financial stability. However, fewer than half of central bank
statutes contain objectives related to financial stability, and, of 146 central banks, less
than one fifth have an explicit objective for financial stability (BIS, 2009, p. 25).
In cases where an objective is set for the wider financial stability function, importance
should be paid to the language since it implies a more conditional degree of
responsibility for outcomes. For example, in Turkey, central bank is being charged with
“promoting” a safe, stable or sound financial system, whereas in the Eurosystem,
“central bank’s responsibility for overall financial stability is even more broadly
defined as “contributing to” financial stability or to the actions of another authority
pursuing a financial stability objective (BIS, 2009, p. 26).”
Financial stability is not an absolute objective and almost impossible to represent and
measure quantitatively. Furthermore, trade-offs need to be considered. Potential
incompatibility with other policy objectives might arise since “instruments that might
influence financial stability have other primary roles: interest rates for monetary
stability; financial regulation for market efficiency and institutional or microstability;
and prudential supervision for institutional or microsoundness. Diverting such
instruments from their primary purpose involves trade-offs, thus a further risk of
unintended consequences (BIS, 2009, p. 26).” This was proven during the recent crises.
Even though financial and monetary policy objectives may not contradict each other in
the midst of a crisis, such a conflict may arise upon implementation of the exit strategy.
“Early removal of stimulus could delay the resumption of normal market functioning;
late removal could risk the take-off of inflation (BIS, 2009, p. 26).”
Payment system objectives: This is an objective that is found very frequently in central
bank law. Statements of this objective are usually very general, stating the central
banks’ commitment to smooth operating, sound and efficient payment systems (BIS,
2009, p. 28).
However, like the problem with the specification of a financial stability objective, there
are trade-offs among objectives that need to be considered in this policy area,
robustness versus efficiency being the major trade-off. For this reason, extra-statutory
20 statements are used to specify these objectives and their associated policy frameworks
(BIS, 2009, p. 28).
Furthermore, there is an ever-increasing variety and sophistication of global payment
systems. Thus, central banks need to be adequately flexible to be able to respond to new
challenges (BIS, 2003, p. 45).
1.1.3. Central Bank Independence
In recent years, there has been a significant trend toward greater independence of central
banks.
However, the issue of central bank independence, whether it should be
independent or if it is better off under the control of the parliament, has been a
controversial topic throughout years.
There are two main arguments for central bank independence. The strongest argument
rests on the shortsightedness of politicians, where political (electoral) cycle would
impart an inflationary bias to monetary policy. Political pressures should not influence
central banks, because politicians, who are driven by short-run objectives to win the
next election, have the tendency to opt for short-run solutions to problems, such as high
unemployment and high interest rates, even if they have unfavorable long-run
consequences. For this reason, they might likely overlook long-run objectives, such as
promoting a stable price level (Mishkin, 2010, p.338).
Furthermore, a central bank under political control might be forced to purchase
government securities in order to facilitate financing of large budget deficits. An
independent central bank would better resist this pressure from the politicians (Mishkin,
2010, p.338).
Another important argument in favor of central bank independence is the possible
incompetency of politicians on issues of great economic importance. This argument can
be best exposed in terms of the principal-agent problem. We know that both central
bank and politicians are agents of the public (principals), and yet they have the incentive
to act in their own interest rather than in the interest of the public. However, the
principal-agent problem is more significant for politicians than the central bankers.
21 Thus, if a central bank is separated from political pressures, it can implement policies
that are politically unpopular, yet in the public interest (Mishkin, 2010, p.338).
As with the case for central bank independence, there are also two main arguments
against central bank independence. First one is the lack of accountability of central bank
decisions. Some argue that it is undemocratic to have monetary policy decisions
controlled by an elite group that is responsible to no one, since there is no sanction on
central bankers if the central bank performs badly. Another argument is that central
banks have not always been successful in using their freedoms, such as the failure of
Fed as a lender of last resort during the Great Depression (Mishkin, 2010, p.339).
Even though central bank independence still has not been proven as the ideal structure,
there is an ever-increasing tendency towards more independent central banks throughout
the world. Besides, positive correlation between central bank independence and
inflation levels is proven by empirical evidence. We can see in the figure below that
countries with more independent central banks have lower average inflation rates.
Figure 3: Correlation Between Average Inflation and Central Bank Independence
22 Source:
Alesina
and
Summers,
1993
However, as Alesina and Summers (1993) has shown in their findings, although
monetary policy associated with central bank independence suggests lower level and
variance of inflation, it does not necessarily result in large benefits or costs in terms of
real macroeconomic performance.
Figure 4: Correlation Between Average Real GNP growth and Central Bank
Independence Source: Alesina and Summers, 1993
Another important point in central bank independence, that is cited by Blinder (1998), is
the central bank’s independence from financial markets, together with political
influence. Central bankers turn to financial markets for instant evaluation of its
decisions. However, financial markets might be over speculative, or speculative bubbles
might overshadow fundamental variables. For this reason, central bankers have to be
more cautious and prudent, and not overlook the fundamentals (Blinder, 1998, p. 61).
In order to overcome the lack of accountability of central banks, which might have
disastrous consequences, a central bank needs to be open and transparent. It should
23 communicate what it is doing, why and what is expected by this decision. This would
allow outsiders to evaluate the success or failure of the central bank’s decisions.
Moreover, a more open and transparent central bank provides markets with more
information regarding its view on fundamental factors guiding monetary policy. By
making itself more predictable to markets, the central bank makes market reactions to
monetary policy more predictable to itself, which would result in a better management
of the economy (Blinder, 1998, p. 68 -72)
Moreover, in order to further implement accountability, central banks should just have
instrument independence, which is the ability of central banks to choose appropriate
monetary policy instruments, but not goal independence, which is the ability to set the
goals of monetary policy (Fischer, 1994, p. 217). Thus, monetary policy goals should
be set by the parliament, which is appropriate in a democracy, and by rendering the
central banks accountable to the parliament so that the efficiency of central banks in
achieving these policy goals can be efficiently monitored (Mishkin, 2010, p. 340).
Now, we shall look at the degree of independence of the three central banks that are
subject to our study; the Federal Reserve, European Central Bank and the Central Bank
of the Republic of Turkey.
The Federal Reserve has both instrument and goal independence. It is also not
influenced by political pressure since the members of the Board of Governors are
appointed for a fourteen-year term. More importantly, Fed has an independent source of
revenue, which gives the Fed a remarkable advantage compared to other governmental
institutions. Yet, it can still be subject to Congress’ influence since its legislation is
written by the Congress and can be amended any time. Fed is also subject to the
influence of the president, either indirectly through the Congress, or through the
appointment of the members of the Board of Governors, which is quite often since most
governors don’t complete a full fourteen-year term (Mishkin, 2010, p. 324 - 326).
European Central Bank is the most independent central bank in the world. Even though
the Fed is very independent, the Maastricht Treaty makes the ECB the most
independent central bank (Mishkin, 2010, p. 330). Since ECB is a product of a treaty
that is agreed and signed by all countries of the European Union, it is very difficult to
24 change the legislation under which it operates. This fact renders ECB more independent
than the Fed (Cecchetti, 2008, p.391). Its structure, in terms of independence, is very
similar to the Fed. Like the Fed’s Board of Governors, the members of the Executive
Board are elected for long terms (eight years) without the possibility of reappointment
and the heads of National Central Banks must be appointed for at least a five-year term.
ECB, like the Fed, has a budgetary independence and it is not allowed to take
instructions from any government (Mishkin, 2010, p. 330).
Central bank independence has been a very controversial topic in Turkey. During the
1980s and 1990s, the activities of the CBRT and the Treasury were vastly intertwined.
The conduct of money and credit policies was a duty of both the Central Bank and the
Treasury in their foundation law, which resulted in a conflict of interest (Gokbudak,
1996, p. 323). Under the law that has passed in 2001, CBRT has gained full
independence in conducting its task and mandate.2
1.2. MONETARY POLICY
1.2.1. Goals of Monetary Policy
Monetary policy set by central banks has five specific goals:
1. Low and stable inflation.
2. High and stable real growth, together with high employment.
3. Stable financial markets and institutions.
4. Stable interest rates.
5. A stable exchange rate.
Instability in any of these – inflation, growth, the financial system, interest rates, or
exchange rates – poses a systemic risk that individuals can’t diversify away. However, it
is very hard to achieve all five of the central banks’ objectives simultaneously. For
example, stable inflation may result in less stable growth, and stable interest rates may
be inconsistent with all the other objectives. Since central bank’s main task is to
improve general economic welfare by managing and reducing systemic risk, it is very
important that a central bank prioritize the objectives and finds the right combination of
tools (Cecchetti, 2008, p.356).
2
www.tcmb.gov.tr 25 Now, we should go further in detail with each objective.
Low and stable inflation: Many central banks take the maintenance of price stability –
that is, to eliminate inflation – as their primary objective.
Prices are central to everything that happens in a market-based economy, because they
provide the information individuals and firms need to ensure that resources are allocated
to their most productive uses. Yet, inflation degrades the information content of prices.
When all prices are rising together, it becomes very difficult to understand the
underlying reason. If the economy is to run efficiently, we need to understand what
causes the prices to rise. The higher the inflation is, the less predictable it gets, and the
more systematic risk it creates (Cecchetti, 2008, p.357).
Furthermore, high inflation results in low growth. In a hyperinflation situation, – when
prices double every 2 to 3 months –, prices contain virtually no information, and people
use all their energy just coping with the crisis, so growth drops down (Cecchetti, 2008,
p.357).
Most people agree that low inflation should be the primary objective of monetary policy
since it is the basis for general economic prosperity. But, it is equally important to
decide how low inflation should be. An inflation level close to zero might result in
deflation – a drop in prices –, which makes it more difficult to repay debt, further
increasing the default rate on loans, and affecting the health of banks. Second, if the
inflation rate were zero, an employer wishing to cut labor costs would need to cut
nominal wages, which is difficult to accomplish. With an acceptable level of inflation,
the employer can leave the nominal wages as they are, and workers’ real wages will fall.
Thus, from an employer’s point of view, a small amount of inflation makes labor
markets work better (Cecchetti, 2008, p.358).
High, stable real growth:, Central bankers aim to moderate business cycles and
stabilize growth and employment by adjusting interest rates. The underlying idea is that
there is a long- run sustainable level of production called potential output that depends
on different inputs, such as technology, the size of the capital stock, and the number of
people who can work. Growth in these inputs leads to growth in potential output –
which we would call sustainable growth. Over the short run, output may deviate from
26 this potential level, and growth may diverge from its long-run sustainable rate. For
example, during recessions, the economy slows down, incomes stagnate, and
unemployment rises. Central bankers can moderate such declines by lowering interest
rates (Cecchetti, 2008, p.359).
Contrary to recessions, there are times when growth rises above long-run sustainable
rates, and the economy overheats. These periods may be regarded as increased
prosperity; yet, reduced spending, lower business investment, and layoffs follow them,
since they don’t last forever. For this reason, a period of above-average growth has to be
followed by a period of below-average growth. During such periods, central banks raise
interest rates and keep the economy from operating at sustainable levels (Cecchetti,
2008, p.359).
Therefore, we can say that, in the long run, stability leads to higher growth. The
rationale behind is that unstable growth creates risk for which investors need to be
compensated in the form of higher interest rates. When interest rates are high,
businesses borrow less, resulting in fewer resources to invest and grow. In addition to
aiming high, stable growth, keeping employment high is equally important for a central
bank (Cecchetti, 2008, p.359).
Financial system stability: A stable financial system is a necessity for an economy to
operate efficiently for one simple reason: when the financial system collapses, so does
the economic activity. If people lose faith in banks and financial markets, they will opt
for low-risk alternatives, and intermediation will stop. Savers will not be willing to lend
and borrowers will not be able to borrow (Cecchetti, 2008, p.360).
The possibility of a severe disruption in the financial markets is a type of systematic
risk, which cannot be diversified away individually. Thus, central banks must control
this systematic risk, in order to make sure that the financial system remains in good
working order. They need to ensure that the markets for stocks, bonds, and the like
continue to operate smoothly and efficiently (Cecchetti, 2008, p.360).
Interest-Rate and Exchange-Rate stability: Central bankers will tell try their best to
keep interest rates and exchange rates from fluctuating too much, in order to eliminate
abrupt changes. Yet, these goals are secondary to those of low inflation, stable growth,
27 and financial stability. It is because interest-rate stability and exchange-rate stability are
means for achieving the ultimate goal of stabilizing the economy; they are not ends unto
themselves (Cecchetti, 2008, p.360).
It is very important to reduce interest volatility as much as possible because, first,
interest-rate volatility makes output unstable. Second, it means higher risk – and a
higher risk premium – on long-term bonds. Risk makes financial decisions more
difficult, lowers productivity and renders the economy less efficient. Since central
bankers control short-term interest rates, they can control this risk and stabilize the
economy (Cecchetti, 2008, p.360 -361).
Stabilizing exchange rates has the last priority among all central bank objectives.
However, it depends on the economic structure of a country. Exchange rate stability is
especially important for emerging, less developed, trade-oriented countries, where
exports and imports are central to the structure of the economy, since the value of a
country’s currency affects the cost of imports to domestic consumers and the cost of
exports to foreign buyers. However, it is not a priority for the Federal Reserve and the
European Central Bank (Cecchetti, 2008, p. 361).
For the Federal Reserve, the objective of monetary policy is:
“The goals of monetary policy are to promote maximum employment, stable prices and
moderate long-term interest rates. By implementing effective monetary policy, the Fed
can maintain stable prices, thereby supporting conditions for long-term economic
growth and maximum employment.”3
For the European Central Bank, the objective of monetary policy is:
“To maintain price stability is the primary objective of the Eurosystem and of the single
monetary policy for which it is responsible. This is laid down in the Treaty on the
Functioning of the European Union, Article 127 (1).”4
For the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey, the objective of monetary policy is:
“The primary objective of the Bank shall be to achieve and maintain price stability.”5
3
4
http://www.ecb.europa.eu/mopo/intro/objective/html/index.en.html http://www.federalreserveeducation.org/about-­‐the-­‐fed/structure-­‐and-­‐functions/monetary-­‐policy/ 28 1.2.2. Monetary Policy Tools
Central banks implement these monetary policy goals mentioned above through several
monetary policy tools. There are three tools that have been used traditionally by central
banks:
1. Open Market Operations: They are the central bank’s purchase and sale of
securities in financial markets. It is the most important monetary policy tool,
since it influences the level of bank reserves and interest rates. Although the
main objective of open market operations has been to control short-term interest
rates and the money supply, after the recent financial crisis, this tool has
effectively been used to affect long-term interest rates and to support the flow of
credit in the financial system (Hubbard, O’Brien, 2012, p. 446).
Open market operations occur at the initiative of central banks, which control
the total volume. These operations are flexible and precise; meaning that they
can be used to any extent. For example, if the desired change in reserves or in
the monetary base is small, this can be achieved through a small purchase or sale
of securities. Moreover, open market operations are easily reversed, and they can
be implemented quickly, without any administrative delays (Mishkin, 2010,
p.383).
2. Discount Policy: It is the monetary policy tool that includes setting the discount
rate and the terms of discount lending. Discount window is the facility by which
central banks makes discount loans to banks, serving as the channel for meeting
the liquidity needs of banks (Hubbard, O’Brien, 2012, p. 446).
Discounting is an important monetary policy tool in preventing and coping with
financial panics, putting an emphasis on central bank’s “lender of last resort”
function, and a particularly effective way of providing reserves to the financial
system during a crisis since reserves are directly channeled to the banks that are
having liquidity problems (Mishkin, 2010, p.384 - 385). However, use of
5
http://www.tcmb.gov.tr/yeni/eng/ 29 discount loans are at banks’ discretion and thus, not completely controlled by
central banks, which renders it an ancillary tool (Mishkin, 2010, p.389).
3. Reserve Requirements: This is the regulation that requires banks to hold a
certain proportion of checkable deposits as vault cash or deposits at central
banks (Hubbard, O’Brien, 2012, p. 446). Changes in the reserve requirement
ratio affect the money supply, thus affecting the money supply by causing the
money supply multiplier to change. A rise in reserve requirements not only
reduces the amount of deposits that can be supported by a given level of the
monetary base and decreases the money supply, but also results in an increase of
the target interest rate. For this reason, changes in the reserve requirement ratios
are usually accompanied with offsetting open market operations (Mishkin, 2010,
p.389).
We need to look at this tool further in detail in order to better understand the
discussions in the following chapters concerning our main argument. Reserve
requirements are no longer used as an effective tool of monetary policy. For
example, Fed had the authority to change reserve requirement ratio since the
1930s, however it rarely exercises this power. The last change was made in
April 1992, where the required reserve ratio was reduced from 12% to 10%
(Hubbard, O’Brien, 2012, p. 450). Likewise, the European Central Bank does
not effectively use it. The main underlying reason is that increasing the reserve
requirement ratio might cause immediate liquidity problems for banks, which
are far more sensitive to these changes than other banks. This is what makes the
monetary policy applied by the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey
increasing. Even though it is a progressively renounced tool, it is one of the tools
that caused a stir as a part of CBRT’s unorthodox monetary policy mix6.
There are two new policy tools introduced by the Fed during the financial crisis that are
connected with bank reserve accounts:
6
Discussions concerning the use of reserve requirement as an efficient monetary policy tool and how it is applied by the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey will be further explained in the following chapter. 30 1. Interest on Reserve Balances: Fed started paying interest on banks’ required
reserve and excess reserve deposits ın October 2008. This reduced the
opportunity loss for banks on the required reserves and gave Fed a greater ability
to influence banks’ reserve balances. By this means, Fed can potentially increase
banks’ holdings of reserves, thus restraining banks’ ability to extend loans and
increasing the money supply by raising this interest rate
(Hubbard, O’Brien,
2012, p. 446).
2. Term Deposit Facility: After the crisis, in April 2010, Fed initiated this facility,
which would offer banks the opportunity to purchase term deposits, which are
similar to the certificates of deposit that banks offer to households and firms.
This term deposit facility provided the Fed with another tool that would help
them manage bank reserve holdings. The rationale behind is that the more funds
banks place in term deposits, the less they will be able to expand loans and the
money supply (Hubbard, O’Brien, 2012, p. 446 - 447).
1.2.3. The Conduct of Monetary Policy: Choosing and Using the Right
Monetary Policy Instrument
There are three monetary policy strategies, all of which has price stability as the main,
long run goal of monetary policy. These strategies are:
1. Monetary Targeting:
Within this strategy’s framework, the central bank
announces that it will achieve a certain target value of the annual growth rate of
a monetary aggregate. The central bank is then accountable for achieving this
target. This accountability aspect of monetary targeting makes it advantageous.
Since monetary aggregate figures are easily observable, monetary targets can
send immediate signals to the financial markets and to the public about the
stance of monetary policy, and can help fix inflation expectations and further
lowering it. However, it all depends on a strong and reliable relationship
between the goal variable (inflation or nominal income) and the targeted
monetary aggregate. If this relationship is weak, it will not send proper signals,
31 thus jeopardizing the accountability of the central bank (Mishkin, 2010, p. 395 399).
2. Inflation Targeting: This strategy is best described by Aglietta and Mojon
(2012) as follows:
“An inflation targeting central bank announces a target level for inflation and
engineers the monetary policy that would drive inflation near this level. The
inflation target is either a point or a range that sets a low and positive level of
inflation for a given consumer price index, and the horizons vary, across
countries, from a couple of years to the business cycle or indefinite. This preannouncement helps anchor inflation expectations and provide a benchmark
against which the central bank can be held accountable.” (The Oxford
Handbook of Banking, 2012, p. 247)
Inflation targeting strategy involves several elements: (a) public announcement
of medium-term numerical targets for inflation; (b) an institutional commitment
to price stability as the main, long term goal of monetary policy and a
commitment to achieve the inflation target; (c) an information-inclusive
approach where many variables (not only monetary aggregates) are involved in
monetary policy decision making; (d) transparency of the monetary policy
strategy provided by communicating the objectives of the monetary
policymakers to public; and (e) accountability of the central bank in reaching its
inflation objectives (Mishkin, 2010, p. 399 - 400).
However, just like other strategies, there are advantages and disadvantages of
this monetary policy strategy. It increases the accountability of the central bank,
since it clearly communicates a target, and thus easily observable due to the
clarity of the target. Moreover, unlike monetary targeting, it does not solely rely
on the money – inflation relationship. However, since inflation levels are
observed, then announced, and thus lagged for a certain period, it sends delayed
signals about the achievement of the target, whereas in monetary policy,
immediate signals are sent to public (Mishkin, 2010, p. 402 - 405).
32 3. Nominal Anchor: Main difference of this monetary policy strategy than the
others is that, it involves an implicit nominal anchor rather than defining an
explicit nominal anchor in order for the central bank to be able to control
inflation in the long run. It adopts a forward-looking approach in which the
central bank prudently monitors signs of future inflation by using information
from various sources, reinforced by “periodic strikes” by monetary policy to
avoid inflation (Mishkin, 2010, p. 405).
As stated above as a disadvantage of the inflation targeting strategy, there are
long lags concerning inflation. Moreover, once inflation gets momentum, it
becomes much harder to control. Thus, it is vital to prevent inflation from
getting started; meaning that, the monetary policy needs to be forward-looking
and act much before inflationary pressures in the economy. Although this
strategy compromises many advantages of the inflation targeting strategy and
demonstrated a huge success in the US, its main difference is that it lacks
transparency, which results in a needless volatility in financial markets and
doubt by public regarding inflation and output. This creates a lack of
accountability for central bank, which is not present with inflation targeting
(Mishkin, 2010, p. 405 - 408).
The latter strategy has been used by the Federal Reserve (Fed), significantly during
former chairman Alan Greenspan’s term, and proven successful up until the financial
crisis. However, even though his successor – current Fed chairman Ben Bernanke – is a
strong advocate of inflation targeting, neither an explicit inflation targeting, nor a single
guide to policy has been adopted by the Fed (Mishkin, 2010, p. 407).
The European Central Bank (ECB) follows a hybrid strategy that combines some
elements from both the monetary targeting strategy and the inflation targeting strategy.
The monetary policy strategy that the ECB pursues has two main pillars: Monetary and
credit aggregates are evaluated with regards to “their implications for future inflation
and economic growth” and several economic variables are used to evaluate the future
outlook of the economy. However, ECB’s strategy is considered imprecise because,
33 even though the ECB announces a “below, but close to 2%” goal for inflation, it does
not explicitly commit to an inflation target, which reduces its accountability (Mishkin,
2010, p. 398).
Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey (CBRT) has adopted the “inflation targeting
regime” in 2002. Between the 2002–2005 period, implicit inflation targeting regime was
applied. From 2005 onwards, in order to increase predictability of policy decisions, the
Monetary Policy Committee started to announce its meeting dates in advance, which
resulted in the explicit inflation-targeting regime that started to be implemented in
20067
1.2.4. Transmission of Monetary Policy through the Banking System
Over the past few decades, the economy, especially the banking system, has gone
through a remarkable transformation. These changes have also affected the means by
how monetary policy is transmitted through the banking system. Although the
conventional interest rate channel is still comprehensively used, the credit channel,
compromised of the broad credit channel and bank lending, is also gaining widespread
acceptance (The Oxford Handbook of Banking, 2012, p. 257).
We will now analyze each of these channels to understand how monetary policy is
transmitted through the banking system.
1. The traditional interest rate channel: This view concerns the liability side of
banks’ balance sheets. It results from the reserve requirement constraints of
banks. This transmission mechanism works in the following manner. When a
central bank carries out open-market operations, sells securities, with the
purpose of monetary policy tightening, banks face a decline in reserves. Hence,
banks are forced, by the fractional reserve system, to reduce reservable deposits
to be able to continue to meet the reserve requirement. This shock not only
constrains banks’ behaviors, but also prompts households to decrease their
reservable deposits holding level, thus results in interest rates on other deposits
and non-deposit alternatives to rise. This upsurge in short-term interest rates is
then transmitted to longer-term interest rates, which is consequently followed by
7
http://www.tcmb.gov.tr/yeni/eng/ 34 a decline in the aggregate demand (The Oxford Handbook of Banking, 2012, p.
259 - 260).
2. The broad credit channel: It is also known as the “balance sheet effect”, or
“financial accelerator”. It suggests that an increase in interest rates, which
results from a monetary policy tightening, deteriorates a firm’s health, both in
terms of net income and net worth. Firm’s net income is affected in two ways:
first, its interest costs rise and its revenues decline due to the economic
slowdown that a tighter monetary policy initiated. Its net worth is also
negatively affected due to the lower cash flows that are generated by the firm’s
assets, who were subject to a discounting with the higher interest rate as a result
of the tighter monetary policy. This deterioration in firm’s both net income and
net worth increases the external finance premium, for all sources of external
finance, that must be paid by the firm. This increase in the external finance
premium for borrowers results in a decline in aggregate demand, in addition to
the decline related to the interest rate channel (The Oxford Handbook of
Banking, 2012, p. 260).
3. The bank lending channel: Although this transmission mechanism has been
controversial and less used in the past, it has recently started to stir interest –
especially after the financial crisis. Interest rates are at their lowest levels all
around the world, being very close to the zero bound on nominal interest rates in
the aftermath of the crisis. Central banks are now seeking alternative monetary
police tools as the traditional interest rate policies are now becoming ineffective
because of this zero lower bound. As we have experienced during the past few
years, lending facilities have been widely used to increase financial institutions’
lending process, highlighting the importance of banks in overcoming a recession
(The Oxford Handbook of Banking, 2012, p. 257 - 258).
As we have seen above, decline in available bank reserves due to a tighter
monetary policy obliges banks to create less reservable deposits. Banks must
replace these losses with non-reservable liabilities, or diminish their asset
35 portfolio, such as loans or securities, to maintain a balance between total assets
and the reduced volume of liabilities. This decrease in the availability of bank
loans, in addition to the interest rate effect, further decelerates the aggregate
demand. The bank lending channel is especially important for countries where
firms are ‘bank dependent’, meaning that they have limited access to financial
markets, since their activities might be restrained should the bank lending
channel is impeded (The Oxford Handbook of Banking, 2012, p. 261).
36 2. MONETARY POLICY STRATEGIES OF THE CENTRAL BANK OF THE
REPUBLIC OF TURKEY
Since 1980, Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey has gone through not only various
different monetary policy applications, but also its structure has evolved significantly
until today. For this reason, it is essential to review and understand what has happened
since 1980, which monetary policies were applied by the CBRT under which
conditions, and the developments that has contributed to the creation of the legal and
structural framework that the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey operates under
today.
In this chapter, firstly, monetary policies applied by the CBRT between 1980 and 2010
will be covered. Then, the unorthodox monetary policy under question in this paper will
be presented. Last section of this chapter will assess the effects and outcomes of this
unorthodox monetary policy in terms of other policy tools and CBRT’s objectives.
2.1. MONETARY POLICY APPLICATION BETWEEN 1980 – 2010
In this section, monetary policies applied by the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey
until 2010 will be presented under four different periods.
•
Monetary Policy application between 1980 – 1988
At the beginning of 1980, Turkey had various economic problems, such as high
inflation, oil and energy inadequacy, import bottlenecks due to the lack of foreign
currency, low economic growth, inability to payback foreign debt and as a result, a full
balance of payments crisis; and it needed fundamental reforms in order to solve these
problems (Onder, 2005, p. 147). As a part of these reforms, Turkey liberalized foreign
trade, adopted an export-oriented industrialism strategy, and took important steps in
order to restructure and develop its financial markets.
The January 24 Decisions, which were put into effect to solve the economic crisis in
1980, raised some policy changes that would have long-term impacts on the
industrialization and growth process. The most important characteristics of these
decisions were that the pricing process was completely determined by market powers
and it brought forward the need to open the economy to foreign countries under the free
market conditions (Serdengecti, 1999).
37 The stability program, which became effective on January 24, 1980 and started to being
applied gradually starting from that day on, had two objectives; the first one was to
decrease the inflation rate and to halt its growth in order to provide internal balance, and
the second one was to decrease the balance of payment deficit and gradually eliminate it
altogether in order to establish external balance (Aren, 2008, p. 200).
This decision envisioned an interest rate policy where money supply and demand
equilibrium would be maintained, money supply increase would be linked to general
price levels, and such that would prevent a potential increase in prices and enable to
make investments that are required for the development of the country and prevent price
increases (Ocal et al., 1997, s. 309).
Within this framework, targets such as decreasing inflation, achieving a fast-growth
performance, transitioning to a flexible foreign exchange policy and devaluating the
Turkish Lira significantly, increasing exports by providing opportunities to exporters
like tax and cheap funding, adopting industrialization strategy, decreasing the budget
deficit and taking the necessary measures to accelerate foreign capital inflow, which are
the general targets that IMF suggests to all countries, were determined for Turkey as
well (Kadioglu, 2006, s.14).
The main objectives of the January 24, 1980 decisions can be listed as follows (Onder,
2005, p. 147-148):
-
Increase savings in the economy by decreasing consumption expenses,
-
In order to get inflation under control by applying a tight money and loan policy,
eliminate the financing deficit of public sector over time and limit Treasury’s
borrowing from CBRT,
-
Implement a realistic and achievable interest rate policy in order to increase the
savings and to collect these savings within the banking system,
-
Establish the supply and demand equilibrium for funds by simultaneously
expanding funds that are lent to banks and decreasing demand for credit through
high interest policy,
38 -
Incentivize private and foreign capital in order to eliminate the financing deficit
and to reaccelerate investments in a way to increase employment,
-
Apply a realistic and flexible foreign exchange rate policy in order to rapidly
increase exports,
-
Direct flow of funds to encouraged sectors.
After 1980, the interest rates changed in favor of depositors. It enabled companies to
issue bonds and meet their financing requirements in a more comprehensive way.
However, increase in the cost of debt caused a reaction within the real sector (Ergin,
1993, p.255).
As a result of these economic measures, the inflation rate, which was 105% in 1980,
dropped down to 34% in 1981 and to 28% in 1982. In 1981, while the practice of
determination of the foreign currency exchange rates on a daily basis was adopted,
restrictions on the interest rates were lifted. Small devaluations that are not in excess of
5% were made until May 1, 1981. On May 1, 1981, daily determination of foreign
exchange rate started and foreign exchange rate adjustments authority was taken from
Ministry of Finance and passed on to the Central Bank. With these regulations, the
flexible foreign exchange rate policy, which decreases the differences between domestic
and foreign inflation rates, was put into practice. The flexible foreign exchange rate
policy had positive effect in terms of the flow of overseas domestic workers’ foreign
currencies into the country and the increase of export revenues (Orhan, Erdogan, 2008,
p. 355).
The decisions taken on and after January 24 caused the interest rates of banks to
increase and exhilarated money markets immediately; but, as the required legislative
assurances were not in place, after a while, these decisions dragged the country into a
crisis known as the “Banker Disaster”. As a result of this, the large banks mutually
agreed to prevent adequate increase of interest rates. Later in 1981, Capital Markets
Board was established, and with the allowance of issuance of new financial instruments
like saving certificates, a certain proportion of savings was included in the insurance
scope and some part of the savings was given to Savings Deposit Institution (Eroglu,
39 2004, p. 59).
Between 1983-1985, the Decree No. 30 liberalized the interest rates on bank loans,
while the authority to determine interest rates on deposits was assigned to the Central
Bank. During this period, short-term interest rates were generally kept above the longterm interest rates and monetary authorities tried to give the impression that the inflation
rate would go down in the long run. Later on, reserve requirements and bank liquidity
requirement rates were lowered and rate differences between term deposits and demand
deposits were eliminated. With the Decree dated 1985 based on Banks Law 1983,
obligations were introduced for banks to allocate precautionary reserve for their delayed
collectables and to keep certain amount of reserves proportional to the amount of loans
they granted. Interbank Money Market and Open Market Operations (hence, a
secondary market for Government Debt Securities) were established in March 1986 and
in February 1987, respectively (Eroglu, 2004, p. 59).
As a result, a strict economic regime was applied during the first three years following
January 24 decisions. Nevertheless, starting from 1983 and 1984, an increase in the
monetary expansion trend emerged. This situation primarily stemmed from budget
deficits. In response, Central Bank’s direct loans and hence money supply increased
(Orhan, Erdogan, 2008, p. 356).
In the mid 1980s and particularly in 1987, the year when the elections were held, easing
in monetary and fiscal policies had increased and devaluation expectations started to
rise. Therefore, a series of measures were taken on February 4, 1988. Within this
framework, deposit interest rates were loosened again (however a ceiling limit was
determined); the required reserve ratio was increased to 16%, bank’s liquidity
requirement was increased to 27%; selling export foreign currencies to banks in six
months became obligatory, export tax return was increased and import deposit rate was
increased to 15%. However, these measures could not prevent the escape from Turkish
Lira. Thus, the central bank intervened and injected 160 Million USD to the market on
October 12, 1988 in order to prevent depreciation in the value of Turkish Lira.
Moreover, interest rates on deposits were completely loosened, the required reserve
40 ratios applied to foreign currency deposit accounts and demand deposits were increased
(Gunal, 2001, p.60).
As mentioned previously, the primary objective of the monetary policy is to establish
price stability. When we observe the data for the 1980-1988 period, the fact that the
inflation rate which was 101.4% in 1980 increased to 73.7% in 1988 shows that these
policies was unsuccessful in practice. Besides, it can be said that, except for export
figures, no positive developments were experienced in other macroeconomic indicators,
either.
Table 1: Macro-Economic Data for Turkey between 1980 and 1988
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
Growth (%)1
-2.80
4.80
3.10
4.20
7.10
4.30
6.80
9.80
1.50
Inflation (%)2
104.40
34.0
28.40
31.40
48.40
45.0
34.60
38.90
73.70
Money
50.40
38.70
40.40
34.60
33.10
43.30
45.00
49.30
48.60
1 USD (TL)4
91.04
134.95
188.60
285.60
446.97
579.71
759.68
1.023.44
1.816.65
Export Value
2.90
4.70
5.70
5.70
7.10
8.00
7.50
10.20
11.70
7.90
8.90
8.80
9.20
10.80
11.30
11.10
14.20
14.30
-5.00
-4.20
-3.10
-3.50
-3.60
-3.40
-3.60
-4.00
-2.70
Issuance
Increase (%)3
(bn USD)
Import Value
(bn USD)
Balance
Trade
of
(bn
USD)
Source: www.tuik.gov.tr
The most important reason underlying the failure to prevent the increase in money
supply during the period of 1980-1988 was the budget deficit. Central bank printed
money continuously in an attempt to cover the budget deficits, and these deficits were
financed through domestic borrowing after 1984.
41 The liberalization process in the Turkish economy, which started in 1980, was
completed by lifting the foreign exchange controls based on the Decree No. 32 that was
released in August 1989 and through decontrolling capital movements. The capital
inflow to Turkey, which had been increasing since mid-1980s, multiplied in the 1990s,
the net capital inflow, which was 73 Million USD in 1984, amounted to 780 million
USD in 1989. However, in parallel to global developments, the portion of short-term
capital flows and portfolio investments entering Turkey during this period increased
whereas the portion of direct investments declined.
•
Monetary Policy application between 1989 – 1994
1989 was a milestone for Turkish economy, which was a result of the following three
important developments (Onder, 2005, p. 172):
1. A sudden increase occurred in wages, which had been suppressed during the
September 12 governments and the first Özal government period. This had
significantly contributed to the public deficit, which was already increasing.
2. Weight in financing of public deficit was shifted from Central Bank sources to
domestic borrowing. Accordingly, to make domestic borrowing available,
interest rates were increased. As a result, both debt burdens started to increase
while the term structure became shorter.
3. Capital movements were decontrolled with the Decree No. 32.
The first and the second developments are related to each other. That is, the increase of
real wages contributed to the increase in public deficit. The important point here that
needs attention is the relation between the increase in interest rates and the liberalization
of capital movements. This relation is the underlying reason of the gap between interest
rates and foreign exchange rate, the increase of short-term capital inflows to Turkey, the
banks’ increasing their open positions, and in short the reason behind the crisis in the
early 1994 (Onder, 2005, p. 172).
Although the Central Bank applied a monetary policy in 1986, 1987 and 1988 and
42 determined monetary targets, they were not announced to the public. As a matter of fact,
no monetary policy was in place in 1989 as the targets were exceeded. In 1990, CBRT
pledged for the first time that it would announce its monetary program to the public in a
clear manner, adopt an interim targeting strategy and stick to these program in its
practices.
This monetary program, which was a monetary target adopted by the German Central
Bank in the past to “control the Central Bank Money”, was based on quantitative and
numeric magnitudes related to four variables from the balance sheet of the Central
Bank. These variables were - in order of importance – the Central Bank Money, Total
Domestic Assets, Total Domestic Liabilities and the size of the Central Bank Balance
Sheet (Kepenek, Yenturk, 2001, p.234).
The fundamental objectives of the monetary program that was put into effect in 1990
were determined as follows (Karatas, 2000, p.137):
•
Central Bank balance sheet shall grow by 12-22%,
•
Total domestic liabilities of the Central Bank shall increase by 15-25%,
•
Total domestic assets of Central Bank shall expand by 6-16%,
•
Central Bank Money shall grow by 35-48%.
When the results of the 1990 monetary program are assessed; it can be observed that
total domestic assets and total domestic liabilities were in line with the targeted levels;
however, size of the balance sheet exceeded the upper limit, and Central Bank Money
was below the lower limit of the target corridor (Orhan, Erdogan, 2008, p. 367).
The monetary program that the CBRT designed and applied in 1990 was a mediumterm program, and it covered the period between 1990-1994. This program was
relatively successful; however, the developments that emerged in the Turkish economy
in the following years did not allow the new monetary programs to be feasible and put
in use. Thus, because of the severe problems that Gulf Crisis caused as well as the
government change in the second half, and further uncertainty caused by elections, a
monetary program was not announced for 1991 (Ocal et al., 1997, s. 314).
43 In 1992, CBRT tried to prevent the extreme fluctuations in the foreign exchange rates.
In order to prevent the increasing liquidity pressures in foreign exchange market,
Central Bank withdrew the excess liquidity through open market operations. It
intervened the foreign exchange market through selling foreign currency. Open market
operations increased the liabilities of the Central Bank. The Central Bank Money, which
was included in the monetary program, reached levels way above the target (Karatas,
2000, p.139)
Consequently, it was understood that the monetary programs applied were unlikely to
prove successful as long as the monetary policy instruments were significantly
influenced by fluctuations in the foreign exchange market due to the external financial
liberalization and inability to control public sector deficits. At that point, CBRT
acknowledged the need for implementation of an effective fiscal policy in addition to
monetary policy (Ocal et al., 1997, s. 314).
As a result, the monetary policy that was applied between the 1991 – 1993 period was
unsuccessful. Since Central Bank’s nominal anchor was completely indexed to the
public financing requirements; it lacked the flexibility to signal to other sectors.
Moreover, the excessive and irresponsible use of election economy during this period
and the use of Central Bank sources for this purpose further aggravated the crisis
conditions (Oktar, 2001, p. 94).
Table 2: Macro-Economic Data for Turkey between 1989 and 1994
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
Growth (%)1
1.6
9.4
0.3
6.4
8.1
-6.1
Inflation (%)2
63.3
60.3
66.00
70.1
66.1
106.3
Money
86.5
68.2
51.3
73.0
71.3
90.5
1 USD (TL)4
2.316.0
2.933.0
5.085.0
8.573.0
14.487.0
38.495.0
Export Value
11.6
12.9
13.5
14.7
15.3
18.1
Issuance
Increase (%)3
44 (bn USD)
Import Value
15.7
22.3
21.0
22.8
29.4
23.2
-4.1
-9.4
-7.5
-8.1
-14.1
-5.1
(bn USD)
Balance
Trade
of
(bn
USD)
Source :www.tuik.gov.tr
By the end of 1993, government’s attempts to keep the foreign exchange rate under
control and to prevent an increase in interest rates, and the annulment of the Treasury
tenders for this purpose rendered the crisis inevitable (Gunal, 2001, p.63).
However, in 1994, it would be more appropriate to analyze the monetary policies
applied in two different periods; that is, before and after April 5. In the early 1994, the
domestic borrowing mechanism for the public sector collapsed and the expectation of
devaluation, due to foreign deficit, increased. CBRT has made efforts to keep the deficit
under control through open market operations during the first quarter (Kepenek,
Yenturk, 2001, p.235).
The general economic outlook before April 5, 1994 shows that the real economic sector
was not built on stable and strong bases, the competitive power of the manufacturer
enterprises did not meet global standards, an extraordinary increase occurred in trade
balance deficits and therefore a stable growth could not be achieved (Kepenek, Yenturk,
2001, p.235).
On top of all these developments, two international rating agencies,
Moody’s and Standard and Poor’s, lowered Turkey’s credit rating and three small banks
were closed down, which caused the Turkish economy to go into a crisis and
contributed to this economic outlook by April 5. Central Bank intervened the interbank
money market, which it had not intervened until January 20, 1994, and had to increase
overnight interest rates in order to prevent excessive depreciation in the value of
Turkish Lira. Besides, interest rates for Government Debt Securities were raised up to
50% and the withholding tax previously imposed on such securities was lifted (Guloglu,
Altunoglu, 2002, p. 17).
45 Two main strategies were identified under the stability decisions taken on April 5, 1994.
The first one was to re-stabilize the disrupted macroeconomic balances in the short run,
and several objectives including decreasing the inflation, re-stabilizing the Turkish Lira,
increasing exports and re-establishing disrupted public balances were defined within
this framework. April 5 Decisions turned out to be quite successful in realizing the
short-term objectives since the inflation rate dropped to its previous levels and the
exports increased due to the devaluation in the following years. However, the second,
long-term strategy of April 5 Decisions could not be realized successfully because of
the failure to take adequate and decisive steps for an economic transformation (Parasiz,
1995, p.188).
April 5 Decisions, which embodied the typical characteristics of January 24 Decisions
comprised of a combination of preventive measures to introduce gradual solutions for
short-term targets, and envisioned shock therapies for long term targets. In this context,
the program had the characteristics of a stability program, which involves controlling
the nominal money amount, and does not provide much room for wage increases while
imposing monetary and fiscal restrictions (Parasiz, 1995, p.188).
When the April 5, 1994 Decisions are analyzed in terms of its success in achieving its
targeted objectives, following results are obtained (Uludag, Arican, 2003, p. 64);
-
The program was unsuccessful in preventing the crisis in financial markets,
though it was able to halt the negative balances for a temporary period,
-
GNP dropped by 6% during the crisis year,
-
Inflation rate did not drop below the 70% level, in line with its pre-1994 trend,
-
More than 40% of the consolidated budget was transferred to realize public debt
interest payments,
-
The crisis did not end.
The reasons of these results can be listed as follows (Egilmez, Kumcu, 2008, p.380381):
-
Only fiscal policy measures were implemented, no monetary policy was applied
46 in order to decrease the excessive liquidity in the market,
-
Distrust in the political power continued even after the economic stability
program was put into effect,
-
Measures with respect to institutional structuring were not implemented during
the application of stability measures; on the contrary, the Treasury which should
have held the largest responsibility in implementation of such measures was
turned into an institution managed without any legislation due to the annulment
of its incorporation law by the Constitutional Court’s and the government’s
inability to put a new law into effect for a long time,
-
The Treasury was obliged to continue short term borrowing, which contributed
to increase in uncertainty in the economic outlook.
•
Monetary Policy application between 1995 – 1999
In 1995, Turkish economy still had the traces of 1994 crisis. The recovery that started in
the second half of 1994 continued also in 1995. With the 1996 monetary program,
content of which was not fully announced, Central Bank targeted to limit the increase in
domestic assets and to create Turkish Lira Liabilities equivalent to increase in external
assets (Orhan, Erdogan, 2008, p. 372).
Maintaining financial stability constituted the fundamentals of monetary policies
adopted in 1996. Central Bank aimed to control the reserve money and monitor
movements in the foreign exchange rates with the 1996 monetary program (Kesriyeli
1997, p. 28).
The monetary policies that were applied by the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey
in 1996 and 1997 were not used to keep inflation under control. Therefore, the main
objective of the monetary policy was determined to be maintaining financial stability.
Within this framework, CBRT tried to maintain short-term interest rates and foreign
exchange rates stable. These objectives were met to a certain extent. Since, however,
budget deficits were being financed by the sources of the Central Bank of the Republic
of Turkey sources, money supply increased rapidly; and consequently the inflation rate
increased (Kesriyeli 1997, p. 28).
47 While there were no significant changes in monetary policy in 1997 compared to the
previous year; in 1998, it was stipulated that quarterly monetary policies would be
imposed. Following the protocol signed between CBRT and the Undersecretariat of
Treasury, CBRT declared monetary policies in accordance with the Treasury’s
borrowing program, and announced its results to the public. In line with the 70%
inflation forecast envisioned for the first half of the year, the reserve money was
estimated to increase by 18-20% within the first three months (Gunal, 2001, p.72).
Within the framework of the “Monitoring Agreement” signed with IMF on June 26,
1998; Turkey announced a monetary policy for the second half of the year. With the
monetary policy announced for the period in question and revised in October, certain
changes were made in the targets and the size of “Net Domestic Assets” in the newly
generated analytic balance sheet was determined to be a new target variable (Eroglu,
2004, p. 99).
Like the previous year, the monetary policy in 1999 was determined in accordance with
the objectives of maintaining financial stability and keeping inflation under control. In
June, further discussions with IMF took place; and on December 9, 1999 the monitoring
program was turned into an “anti-inflation program” that consisted of various reforms.
The objective of this program was to reduce the inflation to a single digit figure through
an anti-inflationist policy while imposing potential “reforms” by means of World Bank
support, in agriculture, social security and public spending to mend the system and to
increase productivity again. This three-year stability program was prepared by IMF and
presented to the government together with the Central Bank and the Undersecretariat of
Treasury and eventually received the government’s support (Orhan, Erdogan, 2008, p.
378).
The main macro-economic data that belongs to this period are shown in the table below.
Table 3: Macro-Economic Data for Turkey between 1995 and 1999
Growth (%)1
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
8,0
7,1
8,3
3,9
-6,1
48 Inflation (%)2
93,6
80,4
85,7
84,6
64,9
Money
86,3
70,7
98,5
75,1
80,0
1 USD (TL)4
61.361
108.045
205.740
314.230
542.703
Export Value
21,6
23,2
26,9
26,9
26,6
35,7
43,6
48,5
45,9
40,7
-14,1
-20,4
-21,6
-19,0
-14,1
Issuance
Increase (%)3
(bn USD)
Import Value
(bn USD)
Balance
Trade
of
(bn
USD)
Source :www.tuik.gov.tr
•
Monetary Policy application between 2000 - 2010
At the beginning of 2000, in order to decrease inflation, a stability program where
foreign exchange rate was used as a nominal anchor; monetary and foreign exchange
rate policies were supported by structural arrangements and tight fiscal policies, was
started to be implemented. Between 2000-2002, the program that aimed to decrease
inflation, which used foreign exchange rate as a nominal anchor, was implemented to
fulfill the following main objectives (Ercel, 1999):
1. To decrease the consumer inflation to 25% at the end of 2000, to 12% at the end
of 2001 and to 7% at the end of 2002,
2. To increase the growth potential of the economy,
3. To provide a more efficient and fair distribution of economic resources.
Main economic policies chosen for the successful implementation of this program
aimed at fighting against inflation was summarized as follows (Ercel, 1999):
1. Increasing primary surplus through a strict fiscal policy, realizing structural
reforms and accelerating privatizations,
49 2. Revenue policy in accordance with the inflation target,
3. Foreign exchange rate and monetary policy applications focused on decreasing
inflation - in order to support the contribution of abovementioned tools in
decreasing inflation and real interest rates and to adopt a long-term economic
perspective.
At the end of October 2000, as demand in both domestic market and foreign markets
increased, Turkish economy achieved a growth rate of 6.5-7%. However, as banks
encouraged the savings for consumption through consumer loans, the decrease in the
inflation rate could not reach to the desired levels. During this period, as the interest
rates were increasing, banks started to sell off the treasury bills and bonds they held.
Thus, banks with liquidity problems were consequently forced to fund the securities
they held, and encountered great losses. On the other hand, as foreign investors started
to exit from Turkey rapidly, the interest rates were further increased. The failure of this
program did not stem from its internal inconsistency but rather from the confidence
crisis that was created by banking sector related to the fast transformation enforcement
and inability to solve the subsequent liquidity problems (Egilmez, Kumcu, 2008, p.396).
In addition to the banking crises experienced in November 2000, the political crisis
experienced in February 2001 further caused total erosion of confidence among
financial markets; and resulted in a great increase in demand for the Turkish Lira. When
the IMF rejected to take the risk that current foreign currency reserves could not be
adequate to endure this increase in demand, on February 21, 2001 the Turkish Lira was
set to free float, meaning that the foreign exchange nominal anchor was abandoned.
This event can be considered as a milestone in Turkish monetary policy (Akat, 2004,
p.2).
After the foreign exchange nominal anchor was abandoned in in February 2001, shortterm interest rates became the fundamental monetary policy tools of the Central Bank to
combat with inflation and it they were solely used to decrease inflation (Yigit, 2002, p.
12). Following the transition to floating foreign exchange policy, the Central Bank has
50 announced that foreign exchange rates would be determined with respect to supply and
demand conditions in the market and no interventions would be made to foreign
exchange rates unless sudden and extreme fluctuations occur (CBRT, 2001, p.76).
Within the framework of the legal regulations that the new program imposed, the most
important development concerning the central bank was the change that was made in
the Central Bank law. Some of the changes that were imposed by this law are as follows
(CBRT, 2001, p.111-113);
-
Establishing price stability was accepted as the primary objective,
-
Within the framework of Transparency and Accountability principles, it was
determined that the Head of Central Bank should provide a report to Cabinet in
April and October each year about monetary policies that were applied and
would be applied,
-
Establishment of the Monetary Policy Committee,
-
Granting loans to public sector was forbidden.
In 2001, within the framework of the monetary policy that was in accordance with the
floating exchange rate regime, all the targets were met, except that the money floor as of
June 30 slightly exceeded the ceiling values. However, in addition to the crisis in
November 2000 and February 2001, as a result of world output’s realizing the lowest
growth rate of the past ten years with 2.4% in 2001, Turkey had its share from this
situation and contracted by 9.4% (Keyder, 2002, p. 455).
Table 4: Macro-Economic Targets of Transition to Strong Economy Program and
Realizations
2001
2002
2003
2004
Realization
Target
Realization
Target
Realization
Target
Realization
CPI
68,0
35,0
29,7
20,0
18,4
12,0
9,3
GNP
-9,4
3,0
7,9
5,0
5,9
5,0
9,9
Primary
5,7
6,5
3,9
6,5
6,2
6,5
6,9
92,0
81,0
78,6
73,0
70,5
69,0
65,0
Surplus/GNP
Net
Debt
51 Stock/GNP
Source : www.tcmb.gov.tr
All things considered, the “Transition to Strong Economy Program” that was applied in
2001 did not yield the desired results. Therefore, the 18th stand-by agreement was
signed with IMF and starting from 2002, a 3-year program was planned once more.
After the Foreign Exchange Rate Targeting strategy that collapsed in 2001, the Central
Bank announced its intentions about transitioning to Inflation Targeting strategy and
within the scope of Inflation Targeting preparations, it started to implement Implicit
Inflation Targeting (Egilmez, Kumcu, 2008, p.397).
The primary target of the monetary policy was determined to decrease the inflation rate
down to 35% levels by the end of 2002. The Central Bank targeted to reach this
objective initially by determining targets for the monetary base, and secondly by
transitioning to official inflation targeting regime after pre-conditions were established.
To this end, a monetary program was formed to highlight the performance criteria
regarding monetary base. During 2002, consistent with 3% real growth rate forecast and
35% inflation target, monetary base was targeted to grow by 40%8. In 2002, the
economy grew by 7.8 % and inflation decreased to 30% levels. Trade balance deficit
increased by 17.5% year on year basis and reached 4.2 billion dollars. During this
period, current account balance deficit was 246 million dollars.
For 2003, the annual inflation rate was announced to be 20% and growth projection was
announced as 5%. In 2002, it was announced that, until the transition to inflation
targeting strategy was completed, the implicit inflation targeting would continue like the
previous year. Monetary base ranked among the target indicators again and it was
released to public that short-term interest rates would focus on next period’s inflation
(CBRT, 2003). However, despite these positive progresses, high interest rate levels and
constantly growing trade balance deficit problems in the economy could not be
eliminated in 2003, either. The main reasons behind this situation were that since 1990s,
8
http://www.tcmb.gov.tr/yeni/paraprog/2002/standby2002-­‐2004.pdf 52 with the economic crises it went through, Turkey lost its long term development
perspective, it could not completely string along with the globalizing world order and it
was stuck in a vicious cycle of high interest rate based debts. Making real interest
payments of approximately 35% in 2001, 22% in 2002 and 28% in 2003 to domestic
debts was also noted as an indicator for this situation. Hovering of real interest rates at
high levels was the fundamental reason of Turkish economy’s getting drawn into a debt
swamp. In 2003, the total debt stock was realized as approximately 85% of Turkey’s
GNP (Cortuk, 2006, p.76).
In 2004, tight monetary and fiscal policies diligently continued along with the structural
reforms imposed. Therefore, dominance of the financial sector in the economy started to
gradually decrease; and as of 2004, real interest rates dropped to 10% and total debt
stock’s rate to GNP dropped to 75-80% levels. Additionally, Treasury’s maturity of
borrowing was extended. For the first time in its history, the Treasury borrowed from
the domestic market with a 5-year maturity term. These positive developments caused
tangible improvements in the growth data, as well. Particularly the realization of a 9.9%
growth rate in 2004 recorded in the history of both the world and the Turkish Republic
as the highest growth rates. In addition to growth rate, the inflation rate dropped to
single digits in 2004, recorded as 9.4%, showed that significant steps were taken
towards establishing price stability. As a result, Turkish economy demonstrated great
success in terms of price stability thanks to the implicit inflation-targeting program
applied between 2002-2005 following the crisis in February 2001 (Cortuk, 2006, p.77).
As can be seen in the table below, although no change or progress was realized in terms
of employment and savings, the economic program that was agreed with IMF in 2002
and ended in 2005 achieved its target to a great extent, contrary to the ones that were
previously applied.
Between 2002 and 2005, there had been some important progress and while inflation
dropped, the credibility of the CBRT increased. During this period, the average growth
rate reached to 7%. Financial dominance weakened and concerns about sustainability
of public debt stock diminished. With the weakening of retrospective indexing in
53 pricing behavior, transition from foreign exchange rate to prices declined. Due to
decreased country risk premium, nominal and real interest rates also decreased.
Attainment of fiscal discipline had significantly contributed to the success of monetary
policy during this period (Kadioglu, 2006, p.19).
Figure 5: 2002-2005 Inflation Targets and Realizations
Source : www.tcmb.gov.tr
In line with the transparency and accountability principles, the Central Bank started to
publish quarterly “Monetary Policy Report”, the Monetary Policy Committee convened
regularly during 2005 on the 8th day of every month and took decisions regarding
interest rates in light of the developments in the economic outlook and these decisions
were announced on the following work day. All these positive developments prepared
the suitable environment for the transition to explicit inflation targeting. As it was
declared at the beginning of 2005, explicit inflation targeting regime commenced to
apply starting from January 2006 (Kadioglu, 2006, p.20).
CBRT preferred the inflation target to be defined by Consumer Price Index, since such
method was considered to be the easiest to follow by everyone and a good indicator of
daily life cost estimations. In this respect, the target variable was determined to be the
year-end inflation rate, which was calculated by annual percentage change of 2003
54 based Consumer Price Index. During the first phase of the inflation-targeting regime,
targets were declared for three-year periods. In line with Turkey’s three years budget
plan, year-end inflation targets for 2006, 2007 and 2008 were determined to be 5%, 4%
and 4%, respectively (CBRT, 2005). However, starting from the period during which
the Inflation Targeting regime was adopted, Turkish economy was exposed to series of
external shocks. Between May-June 2006, decrease in the demand for financial assets of
developing countries as a result of global liquidity conditions’ changing in favor of
developed countries and increased capital outflow from emerging countries also
affected the Turkish economy significantly and caused the CBRT to lose control over
inflation expectations (Kumcu, 2008, p.140).
Table 5: Inflation and Growth Figures Realized Between 2005 and 2009
Inflation Growth 2005 7.7 7.6 2006 9.65 6 2007 8.39 4.7 2008 10.06 0.7 2009 6.53 -­‐4.7 Source: www.tuik.gov.tr
In order to prevent any permanent effects that such developments might cause on the
pricing behavior, Central Bank applied a monetary tightening policy. As a result, for the
first time since the implicit inflation-targeting regime started to being implemented,
there was a significant increase in interest rates and a possible intensifying of the
adverse effects of the crisis was substantially prevented. Besides, target inflation rate
could not be achieved and it was realized to be 9.65% in 2006 (CBRT, 2007).
In 2007, interest rates started to decrease gradually. During this period, the overnight
borrowing rate was lowered by 175 basis points in total and decreased from 17.50%
level to 17.75% level until the end of 2007. The real sector started to be affected by the
crisis and a standstill period started. GDP growth rate dropped to 4.7% in 2007.
Inflation was realized to be 8.39 percent9.
9
http://www.tcmb.gov.tr/yeni/duyuru/2007/Baskan_2008Parapol.pdf 55 In 2008, the year of global financial crisis, the channels through which Turkey was
affected by the crisis came to fore as decreasing fund raising opportunities from global
fund markets and a decline in exports. As a result, due to significantly exceeding the
inflation targets for two years in a row in 2008 and the expectation that it would be
exceeded in the third year as well, caused weakening of the function of inflation
targeting as a reference for expectations. In order to bring the inflation expectations
under control again and re-establish the confidence for the regime in effect, the Central
Bank envisioned that the persistence of this situation would lead to higher costs in
combating with inflation, and therefore suggested through an open letter written to
government in 2008 that new targets should be determined for medium term. It was
advised in the letter that nominal anchor characteristics of inflation target were lost and
therefore inflation expectations should be updated as 7.5% for 2009 year-end and 6.5%
for 2010 year-end; and it should be determined to be 5.5% for 201110. 2008 year-end
inflation was realized as 10.06 percent.
In conclusion, from 2009 overnight interest rates, CBRT decided to lower the Central
Bank borrowing interest rate to 6.50 percent; lending interest rate to 9 percent, and to
lower the borrowing interest rate which was provided to market maker banks through
repo transactions for overnight or one week terms, to 8 percent11. In 2009, inflation was
realized as 6.53 percent.
In 2010, the global economic outlook continued to dominate the domestic economic
outlook. In addition to the slow recovery anticipations in advanced economies, the
probability of a second round of quantitative easing by the central banks of advanced
economies, which were already pursuing unusually loose monetary policies, has
increased. These expectations have consequently increased capital inflows to emerging
markets, whilst causing a significant increase in commodity prices. The abundant global
liquidity, due mostly to the loose monetary policies of advanced economies, and the
escalating search for yields have put the emerging markets, including Turkey, in the
spotlight. Turkey’s country specific developments, such as better than expected
10
http://www.tcmb.gov.tr/yeni/duyuru/2007/Baskan_2008Parapol.pdf http://www.tcmb.gov.tr/yeni/duyuru/2009/DUY2009-­‐63.pdf 11
56 economic activity recovery, credit agencies signal of a possible upgrade, lessened
political uncertainty, and the updated Medium-Term Program (MTP) that showed the
commitment to the fiscal discipline, have only increased this phenomenon. As a result
of these developments, market rates have decreased, stock market has risen and the
Turkish lira has appreciated (CBRT, 2010, p.1).
Figure 6: Capital Flows to Emerging Markets
Source: EDFR Global
During this year, domestic demand remained relatively strong. However, due to weak
external demand, aggregate demand conditions continued to incite disinflation, which
resulted the core inflation to decline to historically low levels. Thus, the Monetary
Policy Committee (the Committee) decided to keep policy rates constant for a while,
and low for a long period (CBRT, 2010, p.3).
As the capital inflows towards emerging countries increased since the end of 2009,
CBRT expected the continuation of a strong domestic demand and weak external
demand. With regards to these anticipations, it has warned against rapid credit growth
accompanied with current account deficit risks and raised concerns about financial
stability. In this respect, CBRT has reversed, to a large extent, the temporary liquidity
57 measures that it has implemented during the crisis period. Hence, it has gradually
withdrawn excess liquidity, and implemented an increase in required reserve ratios.
Furthermore, it has stopped the remuneration of required reserves in order to ease the
use of alternative tools of macroprudential policy, and has changed the operational
framework of liquidity management. Ultimately, in addition to these measures, CBRT
has introduced a new scheme for foreign exchange purchase auctions (CBRT, 2010,
p.3).
During this period, despite the increase in the consumer inflation, core inflation
indicators reached historical low levels, which helped anchoring medium term
expectations. 12- and 24-month ahead inflation expectations were slightly above the
year-end targets of 5.5% for 2011 and 5% for 2012. Due to the sharp decline in
unprocessed food prices and less than expected increase in food prices (year-end
realized 7.02%, October 2010 estimate 10.5%), the inflation rate dropped by 2.83
percentage points, to the rate of 6.4%, almost reaching the year-end target (CBRT,
2011, p.1)
In sum, given the weak global economic outlook and capital inflows towards emerging
countries, risk premiums for emerging economies have decreased, which posed a risk to
the macroeconomic and financial stability. This has initiated the CBRT to use its
alternative policy tools, such as reserve requirements and liquidity management, and to
introduce the unorthodox monetary policy mix at the end of 2010.
2.2. THE UNORTHODOX MONETARY POLICY IN APPLICATION: 2010 PRESENT
Fed’s second round of QE (QE2), which in total injected $2.3 trillion of liquidity to the
markets, and the European sovereign debt crisis, which caused an erosion in investor
confidence, consequently increased capital inflows to emerging markets. These
developments were the main driver behind the significant changes in CBRT’s monetary
policy strategy. These exceptionally loose monetary policy measures applied by
58 advanced economies have not only increased the global liquidity, but also stirred the
search for yield, resulting in even more capital flows to emerging countries (CBRT,
2011-I, p. 1-3). This increasing flow of hot money into Turkey via bond and equities
market can be observed in the below graph.
Accumulated Equity and Bond Flows by Foreigners (bn USD) 80 60 40 20 0 Equity Flows by Foreigners Bond Flows by Foreigners Figure 7: Accumulated Foreign Flows to Turkish Equity & Debt Markets
Source: CBRT
Furthermore, the weak recovery in these advanced economies, which are Turkey’s main
export destination, resulted in a significant decline in external demand growth. Robust
credit growth amid ever-increasing short-term capital inflows, low levels of interest
rates across the globe have reinforced the divergence between domestic and external
demand and, resulted in a rapid widening of the current account deficit in 2010, which
in turn required macroprudential measures12 (CBRT, 2011-I, p. 1-3).
12
During 2010 – 2011, current account deficit level rose to a very high level of 10% of GDP due to the fast growth in domestic demand. 59 Figure 8: Current Account Balance
Source: CBRT, Turkstat
Turkey's Annual CAD as a % of GDP 3.0% -­‐2.0% -­‐7.0% -­‐12.0% 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Annual CAD as a % of GDP Figure 9: Turkey’s CAD as a % of GDP
Source: CBRT & TSI
This so-called “new normal” economic framework has required CBRT to implement a
new strategy that compromises monitoring of the financial stability, whilst keeping the
60 main objective of maintaining price stability. Core inflation indicators were in
accordance with the medium-term inflation target, thus leaving enough space for the
monetary policy to focus on financial stability. Therefore, the CBRT has implemented a
policy mix, by diversifying its set of policy instruments, integrating the active use of
alternative instruments, such as liquidity management facilities and reserve
requirements in addition to the short-term policy rates, which is the 1-week repo auction
rate, its main policy instrument (CBRT, 2011-I, p. 1-3).
CBRT’s initial public claim for this unconventional policy mix was that the global
financial crisis highlighted the fact that ignorance of financial stability threatens both
the price stability objective and, in the long run, the macroeconomic stability (Basci and
Kara, 2011). Before the financial crisis, it was believed that the price stability should be
the primary objective of central banks, which would then result in financial stability.
However, this methodology overlooked potential asset bubbles and possible economic
and financial shocks that would remarkably damage the healthy functioning of
economies. It is evident that inflation rates were at significant low levels before the
onset of the crisis; yet, this price stability didn’t stop financial crisis from happening13.
Thus, it can be stated that price stability is a critical element of a healthy economy, but
not enough to maintain financial stability by itself (Ersel, 2012, p. 43). Furthermore,
another reason for the new macroprudential policy implemented by the CBRT after
2010 was the ever-appreciating Turkish Lira and the risk of increasing imports and the
current account deficit. The similar patterns in other emerging economies had already
raised the question of designing a more flexible and innovative monetary policy mix
which would take these macro economical concerns into account (Bianchi and
Mendoza, 2010, p.47).
Therefore, given the current economic climate, the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC)
has decided that the combination of lower policy rates and higher reserve requirement
ratios is the most suitable policy mix in order to conjointly observe financial stability
and price stability, and furthermore introduced the “interest rate corridor” notion. In this
regard, the MPC decided to: “reduce the 1-week repo auction rate, the policy rate, from
13
A good reference for relevant information can be found in the IMF World Economic Outlook. 61 7 percent to 6.25 percent at December 2010 and January 2011 meetings. In addition to
policy rate cuts, the CBRT overnight borrowing rate was reduced by 450 basis points to
1.5 percent. The corridor between the overnight borrowing and lending rates was
widened to allow for more fluctuations in short-term interest rates when needed. All
these decisions aim to encourage capital inflows from short-term to long-term as well
as to prevent the Turkish lira to detach from economic fundamentals (CBRT, 2011-I, p.
4).
Another constraint while formulating the new policy mix was to limit rapid credit
growth, an important factor that contributes to the widening of the current account
deficit. In order to achieve this objective, CBRT decided to use reserve requirement
ratio as active policy instruments. During December and January, the weighted average
of the reserve requirement ratios has increased significantly. Furthermore, reserve
requirement ratios were permitted to differ by maturities, with longer-term maturities
having lower ratios. This has aimed to slow credit growth whilst extending the maturity
of the banking system’s liabilities, thus reducing maturity mismatches (CBRT, 2011-I,
p.4)
Figure 10: Policy Rates and TL Required Reserve Ratios
Source: CBRT, 2011-I, p.4
While framing the new policy measures for current account deficit, the CBRT has
stressed its commitment to the primary objective being price stability. Hence, it has
62 underlined that the impact of the new adopted measures, and the measures that are
expected to be implemented- within this new policy framework, would result in a
tighter stance. By that means, the expansionary effects of the policy rate reductions
would be more than offset by the monetary tightening due to increase in the weighted
average of reserve requirement ratios (CBRT, 2011-I, p. 4).
A further motivation for the new unorthodox policy mix was the drastic and alarming
change in the funding scheme of the current account deficit. We can see in the below
graph that most of the funding of the current account deficit was fulfilled by the shortterm flows after the second half of 2010. Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey
wanted to change this image by aiming to extend the maturities of the flows coming into
Turkey and deter the amount of short-term flows (Kilinc, 2012).
Figure 11: Main Sources of Current Account Deficit Finance
Source: CBRT14
During this period, the benchmark rate, given the CBRT's rate cut decisions and the
accompanying downward revisions to future policy rate expectations, kept floating at
14
Short-­‐term capital movements are sum of banking and real sectors' short-­‐term net credit and deposits in banks. Long-­‐term capital movements are sum of banking and real sectors’ long term net credit and bonds issued by banks and the Treasury (CBRT) 63 historically low levels. The downtrend in inflation expectations has only contributed to
this phenomenon of market rates decline. The CBRT's rate cuts resulted in a rapid
decline of short-term market rates, while longer-term interest rates have declines only
moderately due to the obscurity concerning the future course of policy rates.
Nevertheless, long-term interest rates remained historically low and relatively stable
despite the volatile global risk appetite, signaling a prospective prolonged low interestrate environment in Turkey (CBRT, 2011-I, p. 5).
Figure 12: Interest Rates and CPI Expectations in Turkey
Source: CBRT, 2011-I, p.5
The illustration below summarizes the new framework and shows the three main tools
that have been used effectively; namely ‘reserve requirements’, ‘weekly repos’ and
‘interest rate corridor’. The fundamental objective is to jointly achieve the two
objectives, ‘price stability’ and ‘financial stability’. The noteworthy point here is that
CBRT uses three intermediary variables, specifically ‘expectations’, ‘loan growth’ and
the ‘foreign exchange (FX) rate’. The reason underlying the selection of loan growth
and the exchange rate as intermediary variables was that both variables are easily
observable and the official data related to loan growth is published weekly. CBRT
declared to affect these intermediary variables by changing the three monetary policy
tools. Changes in these intermediary variables would then change the definitive
objectives as a response to the changes in the policy tools. This dynamic character of
the unorthodox monetary policy, by using more than one policy variable in monetary
policy decision-making process, gives the CBRT the flexibility of adjusting the policy
64 depending on the current state and objectives in the economy. Thus, CBRT can adjust
the intermediary variables accordingly in the future in order to achieve both price and
financial stability at the same time.
Figure 13: Transmission Mechanism of the Unorthodox Monetary Policy
Source: CBRT
CBRT gave the signals of a new policy mix in its exit strategy announcement in May
2010 and changed policy rate from overnight borrowing rate to weekly repo lending
rates, which was set to 7% (CBRT, 2010). In October 2010, CBRT decreased the
overnight interest rates from 6.25% to 5.75% in order to dismiss short-term flows. In
November, the overnight borrowing rate was decreased to 1.75% by 400 bps; and then
to 1.5% in January 2011, where the weekly policy rate was 6.25%. Nonetheless,
overnight lending rate was 9% and this difference between the overnight borrowing and
lending rates created an interest rate corridor of 7.5%. By using this interest rate
corridor, CBRT’s aim was to avoid short-term funds by decreasing the overnight
borrowing repo rate at which short-term funds were placed. The interest rate corridor
meant uncertainty for both external funds and domestic banks. Furthermore, CBRT
increased the reserve requirement ratio and diversified the eligible reserves according to
the banks’ deposit maturities, since deposits are the largest liabilities in the Turkish
banking system. The rationale behind was to improve banks’ balance sheets, and to
mitigate the credit supply. Looking at the overall picture, the new unorthodox policy
65 mix took off with the decrease in the overnight interest rates, implementing the weekly
repo rate as the policy rate, increasing and diversifying reserve requirement ratio, and
the active use of the interest rate corridor.
The graph below shows how the overnight rate, CBRT overnight borrowing and lending
rates and CBRT policy rate evolved since May 2010, when the first signals of the new
unorthodox monetary regime were given. The interest rate corridor – the difference
between overnight borrowing and lending rates –form barriers for the market overnight
rates. This consequently gives CBRT the flexibility to adjust the corridor in order to
control the level of the market overnight interest rates. Yet, this move certainly affects
the market yield curve too. A reason for this is that if the market rates at which banks
borrow from and lend to each other overnight are moved, then this change further
transmits to the other parts of the yield curve, finally reaching the long-end of the curve.
When the long-term yields are affected, consequently the real economic activity is
affected, since the short-term interest rate is adequate to seize the impact of monetary
policy on the economy (Borio, 2011, p.3). Accordingly, by creating a new instrument
called ‘interest rate corridor’, CBRT aimed to influence the real economic activity via
consumption and investment decisions, which are linked to credit growth and the
current account deficit.
Market O/N & Policy Rates 13.00% 11.00% 9.00% 7.00% 5.00% 3.00% 1.00% CBRT O/N Lending Rate Market O/N Rate CBRT Policy Rate CBRT O/N Borrowing Rate Market O/N Rate CBRT O/N Borrowing Rate CBRT O/N Lending Rate CBRT Policy Rate Figure 14: Market O/N & Policy Rates, Source: CBRT & ISE
66 Short-term interest rates in the market are determined by the level of demand and supply
for overnight funds. CBRT uses the interest rate corridor in order to affect interest rates
and the liquidity in the market.
Within the context of the new monetary policy mix and in order to ease the liquidity
management of the banks and further enable them to foresee their total funding costs,
CBRT announces the minimum funding that is planned to be delivered through the 1week repo auctions. Furthermore, in October 2011, in order to limit the adverse effects
of the global economic developments and to be able to allocate liquidity more
efficiently, in addition to 1-week repo auctions, the CBRT has initiated 1-month repo
auctions on every Friday, through the traditional method. This resulted in a “weighted
average funding rate” for the market, which CBRT settled as its effective policy rate.
This provided CBRT the flexibility to determine the policy rate daily. Hence, by
observing the volume and quality of the incoming foreign funds flows, CBRT became
adept to change the rates daily without waiting for the monthly Monetary Policy
Meetings (CBRT, 2012-1, p.78). Thus, this new unorthodox monetary policy mix,
unlike the traditional monetary policy regime, gave Central Bank of the Republic of
Turkey the flexibility to adjust the rates quickly and frequently, in cases where needed.
This resulted in changes in the level and volatility of the exchange rate and the credit
growth channels, which subsequently contributed to jointly provide financial stability
and price stability15.
15
The exchange rate that CBRT followed was a equally weighted basket of USD/TL and EUR/TL.
67 Figure 15: Market Liquidity
Source: CBRT
2.3. EFFECTS AND OUTCOMES OF THE UNORTHODOX MONETARY
POLICY
- The Effect of the Interest Rate Corridor on the Exchange Rate Channel And Credit
Growth Channel:
The increase in the incoming foreign fund flows pushes the local currency to appreciate.
This abundance of liquidity further increases credit growth, and coupled with the
currency appreciation causes a remarkable rise in imports, as happened in Turkey. This
situation was even more drastic in Turkey since it has already had historical problems
concerning these macroeconomic variables. Thus, CBRT, aware of the fact that this
would eventually threaten financial stability, took the necessary measures through the
new unorthodox monetary policy mix in order to eliminate the adverse effects of these
short-term flows (Kara, 2012, p.10-19). At the end of 2010, CBRT decreased the lower
band of the interest rate corridor from 6.5% to 1.5%. This widening of the interest rate
68 corridor meant a higher level of uncertainty for these foreign fund flows. Therefore,
considering a risk/return profile in terms of Sharpe Ratio, the money market somewhat
lost its attraction for these funds, due to the use of the interest rate corridor and the
increasing risk perception. This managed uncertainty in the interest rates creates a risk
for short-term funds that are seeking high yields, and thus works as a counter-move tool
against currency appreciation (Kilinc, 2012).
After October 2011, CBRT became able to affect banks’ credit granting conditions, by
dynamically changing the weighted average cost of funding on a daily basis, as
explained in the previous subsection. Within this framework, the cost of funding should
be adjusted and kept within interest rate corridor every day, so that the width and the
uncertainty vis-à-vis cost of funding can greatly influence the banks with high liquidity
needs. Hence, these banks will be more prudent in granting loans and will decrease the
amount of credit grated. Since CBRT is a net lender via open market operations, banks
are becoming even more careful while granting loans (Kara, 2012, p.9-10). Due to the
increasing uncertainty in the rates, banks significantly decreased their credit supply and,
at the same time, had to increase the interest rates they charge for credits. In sum, we
can see that the interest rate corridor can be effectively used to limit credit growth as
well as affect the weighted average cost of funding.
69 Figure 16: Total Loan Growth Rates
Source: CBRT
- The Effect of Reserve Requirement Ratios on the Exchange Rate Channel And
Credit Growth Channel:
As explained in the first chapter, the reserve requirement ratio is one of the effective
tools of central banks. When the CBRT initially designed the new policy mix in October
2010, it aimed to dismiss short-term foreign fund flows, which threatened financial
stability. Yet, keeping in mind that a low level of interest rates would significantly
increase credit growth, and thus threaten price stability, CBRT increased the reserve
requirement ratio depending on deposits’ maturities, which would tighten the credit
supply of banks and allow the Central Bank to jointly achieve both of its targets – price
stability and financial stability16.
16
As mentioned before, deposits form the greatest part of liabilities of the Turkish banking system; which
explains why CBRT targeted to focus on them.
70 Since the start of the financial crisis, reserve requirements have stirred the attention of
central banks for several reasons. First of all, “since reserves are often remunerated
below market rates, an increase in reserve requirements acts as an implicit tax on the
banking sector and widens the spread between deposit and lending rates (Glocker and
Towbin, 2012, p.2). Hence, a rise in the reserve requirement ratios decreases the
profitability of banks due to higher interest spreads. Therefore, at the end of 2010,
CBRT increased the weighted average of reserve requirement ratio to 13.3%, whilst
introducing the ‘weekly policy rate’ and widening the interest rate corridor. CBRT
governors expected that this increase in the reserve requirement ratio would increase the
cost for banks by 100 basis points. Second, a rise in the reserve requirement ratio
reduces the money supply, thus resulting in an economic slowdown. Lastly, an increase
in the reserve requirement ratio paves the way for depreciation in the exchange rate and
a tighter credit supply, as happened in Turkey after the end of 2010.
As of October 14, 2011, CBRT also moderately allowed the Turkish banks to fulfil their
reserve requirements in terms of gold and other foreign exchanges, corresponding to
their Turkish Lira liabilities. Many banks benefited from this opportunity and CBRT, in
turn, was able to accumulate further reserves both in terms of gold and other foreign
currencies. This was especially important since Turkey has a high current account
deficit problem for many years. This provided certain flexibility in terms of softening
the adverse effects of the volatility in foreign fund flows on financial markets. For
example, it provided the banks with the flexibility of holding most of their liabilities in
terms of foreign exchange during the times when the incoming foreign fund flows
increased rapidly, thus avoiding the overappreciation of the Turkish Lira.
71 120 CBRT Reserves, bn USD Total Reserves 100 80 FX Reserves 60 40 20 0 02/01/2009 Gold Reserves 02/01/2010 Gold Reserves 02/01/2011 02/01/2012 FX Reserves Total Reserves Figure 17: CBRT Reserves
Source: CBRT
The use of reserve requirements is also useful for three main reasons;
-
Raising the reserve requirement ratio is less likely to attract capital inflows
compared to an increase in policy rates,
-
The use of reserve requirements strengthens the effectiveness of interest rate
policy,
-
Reserve requirements can be used to meet financial stability objectives
(Montoro and Moreno, 2011, p.57).
Moreover, the use of reserve requirements is exceptionally more useful during periods
of financial stress as high risk-aversion prevents the transmission mechanism of policy
rates (Quizpe, Rossini, 2010, p. 308). In Turkey, CBRT feared of a rapid growth caused
by the foreign fund flows due to the expansionary monetary policies in advanced
economies. For this reason, reserve requirements have been a very effective tool,
complementing the policy rate, since it solved the dilemma between reducing policy
rates to dismiss short-term flows and to increase policy rates to avoid a credit boom.
Yet, it should be kept in mind that, although reserve requirements can be used to curb
72 credit growth, they also reduce the effectiveness of financial intermediation whilst
increasing the cost of credit.
Reserve requirement ratio affects the credit growth through two channels:
i) Direct Costs: An increase in reserve requirements means a direct cost for banks that
have certain liabilities in their balance sheets. When the CBRT increased the reserve
requirement ratio to 13.3% in October 2010, this meant a cost of 100 basis points for
banks, which they reflected in the credit and deposit rates. However, this increase did
not have a significant effect in the credit supply, thus proves that it remained inefficient
to curb credit growth.17 Even after the increase in the reserve requirement ratio, Turkish
banks were able to fund themselves cheaply through repo auctions, where the low
weekly policy rate was the benchmark. Thus, banks were able to substitute the lost
liquidity due to the increase in the reserve requirement ratio with this cheap funding.
CBRT continued providing this relatively cheap funding for banks in order to be still in
line with its inflation-targeting mandate. Consequently, this limited the anticipated
decline in credit supply through the direct cost channel (Kara, 2012, p. 12).
ii) Liquidity: The effect of the increase in reserve requirements on credit growth is in
fact more effective coupled with the use of the interest rate corridor. Else, the lost
liquidity caused by the increase in reserve requirements would be replaced by CBRT’s
funding through repo auctions. The joint use of the interest rate corridor and the other
liquidity management tools create uncertainty for the banks with higher liquidity
requirements. This, consequently, results in these banks decreasing their credit supply,
and being more cautious. The uncertainty in short-term rates is especially higher during
increasing capital flows, as the CBRT decreases its overnight borrowing rate to
overcome the adverse effects of these flows (Kara, 2012, p. 13).
17
Koray Alper and Tolga Tiryaki shows in their working paper that, since Central Bank continued
funding banks at low rates, the direct cost of limited reserve requirement ratio increases to banks
remained minimal. Source: “Role of Reserve Requirements as a Monetary Policy Tool”, CBRT, April
2011.
73 - The Effect of the Exchange Rate Channel and Credit Growth Channel on CBRT’s
dual objectives: Price Stability and Financial Stability:
The foreign exchange effect on economy cannot be neglected in Turkey since Turkey is
a net importer country and the economic growth is well linked with import substitution.
When the currency depreciates, it results in a value increase of imports in Turkish Lira.
If Turkish Lira potentially depreciates by 10% against an equally weighted basket of US
Dollar and Euro, inflation is therefore expected to increase by 1.5% over one year. More
importantly, this 1.5% inflation increase can be observed in the first 6 months (Kara and
Ogunc, 2011, p.6). This explains why moving the level of Turkish Lira through the new
monetary policy affect price stability.
Credit channel has a direct impact on the economic activity and the current account
balance. Its importance can be clearly observed given that the total amount of credit to
GDP ratio has reached 50% by the end of 2011. Furthermore, domestic consumption
counts almost around 75%, as can be seen in the below graph, meaning that growth is
mainly achieved through domestic consumption. The impact of the credit channel is
expected to have even more impact on aggregate demand, which is why it is taken into
account while designing the monetary policy since it directly affects the current account
balance and the medium term inflation pattern (Kara, 2012, p. 14).
Credit and exchange rate channels have an effect on inflation mainly through aggregate
demand and retail costs (Kara, 2012, p. 14). CBRT is using the new monetary policy
tools, such as reserve requirements, interest rate corridor and the other liquidity
management tools, to achieve its price stability objective and to maintain inflation close
to its targets.
74 80% 78% 76% 74% 72% 70% 68% 66% Contribueon of Consumpeon in Growth Figure 18: Contribution of Consumption in Growth
Source: CBRT
Defining financial stability is harder than price stability because there are no concrete
variables to measure it or one specific definition. Although it is a subjective concept,
Michael Foot, the Managing Director of UK Financial Services Authority, once defined
it in 2003 as;
“We have financial stability where there is: a) monetary stability, b) employment levels
close to the economy’s natural rate, c) confidence in the operation of the generality of
key financial institutions and markets in the economy, and d) where there are no
relative price movements of either real or financial assets within the economy that will
undermine (a) or (b).”18
CBRT has a macro perspective regarding financial stability and reviews it mainly
within the current account balance and credit growth framework.
As explained above, exchange rate influences financial stability through augmenting the
current account deficit. Appreciation of the Turkish Lira increases imports, thus
increasing the trade deficit levels, which subsequently worsens the already problematic
current account deficit. It would further increase the demand for imported products, and
therefore exposing the economy to external shocks. Credit channel has very similar
18
http://www.fsa.gov.uk/library/communication/speeches/2003/sp122.shtml 75 effects on financial stability through the current account balance since a rapid increase
of credit supply subsequently increases domestic demand, where it means an increasing
demand for imported products in Turkey (Kara, 2012, p.14).
Overall, as a result of the rationales explained above, CBRT takes into account the
changes in the foreign exchange and the level of credit growth while dynamically finetuning its monetary policy actions.
Finally, in order to summarize the application of CBRT’s unconventional monetary
policy mix and get a holistic view of the policy’s timeline, the policy regime can be
examined for three periods of time consistent with the range of tools applied by the
CBRT.
- Application during November 2010 - August 2011
During this period, the main target of CBRT was to smoothen the adverse effects of the
short term foreign capital flows to Turkey, due to the on-going quantitative easing
programs (QE2, etc.) in advanced economies, the appreciation of the Turkish Lira and
the increasing current account deficit, and thus to provide financial stability. Since the
lower than targeted level of inflation left room for the use of other policy tools, CBRT
focused its monetary policy to decrease the entry of short tem capital flows in order to
limit credit growth, and consequently to curtail aggregate demand. Hence, in order to
discourage short-term capital flows, CBRT extended the interest rate corridor
downwards, and increased uncertainty in interest rates. At the same time, to balance out
this and to limit possible credit growth due to the low level of interest rates, the Central
Bank further increased the reserve requirement ratio significantly. This rise in reserve
requirements correspondingly resulted in banks increasing their funding from Central
bank through repo auctions, and thus strengthened the command of monetary policy on
credit supply via liquidity channel (Kara, 2012, p.16).
76 - Application during August - October 2011
Economic outlook during this period was dominated by the Eurozone debt crisis and
increasing uncertainty in markets. As the Eurozone debt crisis continued intensifying
and the uncertainty increased, the global risk appetite deteriorated, which in turn
resulted in a significant decline in the volume of foreign capital flows to emerging
countries. Hence, CBRT tightened the interest rate corridor to limit the capital outflows
in order to ease uncertainty contrary to what was aimed during the first period of
application. In other terms, CBRT actively used interest rate uncertainty as a monetary
policy tool. At the same time, in order to limit any downside risks that might cause
exogenous demand shocks, CBRT applied a limited reduction in the weekly repo rates.
Additionally, the Central Bank provided a considerable amount of FX liquidity to
markets to prevent a sudden halt of funding. On the other hand, reserve requirements
were still kept at high levels since the credit growth was still relatively high and the
short-term interest rates were at low levels (Kara, 2012, p.16 - 17). By looking at these
two periods, it can be observed that different policy tools were used during each period
to achieve the joint objectives of price stability and financial stability.
- Application during October 2011 - Present
After October 2011, the inflation pattern started to deteriorate and exceed 10% due to
two important factors. Due to the rapid capital outflows from emerging countries, as
expressed above, this resulted in a remarkable depreciation of the Turkish Lira. This
inflationary pressure was further intensified with the increasing administered good
prices. CBRT forcefully responded to these developments by monetary tightening and
increased the market-lending rate (CBRT, 2011-IV, p.8). During this period, CBRT
decreased the funding it provided to markets via weekly quantity auctions and widened
the interest rate corridor upwards by pushing the upper band to 12.5% from 9%. Hence,
the short-term market rates rose considerably. Moreover, to prevent a sudden halt in the
credit supply due to monetary tightening, reserve requirement ratio was decreased. In
February 2012, following the measures taken by the Eurozone countries to solve the on-
77 going debt crisis, the risk of a sudden halt in capital inflows decreased and, accordingly,
CBRT tightened the interest rate corridor, by decreasing the upper band rate to 11.5%
from 12.5% (Kara, 2012, p. 17).
The unconventional monetary policy mix of the Central Bank of Turkey’s main focus
has been providing financial stability whilst observing financial stability. This implicitly
dual mandate was realized through various monetary policy tools in addition to the
traditional policy rate. Within this framework, foreign exchange and credit channel have
been the actively used intermediary variables, and they have had a direct impact on the
efficiency of the monetary policy application. The intermediate variables, foreign
exchange and credit growth, have moved as it was planned, in favour of the monetary
policy since October 2010. While the currencies of emerging countries, alongside
Turkish Lira, have increased in value against USD until November 2010 in correlation,
After this period, with the help of the new monetary policy mix, it has followed a
different path and depreciated relatively around 20% until August 2011 when the
Eurozone crisis has become more severe. However, as the risk appetite deteriorated
after August 2011, the emerging market currencies have rapidly depreciated while the
Turkish Lira remained relatively stable. The previous depreciation of the Turkish Lira
that was realized before August 2011 prevented further fluctuations in Turkish Lira and
excessive capital outflows (Kara, 2012, p.18). Performance of the EM currencies and
Turkish Lira against US Dollar since August 2011 to present can be observed in the
below graph
78 'USDTRY' vs. 'USD-­‐EM Currencies' Performance, between August 2011 -­‐ Present 1.2 1.18 1.16 1.14 1.12 1.1 1.08 1.06 1.04 1.02 1 USDTRY Performance Aggregate USD/EM Currencies Performance Figure 19: Performance of TL & Emerging Markets Currencies vs. USD since August
2011
Source: Bloomberg
Similarly, the policy has been successful in limiting the credit growth. The total credit
growth was 50% at the end of 2010, and it gradually decreased to around 15 - 20% with
the help of the unconventional monetary policy mix, becoming more coherent with the
moderate GDP growth. It can be seen in the below graph that credit growth slowly
responded to the new monetary policy mix and started to slow down gradually
following the new measures. As the Banking Regulation and Supervision Agency
became involved after mid-2011 by further implementing macroprudential measures,
the credit growth significantly slowed, and as the CBRT widened the interest rate
corridor upwards and tightened monetary stance, credit growth started to decrease
(Kara, 2012, p.19).
79 Credit Growth in Turkey 60.00% 50.00% 40.00% 30.00% 20.00% 10.00% 0.00% TL Credits -­‐ YoY % Change FX Credits -­‐ YoY % Change Total Credits -­‐ YoY % Change Figure 20: Credit Growth in Turkey
Source: BRSA
In sum, it can be seen that the credit growth was kept in line with the financial stability
objective. The unconventional monetary policy regime had been arranged successful in
counterbalancing the capital flows direction and was successful in preventing an such
that it countermoves the direction of capital flows in order to balance a hostile capital
inflow/outflow. Thus, we can say that Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey has been
successful in terms of efficient use of intermediary variables in reaching monetary
policy objectives.
3. EVALUATION OF THE CBRT’S UNORTHODOX MONETARY POLICY
Until this final chapter, we have primarily seen how central banks function. Afterwards,
we have presented the monetary policy application of the Central Bank of the Republic
of Turkey since 1980 to present, including the new unorthodox monetary policy, in
order to get a holistic framework of the Turkish economy and better understand and
assess the monetary policy in question.
In the last subsection of Chapter 2, we have seen that the CBRT so far has been
successful in using the intermediary variables. In the first subsection of this chapter, we
will assess the performance of the unorthodox monetary policy mix in terms of
80 monetary stability and financial stability. We will then present the interviews conducted
with the Treasury departments of three big banks in Turkey and the second biggest asset
management firm to have an objective view of the monetary policy and to understand
how market participants view it, since CBRT has not initially been successful in
communicating it to investors. We will also grasp their expectations on the main
economic indicators. Lastly, combining the evaluation of the new monetary policy
application in the initial subsection and the interviews, a critical analysis of the
unorthodox monetary policy will be presented.
3.1. Global Evaluation of the Policy Performance
In the previous chapter, we have analysed how CBRT used the credit channel and the
foreign exchange channel in order to apply the unorthodox monetary policy mix and we
have seen that it has nearly been successful. However, in order to completely assess the
performance of the policy mix, we need to look at how successful it has been in
achieving its implicit dual objectives: price stability and financial stability.19 While
evaluating the performance of the new policy mix, the main parameter used for financial
stability is the current account balance; while the parameter used for price stability is
inflation and inflation expectations.
-
Financial Stability:
One of the motivations behind the new unconventional mix of CBRT was to limit the
cyclicality of the current account deficit. By achieving that, CBRT aimed to increase the
endurance of the economy against a possible halt in foreign capital flows. Thus, they
aimed to reduce the current account deficit and to bring it funding scheme to a healthier
pattern, and we can say that they have been successful in that sense. We can see in the
below graph that the current account deficit has remained resilient around 10% of GDP
for some time and then started to decrease around mid-2011; yet, it is still expected to
decline further. By the first quarter of 2012, current account deficit excluding energy
was almost eliminated. It is also observed in the graph that the current account deficit
19
As mentioned in the previous chapter, CBRT’s main monetary policy objective is price stability. However, after late 2010, it has stated that its objective is to maintain price stability, while observing financial stability. 81 level is lagging for two quarters after the implementation of the unconventional policy
mix (Kara, 2012, p.20). The remarkable fact here is that it is statistically more
problematic for the current account deficit to return to a high-state level from a lowstate level. Therefore, if the central bank achieves to maintain the current account deficit
at low levels, there may arise an opportunity for policy makers to keep it at low levels
for a long period of time, which will emphasize further the significance of
monetary
policy in terms of financial stability (Akcay, Ocakverdi, 2012, p. 88-91).
20000 10000 0 -­‐10000 -­‐20000 -­‐30000 -­‐40000 -­‐50000 -­‐60000 -­‐70000 -­‐80000 Annual CAD Level of Turkey (mn USD) Annual CAD Annual CAD exc. Energy Figure 21: Annual CAD Level of Turkey (mn USD)
Source: CBRT
The funding scheme of the current account deficit has also improved and reached a
healthier pattern, alongside the current account deficit. By the end of 2010, the main
problem concerning the funding of the current account deficit was that the main portion
of this funding was achieved by short-term capital flows; and that there was a
remarkable need to change this structure. The new monetary policy mix achieved to
increase the proportion of long-term capital and foreign direct investments. However, as
can be seen in the below graph, short-term funds still remain the main source of funding
the current account deficit (Kara, 2012, p.20). We need to mention here that innovative
monetary policy tools cannot solely improve the CAD funding scheme. Turkey needs to
implement important structural reforms such as improving its human capital, investing
in R&D and technology. Only through this reforms dependence on imported goods can
82 be reduced, and the main export zone can shift from Europe to other emerging
countries, which would decrease Turkey’s exposure and vulnerability to advanced
economies.
Funding of the CAD (mn USD) 90,000 80,000 70,000 60,000 50,000 40,000 30,000 20,000 10,000 -­‐ -­‐10,000 FDI & Long Term Investments Short-­‐Term Porholio Flows CAD Figure 22: Funding of the CAD (mn USD)
Source: CBRT
-
Price Stability:
During the last quarter of 2011, annual inflation has reached 10,5%, which is
considerably above CBRT’s target inflation level of 5%. However, it was not merely
related to the inefficiency of the monetary policy, it was more a result of several
external factors combined and these external factors and one-off items contributed to
5.1% of the annual inflation, as presented by many central bank governors.
83 12.0% Annual InflaXon (%) 10.0% 8.0% 6.0% 4.0% 2.0% Annual Inflaeon (%) CBRT Target (%) Figure 23: Annual Inflation
Source: TSI
The price of imported goods and unprocessed food prices, and more than expected tax
on tobacco were the main contributors to the annual inflation, 2%, 1.1%, 2%
respectively. Since they are regarded as one-off items, CBRT did not change its
expectation of a decline in annual inflation in 2012 and remained determined to this
medium-term inflation target level of 5%. We can observe in the below graph that
inflation expectations follow a stable path and there is no deterioration in the 12- month
and 24-month expected medium-term inflation level despite this high level of inflation,
10%. This is very important in the sense that, after the sudden hike in inflation in 2006
and 2008, there was a sharp deterioration in the medium-term expected inflation levels,
as can be observed in the graph. However, after the implementation of the new
unconventional monetary policy mix, medium-term inflation expectations did not
deteriorate. This proves that the policy regime has been successful in keeping the
inflation expectations under control, which is another positive characteristic of the
unconventional monetary policy mix since it gives significant importance to inflation
expectations whilst deciding on target inflation levels (Kara, 2012, p.21-22).
84 InflaXon ExpectaXons 9.5% 9.0% 8.5% 8.0% 7.5% 7.0% 6.5% 6.0% 5.5% 5.0% 15/01/2007 15/01/2008 15/01/2009 15/01/2010 12 Months Inflaeon Expectaeon 15/01/2011 15/01/2012 24Months Inflaeon Expectaeon Figure 24: Inflation Expectations
Source: CBRT
Overall, the unconventional monetary policy mix seems to have a more positive effect
on financial stability compared to price stability. CBRT almost fully achieved its goal of
financial stability. Even though it can bee seen that the CBRT is not neglecting price
stability while observing financial stability, the fact that the medium-term inflation
expectations are still higher than initially targeted proves that the CBRT has not been
successful in achieving price stability. This is the main weakness of the new unorthodox
monetary policy mix (Kara, 2012, p.22).
3.2. Empirical Research: Interviews
The unorthodox monetary policy mix of CBRT has received significant attention from
financial markets and institutions. Mainly because it was an unorthodox policy with
unconventional tools that market participants were not used to, but also CBRT initially
failed to communicate the policy in a clear and comprehensible manner, which created
confusion mostly for foreign participants.
In this chapter, interviews are done with the Treasury departments of major Turkish and
foreign banks, which were affected first hand with the new policy mix and the Fixed
Income Portfolio Managers and the strategist of the second biggest asset management
85 firm in Turkey. Since inflation expectations are a part of monetary policy decisions,
questions reflect the inflation expectations, and also the expected FX and CAD levels.
This will help the readers to assess if the targets of CBRT are realizable and line with
the market participants.
INTERVIEWS
1. What is your annual consumer inflation expectation (%) for;
-
The end of current year?
DEUTSCHE YAPI
ING
BANK
BANK MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT
KREDI
BANKASI
AK
ASSET AK
ASSET AK
ASSET
#1
#2
#3
6.4%
7%
7%
6.15%
DEUTSCHE YAPI
ING
AK
ASSET AK
BANK
BANK MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT
6.3%
6.3%
Mean: 6.525%
-
12 months later?
KREDI
BANKASI
6.3%
5.9%
6.2%
#1
#2
#3
6.5%
7.4%
6.3%
Mean: 6.43%
ASSET AK
86 ASSET
-
24 months later?
DEUTSCHE YAPI
ING
BANK
BANK MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT
KREDI
BANKASI
6.5%
5.7%
5.8%
AK
ASSET AK
ASSET AK
#1
#2
#3
6%
6.9%
6.20%
ASSET
Mean: 6.18%
2. What is your expectation for overnight interest rate established in repo - reverse
repo market (%) for the end of current month?
DEUTSCHE YAPI
ING
BANK
BANK MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT
KREDI
BANKASI
AK
#1
ASSET AK
#2
ASSET AK
ASSET
#3
5.40%
5.5%
5.70%
6.75% 5%
5.6%
Mean: 5.66%
3. What is your expectation for the CBRT one week repo rate (policy interest rate)
(%) for;
-
The end of current month?
DEUTSCHE YAPI
ING
BANK
BANK MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT
KREDI
BANKASI
AK
#1
87 ASSET AK
#2
ASSET AK
#3
ASSET
5.50%
5.75%
5.75% 5.75%
6.3%
5.75%
Mean: 5.8%
-
3 months later?
DEUTSCHE YAPI
ING
BANK
BANK MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT
KREDI
BANKASI
5.50%
5.75%
AK
#1
5.75% 5.75%
ASSET AK
ASSET AK
#2
#3
6.4%
5.75%
ASSET
Mean: 5.81%
-
6 months later?
DEUTSCHE YAPI
ING
BANK
BANK MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT
KREDI
BANKASI
5.50%
5.50%
AK
#1
5.75% 5.50%
ASSET AK
ASSET AK
#2
#3
6.7%
5.75%
ASSET
Mean: 5.78%
-
12 months later?
DEUTSCHE YAPI
ING
BANK
BANK MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT
KREDI
BANKASI
5.50%
5.25%
6%
AK
#1
#2
5.50%
6.7%
Mean: 5.78%
ASSET AK
88 ASSET AK
#3
5.75%
ASSET
-
24 months later?
DEUTSCHE YAPI
ING
BANK
BANK MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT
KREDI
BANKASI
5.50%
6.50%
6%
AK
ASSET AK
#1
#2
5.50%
6.7%
ASSET AK
ASSET
#3
5.50%
Mean: 5.95%
4. What is your expectation for the Interbank USD/TL exchange rate for (TL);
-
The end of current month?
DEUTSCHE YAPI
ING
BANK
BANK MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT
KREDI
BANKASI
1.80 TL
1.81 TL
1.81
TL
AK
ASSET AK
ASSET AK
#1
#2
1.80 TL
1.8240 TL
ASSET
#3
1.80 TL
Mean: 1.807 TL
-
The end of current year?
DEUTSCHE YAPI
ING
BANK
BANK MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT
KREDI
BANKASI
1.82 TL
1.80 TL
1.82
TL
AK
ASSET AK
#1
#2
1.815 TL
1.8220 TL
Mean: 1.8095 TL
ASSET AK
89 #3
1.78 TL
ASSET
-
12 months later?
DEUTSCHE YAPI
ING
BANK
BANK MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT
KREDI
BANKASI
1.85 TL
1.75 TL
1.78
TL
AK
ASSET AK
ASSET AK
#1
#2
1.825 TL
1.8450 TL
ASSET
#3
1.81 TL
Mean: 1.81 TL
5. What is your expectation for annual current account balance (Million USD) for;
-
The end of current year?
DEUTSCHE YAPI
ING
BANK
BANK MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT
KREDI
BANKASI
62 mn USD
65
mn 63 mn
USD
USD
AK
ASSET AK
ASSET AK
#1
#2
63 mn USD
60 mn USD
ASSET
#3
61 mn USD
Mean: 62.3 mn USD
-
The end of next year?
DEUTSCHE YAPI
ING
BANK
BANK MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT
KREDI
BANKASI
70 mn USD
65
mn 69 mn
USD
USD
AK
ASSET AK
#1
#2
66 mn USD
66 mn USD
Mean: 66.5 mn USD
ASSET AK
90 ASSET
#3
63 mn USD
6. What is your expectation for annual GDP growth (%) for;
-
The end of current year?
DEUTSCHE YAPI
ING
BANK
BANK MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT
KREDI
BANKASI
AK
ASSET AK
ASSET AK
ASSET
#1
#2
3.8%
3.9%
4.1%
DEUTSCHE YAPI
ING
AK
BANK
BANK MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT MANAGEMENT
3%
4%
#3
3.8%
Mean: 3.77%
-
The end of next year?
KREDI
BANKASI
3.75%
5%
4.8%
ASSET AK
#1
#2
5%
5%
ASSET AK
#3
5%
Mean: 4.758%
7. What changes do you expect in CBRT’s monetary policy mix in the upcoming
three months?
Deutsche Bank: We are expecting a 100 - 150 bps decrease in the upper band of
the interest rate corridor.
Yapı Kredi Bankası: Since all major central banks in the world are further
decreasing their interest rates, we are expecting the CBRT to also decrease
interest rates unless there is no major change in the global economic outlook.
We are expecting a decrease in the upper band of the interest rate corridor by 50100 bps in the first following Monetary Policy Committee Meeting, then a
further decrease by 200 bps later on.
91 ASSET
ING: We are expecting a 200 bps decrease in the upper band of the interest rate
corridor, while keeping the lower band of the interest rate corridor as it is. We
are not expecting any change in the policy interest rate in the next three months.
Ak Asset Management #1: I expect an easing in the monetary policy due to the
low levels of growth and to the fact that local elections are scheduled to take
place next year. Due to the weakness in advanced economies, there is a
perception towards decreasing inflation. Thus, I expect a gradual tightening in
the interest rate corridor. We can see a 50 bps decrease in the upper band of the
interest rate corridor in the first MPC meeting, and a further 100 bps later on
depending on the quantitative easing programs that Fed and ECB will take place.
Ak Asset Management #2: I expect a tightening in the interest rate corridor.
Ak Asset Management #3: I expect a decrease in the upper band of the interest
rate corridor.
8. Do you find CBRT’S unconventional monetary policy mix successful in terms
of achieving its stated objectives?
Yapı Kredi Bankası: We find CBRT’s monetary policy mix successful since
the beginning of 2012. We believe that CBRT has been successful in keeping
the FX levels in the target range with the help of the global economic
improvement. CBRT has supported the “soft landing” of the economy by
implicitly decreasing interest rates. Even though it is not expected that CBRT
will achieve its annual year-end inflation target, it has been successful in
increasing its credibility. Furthermore, in the beginning of 2012, most foreign
banks were expecting either negative or close to 0 GDP growth levels in Turkey
for 2012 year-end. However, they had to revise their estimates upwards in the
second quarter. CBRT seems to have been successful so far in achieving “soft
landing”. Our main concern about the unorthodox monetary policy mix is that
92 since it is unconventional and complex, it is hardly understood by foreign
financial institutions and investors and thus, creates a risk premium for Turkey.
CBRT should be more clear and precise while communicating its monetary
policy decisions.
ING: Yes.
Ak Asset Management #1: Despite the fact that Turkish economy is positively
affected by the contraction in the global economy, a higher-level inflation is
expected due to the increase in budgetary deterioration, cheap energy prices, and
further quantitative easing programs in the advanced economies will cause on
foreign exchange and commodity prices. Even though the government has
announced that no special economic program will be applied because of the
elections, there is an ever-increasing investment in infrastructure problem in
municipalities. Financing these investments through additional debt or tax might
cause an increase in interest rates. However, CBRT can be successful through
additional foreign capital flows, which would enter Turley if rating agencies
increase Turkey’s grade.
Ak Asset Management #2: Partially yes.
Ak Asset Management #3: Yes, thanks to its flexibility and difficult
predictability.
3.3. Critical Analysis of the CBRT’s Unorthodox Monetary Policy
The unorthodox monetary policy mix of CBRT has been designed and used for the first
time in Turkey. Transmitting the new monetary policy mix, along with the absence of
supporting
financial
data
and
theoretical
background,
caused
problems
in
communicating this unconventional policy mix, as also mentioned in interviews.
Furthermore, since there wasn’t any other institution to take measures against intense
capital flows, the central bank had to intervene and take precautionary measures in
terms of monetary policy.
93 As mentioned above before, CBRT has been successful in providing financial stability
and, to a lesser extent, price stability. In order to assess the performance of the
unconventional policy mix, current account deficit target level is used for financial
stability, and target inflation level is used for price stability. When we observe these
parameters while evaluating the performance of the monetary policy, it can be observed
that there have been significant improvements. However, it can be said that these target
levels are not at their optimal levels; in other words, achieving these targets are far from
sufficient in adding value to the real economy.
When we look at the inflation expectations graph, we can see that inflation expectations
haven’t deteriorated after the implementation of the policy mix –even when the annual
inflation was above 10% -, there still remains great ambiguity over whether CBRT will
be able to achieve its medium-term inflation target of 5%. When we look at the answers
of market participants’ interviews in the previous section, annual inflation estimates for
2012 year-end and next year is observed to be around 6.5%. Furthermore, even though
the current account deficit has improved and its funding scheme started to contain long
term investments more, there still should be further improvement in order to decrease
the vulnerability of the economic outlook. As can be observed from the answers in the
interviews above, the year-end current account deficit is estimated to be around 62.3
million USD for 2012, and 66.5 million USD for 2013. This shows us that, although the
monetary policy mix has been successful to an extent since its implementation in late
2010 until present, it remains insufficient to keep current account deficit under control.
However, as mentioned previously, current account deficit cannot be solely reduced by
monetary policy, but there are more structural reforms needed concerning investment in
R&D and technology, and education.
One of the policy tools that the CBRT actively used in its unconventional monetary
policy mix is the reserve requirement ratio. CBRT started using this tool more actively
starting from late 2010, and increased the reserve requirement ratio with the aim of
slowing down credit growth. However, at the same time, CBRT continued to provide
liquidity to banks through open market operations. Since weekly policy rates were at
very low levels, banks continued to fund themselves through repos in order to
compensate the loss that occurred from increased reserve requirements and accordingly,
94 to lend and supply credit. CBRT had to continue providing this liquidity since it has an
explicit inflation target and needs to provide certain amount of liquidity to the market so
that the market rate can converge to CBRT’s policy interest rate. Thus, reserve
requirements was not very successful on its own but it became a more efficient tool
along with the interest rate corridor, since the ladder created uncertainty in levels of
interest rate.
In the graph below, positive level of open market operations shows the volume of shortterm loans that the CBRT provided banks through repos. It can be observed that the
level of reserve requirements and open market operations are highly correlated, which
shows that the reserve requirements alone, if not supported with another policy tool, is
not effective in curbing credit growth.
80,000,000 70,000,000 60,000,000 50,000,000 40,000,000 30,000,000 20,000,000 10,000,000 -­‐ -­‐10,000,000 OMO Reserve Requirements Figure 25: Reserve Requirements and Open Market Operations (OMO) (mn TL)
Source: CBRT
Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey has carried out an experiment with this
unorthodox monetary policy mix on the Turkish economy to maintain financial
stability. As can be seen in Figure 16, the intervention of the Banking Regulation and
Supervision Agency (BRSA) and the additional macroprudential measures it has
implemented in June 2011 through its Financial Stability Committee, in order to further
95 limit credit growth and increase the efficiency of monetary policy in achieving it,
resulted in a significant decrease in credit growth. Thus, the question that can be asked
here is that what would have happened and would the monetary policy be as successful
as it is today in maintaining financial stability if the Banking Regulation and
Supervision Agency did not contribute to the monetary policy (Ozatay, 2012, p.13).
Another important point that can be raised concerning the involvement of the Banking
Regulation and Supervision Agency in the monetary policy process is that the BRSA
had been late in joining the process. Akcay and Ocakverdi (2012) state in their paper
that the reason why CBRT was able to achieve its goal of decreasing credit growth later
than expected comes from the “exclusion of the BRSA in the initial package and thus
the absence of punitive sanctions on aggressive lending motives.”
Another criticism that Ozatay (2012) has raised in his paper is the existence of two
different institutions that are in charge of financial stability. He proposes that, instead,
some of BRSA’s powers should be transferred to the Central Bank and CBRT should
exclusively be responsible in taking macroprudential measures concerning financial
stability. Otherwise, it would jeopardize either the independency of central bank or the
autonomy of the BRSA.
Increase in reserve requirements represents an additional tax liability for banks. Thus,
after it was increased, banks looked for alternative funding solutions with lower costs.
Accordingly, it stirred corporate bond issuance by banks, which wasn’t common before
in Turkey, and Eurobonds. The volume of syndicated loans provided by international
financial institutions also increased drastically. This increase also encouraged banks to
remove items off-balance sheet items during certain periods.
After 2010, CBRT has sacrificed price stability to an extent in order to maintain
financial stability, which became increasingly important due to the negative global
economic outlook. 12-month and 24-month inflation expectations may have not
deteriorated significantly, but the inflation level has increased above 10% during 2011
and the first months of 2012. Although the Central Bank is determined to maintain its
medium-term inflation target level at 5%, medium-term inflation estimates are higher
96 than 5%, which, after a certain point, might deteriorate medium-term inflation
expectations, and harm the real economy.
97 CONCLUSION
Aftermath the financial and economic crises that started with the subprime mortgage
crisis, global economic conjuncture has remarkably changed and capital flows were
directed to emerging countries. Turkey has been one of the countries that have attracted
these capital flows. Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey had to take additional
measures to prevent the possible negative impacts of these capital flows, mainly
widening of the current account deficit, credit growth and an unhealthy funding scheme
of the current account deficit. Thus, CBRT took on the role to provide financial stability
and adopted an implicit mandate with dual objectives, which are price stability and
financial stability.
During late 2010, CBRT started to apply the so-called “unorthodox” policy mix, which
incorporated an increase in reserve requirements, use of the interest rate corridor and
other liquidity management tools, in addition to the traditional policy rate. CBRT aimed
to achieve financial stability in addition to its primary objective of financial stability
through affecting the credit growth channel and the foreign exchange channel by using a
combination of these policy tools.
When analyzed since the start of its implementation, it can be seen that this
unconventional monetary policy mix has been successful in preparing the Turkish
economy to “soft landing”. Current account deficit, which was at a 40 percent level
before this policy mix, has been following a decreasing trend and reached almost 15
percent. Long-term investments also increased its portion in the current account deficit
scheme since this application. Although it can be argued that this unconventional policy
mix has been less successful in achieving and maintaining price stability, it was
successful in preventing the deterioration in medium term inflation expectations.
However, the inflation outlook can rapidly change if the quantitative easing in advanced
economies continues. This might require the CBRT to take additional measures of
monetary tightening.
Overall, CBRT has been mostly successful with the “unorthodox” monetary policy mix.
Since it is a fairly recent policy mix, it is not possible to capture all aspects and fully
assess its performance. CBRT will have to dynamically adjust its tools with the rapidly
98 changing global economic conjuncture and if proves successful, it might represent a
good example for other central banks.
99 BIBLIOGRAPHY
Akat, A. S., 2004. “Dalgalı Kur ve Para Politikası: Bir Parasal Kural Önerisi”,
İstanbul Bilgi Üniversitesi Yayınları
Akcay, C.; Ocakverdi, E., 2012. “An Interim Assessment of the ongoing Turkish
Monetary and Macroprudential Experiment”, Iktisat, Isletme ve Finans, 27 /315
Alesina, A., Summers, L. H., 1993. “Central Bank Independence and Macroeconomic
Performance: Some Comparative Evidence”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 25:
151 – 162
Aren, S., 2008. “100 Soruda Para ve Para Politikası”, İmge Kitabevi, Ankara
Basci, E. and Kara, H., 2011, “Finansal Istikrar ve Para Politikasi”, CBRT Working
Paper, No: 11/08
Berger, A. N., Molyneux, P., Wilson, J.O.S., 2012, “The Oxford Handbook of
Banking”, Oxford University Press
Bianchi, J. and Mendoza, E.G., 2010. “Overborrowing, Financial Crises and ‘Macro
Prudential’ Taxes”, IMF Working Paper, No: 16091
BIS (Bank for International Settlements), 2009. Issues in the Governance of Central
Banks, A report from the Central Bank Governance Group
BIS (Bank for International Settlements), 2003. The role of central bank money in
payment systems, A report from the Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems
Blinder, Alan S., 1998. Central Banking in Theory and Practice. The MIT Press,
Cambridge. Massachusetts London, England
Borio, C, 2011. “Central Banking Post-crisis: What Compass for Uncharted Waters”,
BIS Working Paper, No: 353
Cecchetti, S., 2008. Money, Banking and Financial Markets. McGraw – Hill/Irwin, 2nd
Edition. New York, NY
Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey (CBRT), 2001. Annual Report, Ankara,
Turkey
Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey (CBRT), 2003. Annual Report, Ankara,
Turkey
100 Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey (CBRT), 2005. “General Framework of
Inflation Targeting Regime and Monetary and Exchange Rate Policy for 2006”, No:
2005-45, Ankara, Turkey
Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey (CBRT), 2007. Annual Report, Ankara,
Turkey
Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey (CBRT), 2010. Inflation Report, 2010-IV.
Ankara, Turkey
Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey (CBRT), 2010.“Monetary Policy Exit
Strategy”, Ankara, Turkey
Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey (CBRT), 2010. Inflation Report, 2011-IV.
Ankara, Turkey
Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey (CBRT), 2012. Inflation Report, 2012-IV.
Ankara, Turkey
Cortuk, O., 2006.“Türkiye-IMF İlişkileri ve İlişkilerin Hesap Bazında İşleyişi”, CBRT,
Uzman Yeterlilik Tezi, Ankara
Egilmez, M.; Kumcu, E., 2008. “Ekonomi Politikası: Teori ve Türkiye Uygulaması”,
Remzi Kitabevi, İstanbul
Ercel, G., 1999. “2000 Yılı Enflasyonu Düşürme Programı : Kur ve Para Politikası
Uygulaması”, www.tcmb.gov.tr
Ergin, F., 1993. “Türkiye’de Tarih Boyunca Para Politikası Sorunları”, İstanbul
Üniversitesi, İletişim Fakültesi Dergisi
Eroglu, N., 2004. “Türkiye’de Parasal Kesim ve Merkez Bankası İşlemlerinin Analizi”,
Der Yayınları, İstanbul
Ersel, H., 2012. “Finansal İstikrarın Sağlanması için Nasıl Bir Mekanizma
Tasarlanabilir?”, Iktisat, Isletme ve Finans, 27 /315
Fischer, S., 1994. "How Independent Should a Central Bank Be?" (with Guy Debelle),
in Goals, Guidelines, and Constraints Facing Monetary Policymakers, Federal Reserve
Bank of Boston, Conference Series No. 38
Glocker, C.; Towbin, P., 2012. “The Macroeconomic Effects of Reserve
Requirements”, WIFO Working Papers, No. 420
Gökbudak, N.,1996.“Central Bank Independence, the Bundesbank Experience and the
Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey”, The Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey
Research Department, Discussion Paper: 9610: 283 – 331
101 Guloglu, B.; Altunoglu, E., 2002. “Finansal Serbestleşme Politikaları ve Finansal
Krizler : Latin Amerika, Meksika, Asya ve Türkiye Krizleri”, İstanbul Üniversitesi
Siyasal Bilgiler Fakültesi Dergisi, No:27
Gunal, M., 2001. “Merkez Bankasının Değişen Rolü ve Para Politikası Uygulamaları”,
İMKB Yayınları, Ankara
Hubbard, R. G.; O’Brien, A. P., 2012. Money, Banking and the Financial System.
Pearson, 1st Edition. Boston, MA
Kadioglu, F., 2006. “Parasal Aktarım Mekanizması : Türkiye Örneğinin Yapısal Model
Çerçevesinde Analizi”, CBRT, Uzman Yeterlilik Tezi, Ankara
Kara, H., 2012. “Küresel Kriz Sonrası Para Politikası”, Iktisat, Isletme ve Finans, 27
/315
Kara, H.; Ogunc, F., 2011. “Döviz Kuru ve İthalat Fiyatlarının Enflasyona Etkisi”,
CBRT Working Paper, No: 11/14
Karatas, M., 2000. “1990 Sonrası Türkiye’de Uygulanan Para Programları”,
Balıkesir Üniversitesi Sosyal Bilimler Enstitüsü Dergisi, Cilt 3, Sayı:4
Kepenek, Y., Yenturk, N., 2001. “Türkiye Ekonomisi”, Remzi Kitabevi, Istanbul
Kesriyeli, M., 1997. “1980’li Yıllardan Günümüze Para Politikası Gelişmeleri”,
CBRT, Araştırma Genel Müdürlüğü, No:97/4, Ankara
Keyder, N., 2002. “Para-Teori, Politika, Uygulama”, Seçkin Yayıncılık, Ankara
Kilinc, M., 2012. “Innovations in Monetary Policy: Turkish Case”, CBRT, FMA
European Conference
Kumcu, E., 2008. “Krizler, Para ve İktisatçılar”, Remzi Kitabevi, Istanbul
Mishkin, F,. 2010. The Economics of Money, Banking and Financial Markets. Pearson,
9th Edition. Boston, MA
Montoro, C.; Moreno, R., 2011. “The Use of Requirements as a Policy Tool in Latin
America”, BIS Quarterly Review, March 2011
Ocal, T.; Colak, Ö.F.; Togay, S.; Eser, K., 1997. “Para Banka Teori ve Politika”,
Gazi Kitabevi, Ankara
Oktar, S., 2001. “Kuramda ve Uygulamada Para Kurulu”, Bilim Teknik Yayınevi
İstanbul
Onder, T., 2005. “Para Politikası: Amaçları, Araçları ve Türkiye Uygulaması”,
CBRT, Uzmanlık Tezi, Ankara
102 Orhan, O. Z.; Erdogan, S., 2008. “Para Politikası”, Palme Yayıncılık, Ankara
Ozatay, F., 2012. “Para Politikasinda Yeni Arayislar ve TCMB”, Iktisat, Isletme ve
Finans, 27 /315
Quizpe, Z.; Rossini, R.; 2010. “Monetary Policy during the Global Financial Crisis of
2007-2009”, BIS Working Paper, No: 54
Parasiz, I., 1995. “Kriz Ekonomisi”, Ezgi Kitabevi Yayınları, Bursa
Serdengeçti, S., 1999. “Türkiye’de Enflasyon ve Büyüme İlişkisi : Genel Bir
Değerlendirme” entitled speech (www.tcmb.gov.tr)
Uludag, I.; Arican, E., 2003. “Türkiye Ekonomisi (Teori- Politika –Uygulama)”, Der
yayınları, İstanbul
Yigit, S., 2002. “T.C. Merkez Bankası Bankalararası Para Piyasası”, TCMB Araştırma
Genel Müdürlüğü
Internet Portals:
http://www.ecb.europa.eu/mopo/intro/objective/html/index.en.html
http://www.federalreserveeducation.org/about-the-fed/structure-andfunctions/monetary-policy/
http://www.tcmb.gov.tr
103