* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Economic voting and the Great Recession in Europe
Second Party System wikipedia , lookup
Political parties in the United States wikipedia , lookup
Electoral reform in the United States wikipedia , lookup
Elections in the United States wikipedia , lookup
Ethnocultural politics in the United States wikipedia , lookup
Independent voter wikipedia , lookup
Third Party System wikipedia , lookup
American election campaigns in the 19th century wikipedia , lookup
Economic voting and the Great Recession in Europe A comparative study of twenty-five countries Troy Alexander Cruickshank August 2016 A thesis submitted for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy of The Australian National University © Copyright by Troy Alexander Cruickshank 2016 Declaration This thesis is entirely my own work and has not previously been submitted for a degree or diploma in any university. To the best of my knowledge and belief, the thesis contains no material previously published or written by another person except where due reference is made in the text. Troy Cruickshank i Acknowledgements I would like to thank first and foremost my supervisor Ian McAllister. Your advice to me has always proven sound, whether relating to my thesis specifically or to academic life more generally. I much appreciate your willingness to meet with me or read my work on short notice throughout my candidature. I would also like to thank the other members of my advisory panel, Juliet Pietsch, who frequently made herself available to discuss my work and whose advice is also much appreciated, and Andrew Banfield, who stepped up at the last minute to fill a formal vacancy. I would also like to thank the other people who have taken the time to discuss my work with me at various points throughout my thesis. These include, in no particular order, Hans-Dieter Klingemann, Jeffrey Karp, Jill Sheppard, Richard Johnston, Shawn Treier, Timothy Hellwig and Yusaku Horiuchi. Finally, I would like to thank my friends and family who have supported me in countless ways throughout this process. You know who you are. iii Abstract The Great Recession of 2007–09 was the worst global economic crisis since the Great Depression of the 1930s. The effects were felt across most of the developed world and Europe was no exception. In many European countries, austerity programmes were implemented in response to the recession, which were often deeply unpopular. Many governments lost power in the years following the recession, with sometimes strikingly harsh swings against them. One notable example was the Irish election of 2011, in which the incumbent Fianna Fáil was reduced from 71 to 20 seats, by far its worst result at any general election since independence in 1922. This is congruent with the theory of economic voting, according to which voters will remove from office governments that fail to deliver economic prosperity. Although there is an enormous empirical literature supporting this theory, almost all of this evidence pertains to the typical boom and bust cycle of individual countries and little is known about economic voting during a severe global recession. The Irish result could have been indicative of the usual economic vote, a bolstered economic vote due to the unusual scale and severity of the crisis, or of dissatisfaction with the government’s handling of the crisis. This thesis investigates whether the usual economic vote in European countries was altered during the Great Recession. This thesis uses survey data from the 2004, 2009 and 2014 waves of the European Election Studies (EES) to compare the economic vote in 25 European countries before, during and after the Great Recession. Multilevel methods are used to model voters’ support for the parties they could vote for at general elections in their own countries. Using this method, the results show that the economic vote was weaker during the crisis than it was either before or after. In order to explain these results, I analyse which parties voters tended to prefer after the crisis and how attitudes towards the European Union evolved over time. The results find that there was a shift away from centrist and pro-European parties towards radical and Eurosceptic parties following the crisis. In addition, support for the EU fell over the same time period and voters were increasingly likely to hold the EU responsible for economic conditions. Given the timing v vi of these shifts as well as the association between European institutions and austerity policies, these findings suggest that the austerity programmes implemented in the wake of the crisis may have been a stronger catalyst for economic voting in Europe than the Great Recession itself. Contents Introduction 1 1 Theory of economic voting: how economic conditions shape the vote 9 1.1 What is economic voting? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 1.2 Perceptions or indicators: the link between the economy and the vote . . . . . 13 1.3 Sociotropic voting: do voters only care about themselves? . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16 1.4 Prospective and retrospective voting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18 1.5 The vote choice process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 1.6 Reward and punishment: the logic of sanction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 1.7 Competent government: the logic of selection . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26 1.8 Political context and the instability problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29 1.9 The Great Recession . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31 1.10 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36 2 Measuring the economic vote 41 2.1 Data sources and timing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42 2.2 Measurement and variables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48 2.3 Method of analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57 2.4 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62 3 Voting in a time of crisis: how the Great Recession affected the economic vote 63 3.1 Party support theory of economic voting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65 3.2 Hypotheses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67 3.3 Measuring the economic vote . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68 3.4 A spatial model of party support . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70 3.5 The prime minister’s party and the economic vote . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73 vii viii CONTENTS 3.6 A multiparty model of the economic vote . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78 3.7 Influence of the economy on mean party support . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84 3.8 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86 4 Clarity of responsibility during a global recession 89 4.1 Clarity of responsibility: economic voting in different contexts . . . . . . . . . . 90 4.2 The dimensions of clarity of responsibility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 94 4.3 Hypotheses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97 4.4 How clarity affects the prime minister’s party . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 99 4.5 The effect of clarity on other parties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 105 4.6 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110 5 Extreme and Eurosceptic parties: the changing policy preferences of European voters 113 5.1 Hypotheses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114 5.2 Classifying parties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118 5.3 How party position relates to voter support . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124 5.4 The changing fortunes of pro-European integration parties . . . . . . . . . . . . 127 5.5 Left–right position: a shift to the extremes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131 5.6 Beyond left and right: social and economic dimensions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 134 5.7 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140 6 Economic abstention: turnout intention in the face of economic pessimism 143 6.1 Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 144 6.2 Hypotheses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 148 6.3 Measuring turnout intention . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 149 6.4 An economic model of turnout . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153 6.5 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 158 7 Attitudes towards European integration and institutions 161 7.1 Austerity and the European Union . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 162 7.2 Measuring attitudes towards the European Union . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 164 7.3 Hypotheses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 168 7.4 Attitudes towards further European integration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 170 7.5 Popular support for EU membership . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 177 CONTENTS ix 7.6 Attribution of responsibility for the economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 183 7.7 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 187 8 Conclusion: revising theories of economic voting 191 A Countries and parties 199 B Coefficient tables 213 References 237 List of figures 1.1 Basic principle of economic voting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 1.2 Outline of economic voting theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37 1.3 Vote choice process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37 2.1 GDP growth in the European Union, 2000–2015 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43 2.2 Distribution of raw and centred party support . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50 2.3 Distribution of left–right distance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52 2.4 Distribution of prospective and retrospective assessments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54 2.5 Relationship between prospective and retrospective assessments . . . . . . . . . . . 55 2.6 Data stacking process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58 3.1 Support for incumbent prime minister’s party by economic assessment . . . . . . . 69 3.2 Relationship between party support and left–distance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71 3.3 Predicted support for prime minister’s party by left–right distance . . . . . . . . . . 75 3.4 Predicted support for prime minister’s party by economic assessment . . . . . . . . 77 3.5 Data classification structures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79 3.6 Economic vote by year and incumbency status . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81 3.7 Predicted support by year and incumbency status . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82 4.1 Economic vote for dominant government party by time in office . . . . . . . . . . . 103 4.2 Economic vote for dominant government party by ideological cohesion . . . . . . . 104 4.3 Economic vote for dominant government party by institutional clarity . . . . . . . . 105 4.4 Government and opposition economic vote by time in office . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107 4.5 Government and opposition economic vote by ideological cohesion . . . . . . . . . 108 4.6 Government and opposition economic vote by institutional clarity . . . . . . . . . . 109 5.1 Relationship between party support and position . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124 5.2 Relationship between integration position and salience . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 126 x List of figures xi 5.3 Party support by position on European integration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 129 5.4 Relative support for pro-integration parties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 130 5.5 Party support by general left–right position . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132 5.6 Party support by economic left–right position . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 135 5.7 Party preference by social libertarian–authoritarian position . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 138 6.1 Average turnout at national elections in EU countries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 151 6.2 Proportion intending to vote by year and economic assessment . . . . . . . . . . . . 152 6.3 Predicted probability of voting by past behaviour . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 155 6.4 Predicted probability of voting by economic assessment and party identification . 156 7.1 Support for European integration by prospective economic assessment . . . . . . . 173 7.2 Support for European integration by left–right position . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 174 7.3 Evaluation of EU membership over time . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 179 7.4 Positive evaluation of EU membership by prospective economic assessment . . . . 180 7.5 Positive evaluation of EU membership by left–right position . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 181 7.6 Attribution of economic responsibility by prospective economic assessment . . . . 184 7.7 Attribution of economic responsibility by left–right position . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 185 List of tables 2.1 Sample size and interview mode of EES surveys . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44 2.2 Key variables used to measure the economic vote . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48 3.1 Prime ministers’ parties model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 74 4.1 Components of institutional and government clarity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95 4.2 Alternative government clarity models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100 5.1 Variation in party position over time . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 123 5.2 Regression model predicting general left–right position . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 127 5.3 Left–right and extreme tendency by year and voter group . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 133 5.4 Directional and extreme tendency along economic dimension . . . . . . . . . . . . . 136 5.5 Directional and extreme tendency along social dimension . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 139 xii Abbreviations BNP British National Party CDU Christian Democratic Union (Germany) CHES Chapel Hill Expert Survey CSU Christian Social Union (Germany) ECB European Central Bank EES European Election Studies EU European Union GDP Gross domestic product IMF International Monetary Fund MSZP Hungarian Socialist Party PASOK Panhellenic Socialist Movement (Greece) ParlGov Parliaments and Governments Database PDY Political Data Yearbook (European Journal of Political Science) SGP Stability and Growth Pact Syriza Coalition of the Radical Left (Greece) UK United Kingdom xiii Introduction The Great Recession of 2007–09 was a deep global recession that severely harmed the world economy. It has been described as the worst economic crisis since the Great Depression of the 1930s, both in general (Reinhart and Rogoff 2009, 208) and in Europe specifically (European Commission 2009, iii). In many European countries, the period following this recession has been characterised by political upheaval and many incumbent governments have lost power as a result (Kriesi 2014). This can seemingly be explained by the theory of economic voting, which predicts that voters’ support for incumbent governments is linked to good economic conditions (Key 1961; Fiorina 1981; van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin 2007; Duch and Stevenson 2008). This simple idea is so well established that it has been described as ‘virtually a social science law’ (Duch 2007, 805). Nonetheless, there are still open questions about economic voting. As the theory was developed after the Great Depression, it is not yet known whether the economic voting effect operates in the same way during a severe global recession than it does at more normal times. The main question motivating this thesis is: was the economic vote during the Great Recession different from that at other times? Since many of the elections following the crisis coincided with deeply unpopular austerity programmes (Kriesi 2014), the thesis also examines whether this austerity played any role in influencing voters’ attitudes and intentions. The Great Recession began with the financial crisis in the United States sparked by the subprime mortgage lending practices of US banks (European Commission 2009, 1). The European Union was strongly affected, with the whole EU entering a fifteen-month recession from early 2008. Although this period ended in mid-2009, it was succeeded by a further recession in late 2011 and yet another in 2012. The Eurozone remained in recession throughout the entire period from late 2011 until early 2013.1 In several of these countries, government funds were used to bail out banking sectors at risk of collapse (62). Austerity programmes were 1 These figures are based on OECD seasonally adjusted quarterly GDP growth rate data, using the common definition of a recession as two or more consecutive quarters of negative growth. 1 2 INTRODUCTION widely implemented. In the following years, a number of governments suffered memorable defeats at the ballot box (Kriesi 2014). Decades of economic voting theory have established that voters punish governments electorally when economic conditions are poor but the Great Recession is of a much greater scale and severity than the typical national recessions that have informed much of this theory. The last comparable event was the Great Depression of the 1930s, and although there have been studies of that time (e.g. Lindvall 2013, 2014), they are fundamentally limited by the lack of any data beyond the electoral results and primitive economic indicators of the time. The purpose of this thesis is to study electoral behaviour in the European Union during the Great Recession and to determine whether voters responded to economic dissatisfaction the same way then as they have at other times. The Great Recession and its after-effects have played out differently in every country. It is worth taking a closer look at some of the countries that were most deeply affected in order to gain an understanding of the ways that governments and voters responded to the unfolding situation. One of the most striking examples of an electoral backlash took place in Ireland. Ireland was the first European country to enter recession, beginning in the second quarter of 2007 and, but for a short reprieve in late 2007, remaining in recession until the end of 2009.2 Unemployment more than doubled in the space of a few years, the rate rising from 6.4 percent in 2008 to 14.7 percent in 2011.3 In 2009, 100 000 workers took to the streets of Dublin to protest the government’s plan to levy the pensions of public sector employees to make up for declining government revenue (BBC News 2009). Irish banks were heavily damaged by the global financial crisis and later in 2009, the Irish government was forced to nationalise the Anglo-Irish Bank to prevent its collapse, after other banks had already been bailed out (Connor, Flavin and O’Kelly 2012). The first opportunity that Irish voters had to respond to these events was the general election of 25 February 2011. This election proved catastrophic for Fianna Fáil, the leading party of the coalition government at the time and the party which had held the Irish premiership for all but eighteen of the 79 years between 1932 and 2011. At the 2011 election, Fianna Fáil lost more than half of its vote compared to the previous election and was reduced from 78 to a mere twenty seats in the Dáil Éireann (O’Malley 2012). Although they have increased their support from that low at the 2016 election, they still received less than one quarter of the vote (Irish Times 2016), showing that they have still not recovered from most of the damage. 2 3 According to OECD quarterly GDP data. According to OECD annual unemployment rate data. 3 One of the countries that has been most severely affected by the crisis is Greece. The Greek crisis has been characterised by high levels of sovereign debt and the inability of the Greek government to repay or service that debt. Greece suffered an exceptionally long period of recession, with negative or zero quarterly GDP growth rates in all but two quarters of the six years from mid-2007 to mid-2013, according to OECD figures. In light of increasing concern that Greece would be unable to repay its sovereign debt, the so-called Troika of the European Commission, European Central Bank (ECB) and International Monetary Fund (IMF) offered Greece a series of bailout loans (European Commission 2010, 2012). These loans were conditional on the implementation of a package of austerity measures, including privatisation and structural reforms. The measures were deeply unpopular with the Greek public, leading to mass protests. One survey found that 29 percent of the Greek population had participated in anti-austerity protests (Rüdig and Karyotis 2014, 488). The economic instability in Greece has been matched by political instability, with five general elections having taken place in the years 2009–15. The first election took place on 4 October 2009, during the recession but before the debt crisis took hold. The centre-left Panhellenic Socialist Movement (PASOK) was able to secure an absolute majority of votes and took government from the centre-right New Democracy party (Mavrogordatos and Marantzidis 2010). Two elections were held in 2012, after the bailout loans had been accepted and the austerity programme had begun to be implemented. The first election took place on 6 May but as no government could be formed, fresh elections were held on 17 June. The result of this election was that a grand coalition was formed in which New Democracy and PASOK shared power along with a third party, Democratic Left. This coalition was was explicitly pro-European and had the objective of keeping the anti-austerity Coalition of the Radical Left (Syriza) out of power (Mylonas 2013). This effort was ultimately futile, as Syriza gained enough seats in the election of 25 January 2015 to form a new government with the support of the right-wing populist Independent Greeks. This new coalition was re-elected in the September elections of the same year (Aslanidis and Kaltwasser 2016). In effect, Greek voters have rejected not just the party in power at the time the crisis began but the entire political mainstream. Not all countries that were deeply affected by the Great Recession experienced such turmoil. The United Kingdom was also hit very hard by the crisis but the political effects were less severe than in Ireland and Greece. The UK was in recession for eighteen months between early 2008 and late 2009.4 The unemployment rate rose from 5.3 percent in 2007 to 8.0 percent in 4 According to OECD quarterly GDP data. 4 INTRODUCTION 2011, before slowly falling again to its pre-crisis level by 2015; youth unemployment peaked at 21.3 percent in 2015.5 Two general elections have been held in the UK since the beginning of the crisis. The first took place on 6 May 2010. In this election, the incumbent Labour Party lost a considerable portion of its support, with its vote share reduced to 29.0 percent, a 6.2 point decline since the preceding election (Whitaker 2011). Despite the use of a majoritarian electoral system, no party received a majority of seats but the Conservatives were able to form a centre-right coalition with the centrist Liberal Democrats. At the second election, which took place on 7 May 2015, the Conservatives were able to form a government in their own right and the Labour Party recovered some of its vote, with a 1.5 point increase in support (BBC News 2015). Thus although there was a change of government, this was nothing like the severe collapse in support faced by the incumbent party in Ireland or the reconfiguration of the party system in Greece. In all of these cases it may seem obvious that the incumbent governments suffered defeats because they were in power at a time when economic conditions worsened considerably. This would be the classic economic voting response, in which voters sanction governments for failing to prevent an economic crisis. This is a reasonable interpretation but there are other interpretations that ought to be considered as well. In the case of the United Kingdom, the Labour Party had already been in power for thirteen years by the time of the 2010 election, an unusually long tenure for a Labour government as no Labour government had previously served more than six years and a few months. Furthermore, this was the first election faced by Gordon Brown, who had succeeded Tony Blair as prime minister and who was less charismatic than his predecessor. In other words, had there been no recession, Labour may well have lost the election anyway. The sheer magnitude of Fianna Fáil’s defeat makes it difficult to deny that the Irish result was related to the crisis. Similarly, the fact that the grand coalition of Greek mainstream parties has failed to hold on to office is strongly suggestive of a crisis response in Greece. Even so, an economic vote would normally be expected to benefit the main opposition party, which in this case was also clearly rejected. Furthermore, voters may well have been reacting to the unpopular austerity measures as much as or more than the recession itself. This thesis aims to shed new light on economic voting theory by testing these alternative explanations. Although there is an enormous economic voting literature showing that voters do tend to vote against incumbent parties when economic conditions are poor,6 these results have not been thoroughly tested in the context of a global economic crisis. This means that 5 6 According to OECD annual unemployment rate and youth unemployment rate data. This literature is discussed in Chapter 1. 5 it is not yet known whether the economic voting response is stronger in such a context or whether there are spillover effects, such as a loss of support for mainstream non-government parties. It has previously been hypothesised that the economic vote may operate differently in different economic contexts (Stevenson 2002, 45) and the Great Recession offers an ideal opportunity to test this hypothesis. Furthermore, economic voting theory has little to say about the electoral response to the austerity measures that played such a large role in the political response to both the Great Depression and the Great Recession. These are the key questions motivating to this thesis. To what degree, if any, does the electoral response to the Great Recession differ from the ordinary economic voting response and how much of this can be attributed to austerity measures rather than the economic conditions themselves? In order to examine these questions, this thesis uses data from several sources. The most important of these is the European Election Studies (EES) voter surveys. These are surveys of approximately one thousand respondents in each European Union member state. A wave of the EES surveys has been collected shortly after each set of elections to the European Parliament since 1979. Three of these waves are used in this thesis. The first, the 2004 wave, took place a few years before the beginning of the Great Recession. The 2009 wave was collected at a time when most of the countries had entered recession. The final wave, collected in 2014, took place in the aftermath of the crisis, when many countries were still in recession and once the effects of the austerity programmes had been widely felt. In other words, these three time points represent the before, during and after periods of the Great Recession. The EES data includes a number of questions that make it suitable for measuring the level of economic voting propensity. The EES survey data is also supplemented with aggregate data, most notably from the Parliaments and Governments Database (ParlGov). Multi-level modelling is used to estimate economic voting effects across the 25 countries that had joined the EU in 2004 or earlier. This thesis consists of eight chapters. Chapter 1 reviews the economic voting literature and explains the theoretical model informing this study. This chapter argues for a sociotropic model of economic voting and for an individual-level study using party support rather than vote choice as the dependent variable. It argues that both the prospective and retrospective theories of economic voting have merit but that a prospective approach is appropriate for this thesis because asking people in 2009 how they felt the economy had changed over he past twelve months is not very informative, since there is broad agreement in most of the studied countries that the economy had become worse in that period. This chapter also outlines the 6 INTRODUCTION two-stage model of vote choice according to which voters form an assessment about the economic conditions in their country, which in turn influences their level of support for each of the parties in their country, this preference finally determining their vote choice. This theoretical model informs the empirical model developed in later chapters to measure the economic vote. Chapter 2 explains in depth the data and methods used throughout the rest of the thesis. The chapter discusses how the economic vote is measured using multilevel analysis to predict an individual’s level of support for the parties in his or her country. The term ‘economic vote’ is used throughout this thesis to mean the degree to which an individual’s current support for government parties relative to opposition parties is affected by his or her economic perceptions. This means that there need not be an actual election in order to speak of the economic vote in a given year. The chapter also discusses the choice of datasets in more depth as well as the details of how the key variables have been measured. The remaining chapters discuss the results of the analysis. Chapter 3 compares the economic vote in 2004, 2009 and 2014. In this chapter, a multilevel model is developed to measure the effect of a change in prospective economic assessment on a voter’s levels of support for each of the parties in their country. This model is used to show that support for incumbent parties is positively associated and support for opposition parties negatively associated with an individual’s prospective economic assessment, as economic voting theory predicts. It goes on to show that this effect was stronger in 2004, before the Great Recession, than it was in 2009, when the recession was at its peak. It further shows that the economic voting effect was stronger in 2014 in the aftermath of the recession than in 2009, although not as strong as in 2004. These results are contrary to expectations and some of the implications are discussed. Potential explanations for this result are explored throughout the remainder of the thesis. Chapter 4 is concerned with explaining why some countries experienced a stronger economic voting effect than others. There is a body of evidence that certain political institutions afford greater clarity of responsibility than others, making it easier for voters to apportion blame and so strengthening the economic voting effect in those countries. For example, in the United Kingdom, the majoritarian electoral system, the weak upper house and the procedural norms together have the effect that prime ministers are almost always in a position to implement their preferred legislation without having to negotiate with a number of other actors. In Germany, by contrast, federal chancellors usually have to contend with coalition partners, a powerful upper house and a parliamentary committee system not necessarily controlled by their party. As a result, it is not surprising that British voters are more willing than German 7 voters to hold their governments to account for poor economic conditions. This chapter investigates whether clarity of responsibility can also explain the variation between countries in their response to the Great Recession. The only clarity effect that is found is that the economic vote is stronger in countries where the government is more ideologically cohesive. Even this clarity effect was depressed during the recession. Chapter 5 examines which parties benefited from the Great Recession. Earlier chapters have established the presence of economic voting during that time, meaning that incumbent parties suffered a loss of support when voters believed the economy would worsen. This raises the question of which parties those voters turned to and it is this question that this chapter addresses. It is variously claimed that extreme parties, left-wing parties and Eurosceptic parties ought to be the beneficiaries of any post-crisis change in party support. This chapter puts these claims to the test by classifying each of the parties in the study and examining whether parties in any particular group are more likely than other parties to gain support from voters pessimistic about the economy. It is found that the biggest beneficiaries of the recession were Eurosceptic parties and parties further from the centre than the mainstream. As well as the economic voting behaviours discussed up to this point, there is also the possibility that voters have chosen to respond to the dire economic situation by withdrawing from voting altogether. Chapter 6 investigates the possibility of an economic abstention effect. There is an existing body of evidence suggesting that poor economic conditions do depress turnout but, as with economic voting, there have been very few studies of this effect in the context of a severe transnational crisis. This chapter tests the hypotheses that there was an economic abstention effect in all three years of the study and that the size of this effect was greater during the crisis than it was at other times. Although the economic abstention effect was found to exist, it was also found that this effect was weaker during the crisis before becoming stronger than even previously in the years following. The preceding chapters found that the strongest changes in attitudes and intentions mostly took place too late to be attributed to the crisis alone, suggesting that the austerity introduced in response to the crisis may also have played an important role. Chapter 7 tests this hypothesis by examining attitudes towards the EU and European integration as well as how responsible voters believe the EU is for the economy. Given the highly visible role of European institutions in negotiating austerity programmes with several countries as a condition of bailout loans, it is expected that any anti-austerity sentiment would influence this attitude. It is shown that 8 INTRODUCTION support for European institutions and further integration fell in the years following the crisis and voters became increasingly likely to believe that the EU is responsible for the economy. Finally, Chapter 8 draws these various threads together to offer a coherent explanation of European electoral behaviour before, during and after the Great Recession. Several possible explanations for these results are discussed and the merits of each examined. It is argued that the best explanation for these results is that the electoral response to the austerity measures imposed in many countries was stronger than the response to the recession itself. It seems that voters were able to be relatively forgiving of a crisis that spread to Europe from overseas but they were less forgiving of their governments’ management of the crisis and unwilling to accept the austerity programmes that many of those governments implemented. This has implications for economic voting theories, which usually assume that specific policy measures are of little import to voters as it is only the outcomes that interest them. Chapter 1 Theory of economic voting: how economic conditions shape the vote Few theories in political science have been as successful as the theory of economic voting. Economic voting effects have been observed time and time again, at numerous times and in numerous countries. As Raymond Duch puts it, ‘it has now become virtually a social science law that the economy is one of the most important influences on how individuals vote’ (Duch 2007, 805). Despite, or perhaps because of, this success, there are numerous variant theories of economic voting. Some argue that economic voters are trying to select the best possible party to govern them; others that they are simply trying to reward or punish the incumbent government for its performance. Some theories posit that voters look to the future condition of the economy; others that they simply react to its past performance. It has been theorised that economic voters are only concerned with their own situation but it has also been theorised that they also take into account the conditions of others. Moreover, economic voting suffers from an instability problem (Lewis-Beck and Paldam 2000). What this means is that measurements of the strength of the economic vote have a tendency to be very sensitive to both the country and the time of the measurement, although there is no obvious reason why this should be the case. Attempts to solve this problem have led to even more formulations of economic voting theory, such as the idea that certain institutional arrangements are more conducive to economic voting than others. This chapter reviews these competing theories in the light of the existing empirical evidence in order to construct the specific economic voting theory that informs this thesis. This chapter begins with an overview of economic voting, explaining what it is and briefly discussing the history of the theory. The next sections examine some of the key disputes in the literature. The first of these is whether the economic vote should be modelled using objective economic indicators or voters’ perceptions of the current economic conditions. The second 9 10 CHAPTER 1. THEORY OF ECONOMIC VOTING Figure 1.1: Basic principle of economic voting The central idea of economic voting theory is that a strong economy benefits the incumbent electorally and a weak economy benefits the opposition. This implies that a person’s vote choice is affected differently by the prevailing economic conditions depending on which parties are currently in power. is whether economic voters are egocentric, that is to say entirely concerned with their own situation, or sociotropic, which means at least partially concerned with the well-being of others. The next debate is whether economic voting is prospective or retrospective in orientation, in other words, whether voters are more concerned with the likely future trajectory of the economy or with its history. Following that, there is a discussion of the process of vote choice formation, where it is argued that economic voting should be studied in terms of party support rather than final vote choice. Then there is a discussion of the two basic logics of economic voting that have been proposed. These are the sanctioning models and the selection models, which offer different explanations as to what individual economic voters intend to achieve through their actions. Following this, there is a review of the literature about economic voting during the Great Recession. It will be shown that there is a need for a cross-national individual-level study that explicitly compares economic voting during the Great Recession to that at other times. Finally, it will be shown how these threads fit together to form the cohesive theory that underpins this work. 1.1 What is economic voting? The fundamental claim of economic voting theory is that voters are more likely to support the incumbent government when the economy is performing well and more likely to support opposition parties when the economy is performing badly. This idea is illustrated in Figure 1.1, which is intended to be general enough to describe any variant of the theory suitable for a multiparty system. As the diagram shows, a person’s vote choice is influenced by the current 1.1. WHAT IS ECONOMIC VOTING? 11 economic conditions and, crucially, the precise nature of this influence depends on which party or parties are currently incumbent. Without this interaction, a strong economy would always benefit the same party but the theory predicts that a strong economy benefits whichever party happens to be in power. The term ‘economic vote’ refers to this interaction throughout this thesis. In a strictly two-party context, such as the United States, this model can be, and frequently is, simplified further so that the interaction can be eliminated entirely and the model simply becomes support for the government relative to support for the opposition depends on the prevailing economic conditions. It will be shown later in this chapter that this is not an appropriate model for the multiparty systems analysed in this thesis. Before proceeding to discuss specific aspects of this theory, it is worth briefly discussing the historical development of the idea of economic voting. Economic voting has a long history of being studied. Some of the earliest studies were published during the Great Depression, although the term ‘economic voting’ was not used until much later. Tibbitts (1931), building upon an even earlier study (Rice 1928, cited in Tibbitts 1931), found evidence that changes in incumbent vote share at US congressional elections can be partly explained by fluctuations in economic conditions. This study is unusual for such an early paper in that the ideas it presents are very similar to economic voting as it understood today. Another early study of economic voting was conducted by Pearson and Myers (1948), who found that price indices compared favourably to opinion polls as a predictor of US presidential elections, with high inflation aiding the challenger and low inflation the incumbent. On the other hand, Wilkinson and Hart (1950) found almost no correlation between incumbent vote share at presidential elections and an index of economic activity. There was little agreement at this stage not only about results but also about which parties should benefit from good economic conditions. Many studies of the relationship between electoral behaviour and economic conditions were looking for party-specific effects rather than the incumbent effects that characterise economic voting and which have come to be expected today. For example, during Franklin D. Roosevelt’s presidency and motivated by his depression-era social and economic reforms, there were studies seeking to determine which groups had the greatest support for Roosevelt, finding that poorer counties (Ogburn and Coombs 1940) and counties that had been most severely affected by the depression (Gosnell and Colman 1940) were most likely to support the president. Other studies anticipated that voters would turn to the left when economic conditions are poor and to the right when conditions are good, finding some support for this hypothesis in US election results at US pres- 12 CHAPTER 1. THEORY OF ECONOMIC VOTING idential (Kerr 1944) and congressional (Rees et al. 1962) elections. There is little discussion from this period of economic voting outside the United States and that is not well-developed. The idea that the fate of the contemporary Conservative government in the United Kingdom might depend on economic conditions is explored by Durant (1965), the then-director of the UK Gallup Poll, who quotes newspapers as the source of this idea, but it is not clear whether this is expected because of that party’s political orientation or because of its incumbency. Even though these ideas have largely been supplanted by the incumbent-focused theory of economic voting, studies of this kind still appear occasionally. Carlsen (2000), for example, analysed the effect of unemployment and inflation rates on quarterly opinion polls in the US, the UK, Canada and Australia, arguing that left- and right-wing parties are affected differently by different kinds of economic adversity. This debate was reignited when Kramer (1971) published a study introducing multivariate statistical analysis to this question. This marked a shift away from the basic cross-tabulation and correlation analyses of earlier studies but Kramer’s work continued in the tradition of analysing aggregate data sources, namely incumbent vote share and various economic measures such as unemployment, income and price indices. He found a positive relationship between real income and incumbent vote share in elections to the US House of Representatives. Shortly afterwards, Stigler (1973) published a refutation, using similar methods to argue that this relationship actually does not exist and theorising that it ought not exist in any case, as in his view the two major parties in the United States are equally driven to manage unemployment and inflation. Arcelus and Meltzer (1975) also found only weak evidence of any link between aggregate economic conditions and the vote shares of the major US parties. Tufte (1975) on the other hand found results consistent with Kramer’s, in that US midterm election results were influenced by economic conditions. In an effort to explain these inconsistent findings, Bloom and Price (1975) hypothesised that economic conditions affect voter behaviour much more during times of deprivation than during times of prosperity. Their findings seemed to confirm this hypothesis and they argued that voters were inclined to punish governments for poor conditions at US House elections but not to reward them for better conditions. Even this did not settle the debate, and further research found no important relationship between US presidential vote share and economic conditions (Fair 1978). Economic voting soon became a major focus of study within the discipline. Not only did the literature expand considerably but various competing theories of economic voting arose. Kinder and Kiewiet (1981) proposed the sociotropic voting theory, which rejects the older 1.2. PERCEPTIONS OR INDICATORS 13 egocentric voting theory and argues that voters are concerned, to at least some degree, with the conditions of others, not just themselves. Fiorina (1981) brought new attention to Downs’ (1957) idea that economic voting could be explained by a rational model of selection, which offered an alternative to the then-dominant idea that economic voting was an act of punishment or reward (Key 1961, 1964, 1966). Since the theory developed in so many different directions, rather than continuing chronologically, this chapter will proceed thematically. Each of the key debates is discussed in turn, along with any empirical evidence that sheds light on the competing approaches and a discussion of how these developments are relevant for this thesis. 1.2 Perceptions or indicators: the link between the economy and the vote Economic voting theory naturally raises questions about the nature of the link between the prevailing economic conditions and the individual’s vote choice. For example, what sorts of economic privations are voters sensitive too? Are these all equal? Do voters see these as separate issues or facets of a cohesive economy issue? The answers to these questions typically fall into one of two categories. The first category posits that voters respond to material changes in well-being, which can be measured by standard economic indicators, such as inflation or unemployment rates. The second category proposes that voters form an overall impression of the condition of the economy and it is this impression that influences their vote choice. For example, even if all of the economic indicators for a given year are positive, a particular voter might be under the impression that the economy has worsened over the past year, leading that voter to turn against the government. This might be the case if that voter’s personal experience of the economy was bad or if the sources of information relied upon by that voter gave a distorted impression of the true situation. There are further related questions, such as whether voters are exclusively concerned with their personal situation or whether they are concerned with the economy more broadly and also whether voters are primarily influenced by their assessment of past economic performance or their expectations of future economic performance. These related questions are discussed in the following sections. This section examines the relative merits of the economic indicators and individual perceptions theories of economic voting and explains why the perceptions approach is preferred in this thesis. The different approaches offer contrasting benefits. While it is naturally true that voters can only respond to their own perceptions of the economic situation, if these perceptions are 14 CHAPTER 1. THEORY OF ECONOMIC VOTING highly accurate, then an unnecessary link can be eliminated from the theoretical model of economic voting behaviour. Indicator-based theories also lend themselves well to macro-level empirical studies, where individual evaluations are not available in any case. Furthermore, since most countries collect data pertaining to multiple different aspects of the economy, an indicator-based theory can make empirically testable claims about how voters react to different kinds of economic privation. For example, it is sometimes argued that voters are more sensitive to unemployment when the incumbent government is left-leaning and inflation when rightleaning (Powell and Whitten 1993, 404–405; Whitten and Palmer 1999; van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin 2007, 59). Empirical efforts to pin down these sorts of differences have not, however, been overwhelmingly successful. For example, Chappell and Veiga (2000) examined 136 elections in thirteen European countries between 1960 and 1997 and were able to find significant economic voting effects for inflation but not for other kinds of economic problems. Another study examined quarterly opinion polls from Australia, Canada, the United Kingdom and the United States, finding that voters were more tolerant of inflation than unemployment when right-wing governments were in power, but there were no conclusive results for leftwing governments (Carlsen 2000). A recent study of OECD elections between 1975 and 2013 has also found a difference between patterns of economic voting for left-wing and right-wing governments but in this case it was found that voters were more tolerant of inflation when leftwing governments were in power (Bouvet and King 2016, 76). These findings are obviously contradictory and it may well be that there is no systematic pattern of differences in economic voting according to the ideology of the governing parties. On the other hand, if voters’ perceptions of the economy are substantially distorted, then omitting the perception formation process from the theory will cause problems, which may explain the inconsistent findings discussed above. Furthermore, given the notorious instability problem of economic voting studies, it is worth reconsidering some traditional strong assumptions, as they may provide some helpful clues. If it is in fact the case that voters’ perceptions are distorted, then both the link between objective conditions and voters’ perceptions of those conditions and the link between perceptions and vote choice ought to be studied carefully in order to understand economic voting. Much therefore hinges on whether voters accurately perceive economic conditions. This was studied by Paldam and Nannestad (2000), who found that Danish respondents mostly knew little about the state of the economy, in terms of indicators like unemployment, inflation and foreign date rates (Paldam and Nannestad 2000). This is problematic for an indicator-based theory, since if voters do not know how those indicators 1.2. PERCEPTIONS OR INDICATORS 15 are moving, then it is difficult to see how they could condition their votes. In response to these findings, Sanders (2000) looked at voters’ assessments of the overall condition of the economy in the United Kingdom between 1974 and 1997. He found that, although voters typically have little awareness of specific economic facts, their assessments of the general state of the economy tend to be remarkably accurate. Taken together, these findings suggest that a perception-based theory of economic voting is more promising than an indicator-based theory. On the other hand, it has also been found, in an aggregate study of German electoral behaviour, that hidden unemployment as well as official unemployment harms support for the governing parties (Feld and Kirchgässner 2000). It is thus possible that the evident lack of knowledge of official statistics does not represent mass ignorance of the true state of the economy. Nonetheless, even if it is true that voter perceptions are in some respects a better reflection of the economic reality than the official statistics, this just strengthens the argument that published economic indicators are a flawed tool for understanding the economic vote. It has also been argued that, even though the average voter may have no incentive to learn about the condition of the economy, there is a subset of informed voters that does have such an incentive and this subset could be sufficient to explain the economic voting effect (Aidt 2000). Only a theory that includes perceptions can properly account for this possibility. One difficulty with a perception-based theory is that it has been theorised that voters have a tendency to filter the information that they pay attention to based on their prior beliefs about the incumbent government. Government supporters are more likely to be receptive to news that supports the belief that the economy is being managed well than to news challenging that belief, while the opposite is true for opposition supporters. If this is the case then this produces a potential endogeneity problem since, according to this model, a citizen’s vote choice both influences and is influenced by his or her perceptions of the economy. This point has produced considerable concern in the literature (e.g. Wlezien, Franklin and Twiggs 1997; Evans and Andersen 2006; Evans and Pickup 2010) and has been particularly forcefully expressed by van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin (2007, 26). The empirical evidence, however, suggests that this is much less of a problem in practice than it might appear. As part of their detailed study of the economic vote, Duch and Stevenson (2008, 123–126) compared their key models to variants specifically designed to account for any endogeneity effects in voters’ economic perceptions and found no evidence of systematic bias in the results of the naive models. Other attempts to exogenise economic perceptions have similarly confirmed the existence of the 16 CHAPTER 1. THEORY OF ECONOMIC VOTING economic vote (Lewis-Beck, Nadeau and Elias 2008; Lewis-Beck, Stubager and Nadeau 2013; Hansford and Gomez 2015; Stevenson and Duch 2013, 318).1 1.3 Sociotropic voting: do voters only care about themselves? A related question is whether voters are concerned with the broader economy or merely their own personal well-being when they vote economically. As discussed earlier in this chapter, many of the early studies of economic voting used aggregate data to demonstrate a link between economic conditions and voter support for the incumbent government. These early studies typically gave no account of the individual behaviour that gave rise to these largescale patterns and it fell to later scholars to produce theories to explain these trends. A common assumption was that individuals respond to changes in their own personal conditions. Thus, if many people become worse off, both the government’s vote share and the national measures of economic well-being decline simultaneously. Conversely, if many people become better off, these indicators improve together. This is what is meant by egocentric (or pocketbook) voting—voters consider only their own personal circumstances, or perhaps those of their friends and family. Although these early studies rarely made explicit an assumption of egocentric voting, it tends to be apparent in their models. For example, Tufte (1978, 127–134) breaks down the vote at the US presidential elections of 1968, 1972 and 1976 by income and family financial situation. Similarly, Bloom and Price (1975, 1243) produced a model in which the short-term variations in voting behaviour are primarily explained by short-term changes in real income. In their influential book The American Voter, Campbell et al. (1960) also make the claim that political behaviour, at least in some spheres, can be explained in terms of ‘primitive self-interest’ (205). Again, their analysis focuses on the way that voting behaviour changes in response to changes in personal economic conditions (381–401). Although egocentric voting was widely assumed, the theory was rarely put to the test. When Fiorina (1978) did test the egocentric voting hypothesis using individual-level survey data, he failed to find support for it. Similarly, in a study of voting in US congressional elections between 1956 and 1976, Kinder and Kiewiet (1979, 521) found little support for the idea that an individual’s vote choice was materially affected by any economic troubles that individual had personally experienced. In order to explain this, and in light of the evidence 1 It should also be noted that it is not the purpose of this thesis to establish the absolute size of the economic vote but rather to determine whether economic voting was different during the Great Recession. The substantive results of this thesis should thus be unaffected by any inflation in the estimates of the size of the economic vote owing to an endogeneity effect, unless that effect was itself affected by the recession. 1.3. SOCIOTROPIC VOTING: DO VOTERS ONLY CARE ABOUT THEMSELVES? 17 that a government’s fortunes are tied to the economic conditions it presides over, they theorises that voters respond more to national economic conditions than to their own personal conditions (524). That is, voters do hold governments to account for the state of the economy but not necessarily for the individual economic events in their own lives. A later study found further evidence for what they refer to as sociotropic voting (Kinder and Kiewiet 1981). Using a panel study of voters at the 1972, 1974 and 1976 US elections (congressional and, other than in 1974, presidential), they once again tested the egocentric voting hypothesis. Again, they found that sociotropic voting better explains their observations than egocentric voting. Although they note that presidential elections have often provided more support for egocentric voting than congressional elections (147), they conclude that ‘for presidential voting even more completely than for congressional voting, citizens’ assessments of national economic conditions—their sociotropic judgements—overwhelm economic grievances encountered in private life’ (148). Although it is used here in contrast with the term egocentric, the term sociotropic does not simply mean altruistic. That would suggest that sociotropic voters act purely in the interests of others and pay no heed to their own interests. Rather, the term was coined to mean ‘taking some account—we needn’t say exactly how much—of other persons’ interests or, if you like, of the collective’s interest’ (Meehl 1977, 14). So, both theories accept that voters heed their own interests to some degree. Sociotropic voters do not necessarily ignore their own interests but they do give some consideration to the interests of others. The key difference between egocentric and sociotropic theories of voting is how the individual voter behaves. According to the egocentric theories, a voter will react to changes in his or her personal conditions. So a voter who loses his or job, for example, will be more likely to vote against the government than one who keeps his or her job, irrespective of the unemployment rate. The sociotropic theories, on the other hand, predict that the voter who just lost his or her job is not much more likely than anyone else to vote against the government but if the unemployment rate goes up then this will mobilise voters, employed or otherwise, to vote against the government. The sociotropic theory of economic voting was criticised by Kramer (1983), who argued that the evidence offered in support of this theory was insufficient to reject the null hypothesis of egocentric voting. In his view, this evidence is merely a ‘statistical artifact’ (93). Despite these early objections, sociotropic voting has become the consensus position in the literature as the evidence has mounted (Nannestad and Paldam 1994). This consensus appeared to be under threat when Nannestad and Paldam (1995, 1997a) published two studies finding a 18 CHAPTER 1. THEORY OF ECONOMIC VOTING stronger egocentric than sociotropic economic voting effect in Denmark. This was so unexpected that this result has been described as ‘virtually unique in the literature’ (Lewis-Beck, Stubager and Nadeau 2013, 501). Even these findings have been disputed on methodological grounds (Hibbs 1993, 62–63) and several later attempts to replicate this results have reached the contrary conclusion (Borre 1997; Lewis-Beck, Stubager and Nadeau 2013; Stubager et al. 2014). In light of this, it now appears that Denmark is no exception to the usual pattern of sociotropic voting. Finally, there is also some evidence that the centre of focus for the economic vote may lie somewhere between the individual and the entire nation (Rogers 2014). This idea that voters are ‘communotropic’—mostly concerned with the economic conditions of their own communities—is interesting but has not yet been thoroughly tested in its own right, unlike the sociotropic theory. Furthermore, this approach would pose measurement difficulties, since communotropic economic assessment questions are not currently common in survey instruments. Given the considerable body of evidence that has been accumulated in support of the sociotropic hypothesis, this thesis uses a sociotropic theory of economic voting. 1.4 Prospective and retrospective voting Retrospective voting and prospective voting are the ideas that voters base their vote choice on an assessment of the incumbent government’s past performance or an expectation of the government’s likely future performance respectively. In many respects, the prospective voting hypothesis is a more natural one than the retrospective voting hypothesis. A rational voter, after all, ought to be more concerned with the future, which can still be influenced, than the past, which cannot. Most retrospective studies do not give an explicit rationale for the decision to use that approach but among those that do, there appear to be two main justifications. The first is the idea that voters are not trying to rationally select the party that will produce the most favourable outcomes but rather to simply reward or punish the incumbent for its successes or failures. The relative merits of the selection and sanctioning models of economic voting are discussed later in this chapter. For now, it suffices to say that the sanctioning model is not accepted by this thesis. The second justification for a retrospective theory is that, while the rational voter is indeed trying to select the party most likely to deliver the desired outcomes, past performance is simply a cheaper and more accessible means of assessing this than the alternatives (Downs 1957, 38–40). It is argued that, while past performance is only a rough measure of a party’s likely future performance, it is not worth the time and effort 1.4. PROSPECTIVE AND RETROSPECTIVE VOTING 19 for most voters to find and synthesise other sources of information to produce a better estimate. While this argument has merit, it is not actually necessary to enquire into the process of prospective assessment formation in order to understand economic voting. Why use the retrospective measure as a proxy for the prospective measure, when the latter could simply be measured directly? It should also not be ignored that citizens’ retrospective and prospective assessments of the economy are often not particularly strongly correlated (Kuklinski and West 1981; Conover, Feldman and Knight 1987). Efforts have been made to compare the prospective and retrospective theories empirically. MacKuen, Erikson and Stimson (1992) made a distinction between ‘peasants’—retrospective voters whose expectations of the trajectory of the economy are simple extrapolations of its recent performance—and ‘bankers’—prospective voters whose expectations are formed by a more sophisticated analysis. Using survey data, they attempted to determine which archetype more accurately described US voters, finding that the banker model was more accurate than the peasant model. In other words, their findings supported by the prospective theory of economic voting. They confirmed these findings in a follow up study, further noting that retrospective assessments do seem to influence future expectations to a degree but it is ultimately the future expectations that predict vote choice (Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson 2000). Recent studies have continued to find empirical support for prospective economic voting. Michelitch et al. (2012) found prospective economic assessment to be an important predictor of vote choice at both the US and Ghanaian presidential elections of 2008. The fact that they were able to make the same findings in both the US and Ghana, two very different countries, is promising, as it makes it unlikely that prospective voting is merely a quirk of American politics. A further problem for retrospective voting is that there is evidence that voters’ retrospective assessments lack some of the qualities that would be expected from rational retrospective voters. Using survey data collected from 40 countries between 1996 and 2005, Stanig (2013) has shown that several psychological biases are in play when voters form retrospective assessments of the economy. For example, voters are more likely to change their assessments in response to worsening conditions than to improving conditions (736–737). Furthermore, these assessments are also affected by partisanship and ideology, with supporters of government parties typically less likely to be critical than opponents (737–739). Strangely, however, this difference between supporters and opponents of the incumbent government is considerably weaker during a recession than at other times (739–740). It has to be acknowledged that 20 CHAPTER 1. THEORY OF ECONOMIC VOTING prospective assessments may also suffer from some of these problems as well. Unfortunately, there is little evidence either way, as most published research has focused on the retrospective assessment. A related question that has attracted recent scholarly attention is: how far back do retrospective voters look? Hellwig and Marinova (2015) surveyed voters during the 2012 US presidential election, finding that short-term and long-term retrospective assessments of the economy were approximately equally accurate, which is to say, not particularly accurate at all. They also found that neither the short-term nor the long-term assessment was a clearly superior predictor of vote choice over the other. Based on this finding, they argue that the almost universal choice of a twelve-month time window in retrospective voting studies is no worse than any other choice (884). Wlezien (2015), on the other hand, found that voters at US presidential elections between 1952 and 2012 appeared to look back approximately two years when forming the retrospective assessment that would influence their vote choice. This may well be a quirk of US elections specifically, given that partial legislative elections take place two years before every presidential election. These findings may indicate that voters are simply reflecting back on the period since the last time a federal election of some kind was held. Finally, Taniguchi (2016) studied retrospective voting during the 2013 Japanese upper house election. Based on a survey of Japanese voters, he argues that voters actually look to the long-term, slowly adjusting their perceptions over time. Unfortunately, no consensus has emerged from these studies, nor do these results shed any light on the time frames relevant to prospective voters. Nevertheless, this thesis is limited to the questions actually asked in the surveys used for its analysis. As will be seen in the next chapter, this means that the time window has to be either the year just past or the coming year, at the time of the survey. This thesis is based on a prospective theory of economic voting. Given that retrospective voting tends to be the default choice for economic voting studies, this may be a slightly surprising choice. The theoretical motivations discussed here are genuine—even if voters do use retrospective evaluations as a shortcut for forming prospective assessments, as Downs (1957) claims, it is not at all obvious that this means that those retrospective evaluations should be used as a proxy for the prospective assessments when the means are available to measure the latter directly. Nonetheless, it must also be acknowledged that there are more practical motivations for pursuing a prospective rather than a retrospective study. As will be shown in Chapter 2, there was something of a consensus among European voters in 2009 that the economy had become worse over the previous year. This lack of variance in a key independ- 1.5. THE VOTE CHOICE PROCESS 21 ent variable would have posed serious problems for statistical analysis, so the retrospective approach was not viable. Voters did, however, have a variety of opinions about the future course of the economy, so a prospective analysis was possible. In any event, the fact that the retrospective approach broke down during the Great Recession, at least for the data used by this thesis, while the prospective approach remained viable, offers empirical support for the argument that economic voting is fundamentally a prospective phenomenon, regardless of how convenient retrospective evaluations may often be as a means of quickly forming a prospective assessment. 1.5 The vote choice process The preceding sections have discussed the nature of the link between the economy and an individual’s vote choice but the mechanism by which this vote choice is made was left unspecified. Most early studies of economic voting tended to use aggregate data, so there was no need for a specific theory of individual vote choice and no means of testing such a theory anyway. These studies simply looked for relationships between the incumbent government’s vote share2 and various economic indicators. A good example of this genre is Pearson and Myers (1948), showed that the incumbent party tended to win US presidential elections if and only if the economy was strong. Aggregate studies still take place today—Carlsen (2000), for example, who showed that government vote share in four countries was linked to the unemployment rate—but they cannot shed light on the vote choice mechanism. The simplest plausible vote choice mechanism is one whereby a voter simply weighs up the strengths and weaknesses of the incumbent government and votes to return the government should its overall performance exceed some (possibly idiosyncratic) threshold and votes to reject the government otherwise. This naive picture of the vote choice process seems perfectly logical in the context of a strict two-party system, such as the United States. This approach tends to be assumed by individual-level economic voting studies. Given that the vast bulk of such studies have investigated US politics specifically, this may well explain the near universality of this approach. This approach is typically modelled using logistic or probit regression on an individual’s reported vote choice or intended vote choice. This is not only methodologically straightforward but also a natural operationalisation of this theoretical model of vote 2 Some early US studies looked at the vote share for the Republicans or the Democrats rather than the incumbent party as such. This is because the link between economic conditions and support for the incumbent government had not yet been decisively established, so these papers were testing theories about certain economic outcomes favouring specific parties. For example, Kerr (1944) found a correlation between the conservative vote and several economic indicators in the United States. 22 CHAPTER 1. THEORY OF ECONOMIC VOTING choice, which may further explain the enduring popularity of this approach. An example of this approach is Nadeau and Lewis-Beck (2001), who predicted the likelihood of US voters supporting the incumbent party’s presidential candidate under various scenarios. This theory of vote choice works well in the US context. Many countries are not two-party systems, however, and certainly most European countries have more than two parties that typically receive a non-trivial proportion of the vote. This extra complexity can be handled in several ways. The simplest way to generalise the naive vote choice model to a multiparty system is to ignore parties altogether and recast the vote choice task as voters simply making a decision to support or reject the government. Thus a vote for any coalition party is treated the same and a vote for any opposition party is treated the same. One example of this approach is Lewis-Beck (1986), who used various economic variables to predict the likelihood of voters supporting any of the incumbent government parties as opposed to any of the opposition parties at elections in France, Germany, Italy and the United Kingdom. Another example is Nadeau, Niemi and Yoshinaka (2002), who modelled this dichotomous vote choice in eight European countries. Interestingly, they found different results in the majoritarian and consensual systems that they studied (419). This could be an artefact of the forced dichotomisation of the vote choice, since majoritarian systems tend to have fewer relevant parties than consensual systems. This method heavily simplifies a complex decision. If voters really are primarily concerned with the choice between supporting and rejecting the government, then it is not clear why such complex party systems are sustainable. In that case, it would be expected that voters would simply support the largest government or opposition party and the remaining parties would be starved of votes. Yet this is not the case. An explicit theory of vote choice formation was proposed by Downs (1957, 36–50) and elaborated by van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin (2007, 31–53). According to this theory, vote choice is a two-stage process. The first stage is one of assessing party utility. For each viable party, voters estimate by some method the utility they would derive from the success of that party. This estimated party utility will be referred to as party support throughout this thesis.3 The second stage of this process is where voters actually select which party will receive their votes. This is assumed to be done by the obvious method of selecting the party that has the greatest estimated utility to the individual voter, or in other words, each voter selects the party that he or she supports most. The interesting stage is thus the first stage, in which these levels of support are established in the first place. It is important to note that a voter’s 3 This follows the usage of van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin (2007). 1.5. THE VOTE CHOICE PROCESS 23 levels of support for the various parties do not merely form an ordering between the parties but also indicate the degree to which one party is preferred over another. This is important because one of the key implications of this theory is that a particular event might cause two different voters to adjust their levels of support for a particular parties in the same direction and by precisely the same amount and yet lead to the two voters changing their vote choices in different ways or to only one voter changing his or her vote choice while the other does not. The final outcome depends not just on the immediate effect of the event on party support but also on each individual’s levels of support for the other parties in the system. It is argued that, by failing to capture this complexity, the dichotomous approaches discussed above invite or at least exacerbate the instability that has long plagued the study of economic voting (14). A further method that is sometimes used to predict vote choice in empirical studies is to generalise the two-party logistic regression model to multiple parties using techniques such as pairwise or ordered logistic regression. For example, Duch and Stevenson (2008, 42–52) measure what they call the ‘general economic vote’—the total variation in vote choice that can be explained by the economy—by using a multinomial logistic regression model to predict which of several parties would be the respondent’s vote choice. Although this is done without giving a detailed theory of vote choice, it is compatible with the party support theory outlined above. This method also has the advantage of taking into account the full complexity of the party system, unlike the dichotomous method. Nonetheless, the full party support model offers two key advantages over this approach. The first advantage is that, by modelling party support directly, it is possible to use much richer data, since a full vector of party support levels encodes much more information that a single categorical vote choice item. The second advantage is that the party support model allows important information about the party, such as its incumbency status, to be treated as independent variables, which is not possible using the ordered logistic regression method. This is particularly important for a comparative study such as this. These methodological details are the subject of the following chapter but they are worth mention here because they highlight the importance of an explicit vote choice theory. There is some empirical evidence that economic voters in multiparty systems do operate according to a more complex logic than a simple government–opposition dichotomy could describe. For example, it has been found that unionist voters in Northern Ireland in 2011 tended to base their party choice not just on the performance of the government but also on the perceived influence of each party within the governing coalition (Garry 2014). This latter aspect can be explained by the party support theory but not by the dichotomous vote choice 24 CHAPTER 1. THEORY OF ECONOMIC VOTING theory. It has also been shown that partisans of particular coalition parties tend to believe that the political position of the entire coalition is closer to the position of their preferred party than other voters do (Meyer and Strobl 2016). Furthermore, it has been found that economic voting effects are stronger for the head of government’s party than for other coalition partners (Fisher and Hobolt 2010; Debus, Stegmaier and Tosun 2014). It has also been established that the vote choice decision becomes more difficult for voters to make as the number of parties increases (Orriols and Martínez 2014). These results all suggest that voters think about parties rather than blocs and that the party rather than the coalition is thus the natural unit of analysis. Consequently, the party support theory of vote choice forms an important piece of the overall economic voting theory tested by this thesis. 1.6 Reward and punishment: the logic of sanction So far this chapter has discussed various individual aspects of economic voting but there has not yet been a discussion of the underlying logic of the phenomenon. What motivates people to vote economically and what do they hope to achieve in doing so? This section introduces the sanctioning model of economic voting, which was the first serious effort to answer these questions. It is not, however, the only possibility and the competing selection model is discussed in the following section. The sanctioning, or reward–punishment, model posits that voters seek to reward governments for good performance and punish them for bad performance. This would explain why voters are more likely to support governments when economic conditions are good than when they are bad, which is the central observation of economic voting. This theory is most strongly associated with V. O. Key, who described it thus: The patterns of flow of the major streams of shifting voters graphically reflect the electorate in its great, and perhaps principal, role as an appraiser of past events, past performance, and past actions. It judges retrospectively; it commands prospectively only insofar as it expresses either approval or disapproval of that which has happened before. Voters may reject what they have known; or they may approve what they have known. They are not likely to be attracted in great numbers by promises of the novel or unknown. Once innovation has occurred they may embrace it, even though they would have, earlier, hesitated to venture forth to welcome it. (Key 1966, 61) 1.6. REWARD AND PUNISHMENT: THE LOGIC OF SANCTION 25 In effect, he argues that election results must not be read as an endorsement of the policies of the winning party, but as a judgement of the competence of the previous government (Key 1961, 473–474; 1964, 543; 1966, 51–52). The most striking characteristic of this model is that it asserts that voters are outcomedriven rather than policy-driven. What this means is that citizens do not compare the policy packages put forward by the various parties in order to ascertain which is the best offering. It is assumed that they not have the resources to do this effectively (Fiorina 1981, 45). Accurately weighing the different claims as to which course of action will most benefit the economy4 is likely to be a demanding task for even highly educated voters. Even reading all of the party manifestos consumes more time than many people are likely to be willing to spend. On the other hand, most citizens are likely to have some idea of how well the economy has been functioning. Recessions do not tend to go unnoticed after all. In other words, comparative policy assessments are difficult to come by but assessments of government performance— assuming a link between economic outcomes and government policy—are readily accessible (9). The sanctioning voter, according to this line of thinking, thus makes the best use of the available information. A second key characteristic of the sanctioning model is that it is explicitly retrospective in orientation. According to this theory, voters are not merely looking at past performance in order to inform their future expectations. A vote is actually an expression of the voter’s assessment of the government’s past performance. Key (1961, 473) describes the public as ‘speak[ing] in disapprobation of the past policy or performance of an administration’. Elsewhere he claims that ‘[r]etrospective judgments by the electorate seem far more explicit than do its instructions for future action’ (Key 1964, 643). Thus according to this model of economic voting, citizens use their vote to signal which outcomes they deem acceptable and which they do not. For example, even if a voter expected that the economy would improve from a recent crisis under the incumbent government, the sanctioning model predicts that this voter would vote against that incumbent anyway. Doing otherwise would send the wrong message. As Duch and Stevenson (2008, 11) put it, politicians ‘anticipate that voters will sanction them if they underperform. And, to maintain the credibility of this threat, voters punish incumbents at the polls when retrospective economic performance is substandard.’ This illustrates the vote choice logic at the heart of the sanctioning model and it is a rational one. Although unremarkable today, this was an unexpected position to take in the wake of 4 Voter utility is certainly not limited to economic issues and there is no reason why a sanctioning voter would not treat failures in other areas equally harshly but non-economic issues are beyond the scope of this thesis, so this analysis will assume that the issues in question are economic ones. 26 CHAPTER 1. THEORY OF ECONOMIC VOTING highly influential work such as Campbell et al. (1960), which had argued that vote choice was driven primarily by party identification and not rationality. Key (1966, 7) admitted as much when he described his own argument as ‘perverse and unorthodox’ before adding: ‘To be sure, many individual voters act in odd ways indeed; yet in the large the electorate behaves about as rationally and responsibly as we should expect, given the clarity of the alternatives presented to it and the character of the information available to it.’ Others have produced formal models of rational individual behaviour which would produce an aggregate retrospective voting effect of the sanctioning kind. The basic idea is that voters must punish unsatisfactory outcomes in order to incentivise incumbents to act in the public interest (Barro 1973; Ferejohn 1986). It is worth noting that, for this to be effective, voters must even punish governments for poor economic outcomes even if they are personally unaffected. This has led Ferejohn (1986, 23) to argue that sociotropic voting is an essential feature of retrospective voting (23). The sanctioning model is appealing for its simplicity. It is also important to understand because it underpins so much of the early economic voting research. Nonetheless, it is not the model that will be used by this thesis. For one thing, as has already been discussed, this thesis is testing a prospective theory of economic voting, while the sanctioning model assumes a thoroughly retrospective orientation on the part of the voter. The empirical evidence that prospective voting exists (for example Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson 2000; Michelitch et al. 2012) cannot be explained by the sanctioning model. The next section introduces an alternative model, the selection model. 1.7 Competent government: the logic of selection The selection model offers an alternative explanation for the phenomenon of economic voting. The differences between the two models stem from differing assumptions about what voters intend when casting their votes. Whereas the sanctioning model asserts that voters are primarily casting a judgement upon the incumbent government, the selection model posits that voters are actually trying to select the party most likely to maximise their utility. For economic voters in particular, this means selecting the party which can most reasonably be expected to deliver positive economic outcomes. This model stems from Downs’ An Economic Theory of Democracy, in which he explains the basic challenge of voting as one of selection: When a man votes, he is helping to select the government which will govern him during the coming election period (i.e., period t + 1). Therefore as we have just 1.7. COMPETENT GOVERNMENT: THE LOGIC OF SELECTION 27 shown, he makes his decision by comparing future performances he expects from the competing parties. But if he is rational, he knows that no party will be able to do everything that it says it will do. Hence he cannot merely compare platforms; instead he must estimate in his own mind what the parties would actually do were they in power. (Downs 1957, 39) The point being made here is that if voters are assumed to behave rationally and to be motivated by selection, rather than sanction, then voter behaviour can only be understood by knowing how voters measure the expected utility of each political party. Furthermore, this is not simply a question of comparing party manifestos because they are not reliable indicators of behaviour in office. This differs greatly from the sanctioning model, which argues that voters do not think about a party’s future actions but only about its past performance. According to the selection model, voters determine the expected utility associated with each party by looking at their past performance. It is argued that this is precisely what a rational voter would do: Since one of the competing parties is already in power, its performance in period t gives him the best possible idea of what it will do in the future, assuming its policies have some continuity. But it would be irrational to compare the current performance of one party with the expected future performance of another. For a valid comparison, both performances must take place under the same conditions, i.e., in the same time period. Therefore the voter must weigh the performance that the opposition party would have produced in period t if it had been in power. (39–40) In other words, voters compare the incumbent party’s current performance—using their retrospective knowledge—to the hypothetical performance of an opposition party. It is important to note that these assessments are not based purely upon retrospective knowledge. Downs (1957, 41–45) explains that these assessments are modified by what he calls the ‘trend factor’ and ‘performance ratings’. The trend factor refers to the consideration that voters give to current events and is the device used to project retrospective knowledge into the future. For example, if it is clear that the economy is on the verge of a recession, voters are not going to ignore this simply because the economy had been otherwise well-managed up until this point. Performance ratings are only used to discriminate between two parties proposing indistinguishable platforms. In this case, voters can only contrast the past effectiveness of the parties. 28 CHAPTER 1. THEORY OF ECONOMIC VOTING The model just described was not introduced as a freestanding theory but rather formed part of Downs’ comprehensive theory of political behaviour. It was Fiorina (1981) who developed these ideas further and presented them as a coherent alternative to the sanctioning model. His description of the model is succinct: ‘In deciding how to vote, the rational citizen would compare the performance of the incumbent administration to the platform promises of the challenger rather than compare both sets of platform promises’ (46). One key difference between the sanctioning and selection models is that the latter explicitly assumes that a party’s past behaviour is a reliable predictor of its future behaviour (Downs 1957, 96–113; Fiorina 1981, 45), whereas the logic of sanctioning implies that voters expect to be able to condition the parties to behave as intended. If the parties did not respond to such cues, then there would be no reason to punish or reward them electorally. Another difference between the models is that the sanctioning model assumes that voters typically cannot compare policy platforms, whereas that selection model assumes that this can be done in principle but that it is too expensive, so retrospective information is a cheap and effective substitute (Fiorina 1981, 45–47). The selection model has been a popular choice for empirical research into economic voting beginning with Kramer (1971, 134), who argued that the ‘past performance of the incumbent party in particular gives some indication of what it would do if returned to office, and of the effectiveness of its policies and personnel’. Even his critic Stigler (1973, 165) agreed that a rational voter should predict future performance based on past performance. The selection model continues to inform recent work, such as Duch and Stevenson (2008). One of the strengths of this theory is that selection effects have proven capable of explaining why incumbent legislators can be so difficult to unseat (Ashworth 2005; Ashworth and de Mesquita 2008; Gowrisankaran, Mitchell and Moro 2008). The argument is that voters tend to return high quality legislators and replace low quality ones, so the median incumbent tends to be of a higher quality than the median candidate. This effect cannot be explained by the sanctioning model. It should be mentioned that there are some recent experiment-based studies finding support for a sanctioning effect (Huber, Hill and Lenz 2012; Woon 2012). Nonetheless, the evidence for selection effects is strong. It is also possible that the two effects exist simultaneously (Fearon 1999, 56–57). This thesis is informed by the selection model. This may be surprising, since the selection model is a retrospective theory and it is has been stated that the thesis is operating from a prospective perspective. These approaches are not contradictory, however. The selection model 1.8. POLITICAL CONTEXT AND THE INSTABILITY PROBLEM 29 assumes that voters have a prospective orientation, in that they seek to select the party most likely to produce the best outcomes. What makes it a retrospective theory is that it posits that voters use retrospective knowledge as a shortcut for forming their view as to which party this is. As mentioned earlier, Downs expects voters to augment their retrospective evaluations with a trend factor, reflecting their assumptions about the future course of present events. Given this framework, it is not unreasonable to interpret a voter’s reported prospective economic assessment as a projection of his or her retrospective economic assessment using a trend factor. The prospective interpretation of the selection model used in this thesis thus predicts that the retrospective and prospective economic evaluations are typically moderately correlated but that the prospective evaluations are the stronger predictor of party support. 1.8 Political context and the instability problem An enduring problem for economic voting research has been the instability of its findings. It has frequently been the case that promising efforts to measure the economic voting effect have produced wildly different estimates in different countries and sometimes even the same countries at different times. Explaining this instability has increasingly become a focus for research in this area (Lewis-Beck and Paldam 2000, 113–114; Dorussen and Palmer 2002, 1– 5). This instability is particularly salient for a comparative study such as this one because it is clearly not reasonable to assume that the economic vote is the same for all of the different countries under study or even that it is stable across time. An understanding of political context is thus important and this section reviews what is already known about the impact of context on the economic vote. Non-contextual explanations for the instability problem have also been proposed. For example, van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin (2007, 16) argue that model misspecification is the principle cause of this instability5 but even if true, this does not mean that context does not also play a role. Voter heterogeneity has also been proposed as a possible cause of the instability problem (Dorussen and Palmer 2002, 7) but these possibilities are beyond the scope of this thesis.6 One way to take into account contextual differences is simply to model them without trying to explain them. For example, if the model allows for the possibility that, say, Poland and the Czech Republic have different levels of 5 In particular, they argue that the instability results from the failure to take into account party competition. Their recommendation is to model party support explicitly rather than just vote choice and this is the approach taken in this thesis, as was discussed earlier in this chapter. 6 As well as adding considerable extra complexity and consuming degrees of freedom, the required data is not readily available: ‘Information about relevant sources of voter heterogeneity is much more sparse, basically only available for a few countries and measured at irregular intervals’ (Dorussen 2002, 309). 30 CHAPTER 1. THEORY OF ECONOMIC VOTING economic voting then this can be accounted for. This is the method used by Chapter 3. Of course this is merely an empirical fix and does not solve the theoretical problem, as it sheds no extra light on these differences. A more sophisticated approach requires an understanding of the causes of the variation between political contexts. The most influential theory of contextual variation in the economic vote is the theory of clarity of responsibility, which was introduced to the literature by Powell and Whitten (1993) and further developed by Whitten and Palmer (1999). According to this theory, economic voting is more likely to take place in contexts where voters can reasonably hold a particular incumbent responsible for the condition of the economy. While this can be reasonably done in a country like the United Kingdom, where there is very little to hinder prime ministers from taking whatever course of action they feel is required, this is not necessarily the case everywhere. For example, the German chancellor frequently has to negotiate policies with coalition partners as well as gain the support of the upper house if certain forms of legislation are required. Furthermore, certain policies may be beyond the jurisdiction of the federal government and require the support of the states to be implemented. This implies that it is less clear in Germany which government and who within the government, if anyone at all, ought to be held responsible for any unwelcome economic events. Accordingly, the argument runs, German voters ought to be less inclined to vote economically than their British counterparts. Much of the work in this area has focused on precisely how clarity of responsibility should be measured. In its original conception, the key variables were the voting cohesion of the incumbent parties, the strength and inclusiveness of the parliamentary committee system, opposition in any constitutionally significant upper house, and the presence of a minority or coalition government (Powell and Whitten 1993). Alternative measures have been proposed but these are discussed in Chapter 4, where a clarity of responsibility model is constructed. An alternative contextual theory of economic voting has been developed by Duch and Stevenson (2008). Basing their model on the rational expectations literature, and particularly Alesina and Rosenthal (1995), they distinguish between two types of economic growth shocks. These are competency shocks, which derive from the actions of the incumbent government, and exogenous or nonpolitical shocks, which do not (Duch and Stevenson 2008, 132–133). The strength of the economic vote depends on the proportion of shocks which are competency shocks (138). Duch and Stevenson (2008, 147) argue that this proportion is related to the mix of ‘electorally dependent’ and ‘nonelectorally dependent’ economic decision makers. Electorally dependent decision makers include both elected officers themselves and also the 1.9. THE GREAT RECESSION 31 government agencies that answer to them. Nonelectorally dependent decision makers are ‘everyone else whose decisions might impact the economy, including individuals, firms, interest groups, nonelectorally dependent (entrenched) bureaucrats, foreign leaders, the WTO, and many more’ (139–140). The argument is that in contexts where economic decisions are largely driven by elected officials or bureaucrats responsible to them, a high proportion of economic shocks will be competency shocks and the economic vote will be correspondingly high. By contrast, in contexts where many economic decisions are made by statutory bodies or international agencies or are otherwise outside of the control of the incumbent government, the economic vote will be considerably lower. There are some similarities with the clarity of responsibility theory, in that both theories relate the strength of the economic vote to political control but there are importance differences. Clarity of responsibility theory is concerned with the degree to which the dominant government party has to negotiate with other parties to implement government policy, whereas this theory is concerned with the degree to which economic policy is influenced by non-political actors. Although this is a promising theory, it is not used by this thesis, mainly because it is based on some of the opposite assumptions from those made here. For example, theirs is a retrospective vote choice theory, whereas this thesis is based on a prospective party support theory. 1.9 The Great Recession The central question motivating this thesis is whether the Great Recession affected the economic vote in the European Union. Of course, classic economic voting theory already predicts a strong electoral response, since the recession was both widespread and severe. The question is whether the strength of the economic vote exceeded this expectation. There are two threads in the literature that suggest that this might be the case. The first thread is the idea of grievance asymmetry, which claims that the response to a good event is not necessarily of the same magnitude as the response to a bad event. It is typically argued that the response to a negative stimulus is stronger than the response to a positive one. This argument appeared as early as Campbell et al. (1960, 555), who wrote: Compare the change wrought in party fortunes in either of these cases [the panic of 1893 and the Great Depression] with the change occurring when a party already in office witnesses a surge of economic prosperity. This prosperity clearly benefits the administration party, but it has nothing like the magnitude of the effect that 32 CHAPTER 1. THEORY OF ECONOMIC VOTING would result from economic distress. A party already in power is rewarded much less for good times than it is punished for bad times. This idea was tested by Bloom and Price (1975), who extended previous economic voting models to account for this possibility. In an aggregate study of US House of Representatives elections, they found that recessions were associated with reduced incumbent support but that the opposite was not true for economic recoveries. Similar results have occasionally been found elsewhere. For example, a grievance asymmetry was also found at Danish elections between 1985–92 using an individual-level model (Nannestad and Paldam 1997b) and a study of Hungarian voters in 1997 found a similar effect (Duch 2001). Looking beyond studies of economic voting specifically, it has also been found that the media and public opinion response to negative economic news is stronger than the response to positive economic developments (Soroka 2006). What these findings suggest is that economic voting is weaker than expected during times of prosperity. It is not therefore too much of a stretch to hypothesise that economic voting might be stronger than expected during a recession of exceptional severity. The second relevant thread in the literature pertains to the salience of economic issues. The argument is that voters are more likely to vote economically when the economy is a salient issue for some reason and that the salience of economic issues is linked to economic performance. Consequently, economic voting is expected to recede when the economy is performing satisfactorily. Duch and Stevenson (2008, 171) summarise the argument thus: ‘when the economy is in equilibrium, or possibly even out of equilibrium but in a positive direction, economic evaluations are likely to play a much less important role in the vote decision.’ This idea has some empirical support, with survey data from the 2008 US presidential election (Singer 2011a) and cross-national survey data from 38 countries in the years 2001–2006 (Singer 2011b) showing that the salience of the economy is greater in contexts where economic conditions are poor and among individuals who are personally affected by economic privations. A follow-up study using aggregated survey data from elections in 43 countries in the years 2001–2011 found further evidence that economic issues tend to be most salient when the economy is less healthy (Singer 2013). It is interesting that the implications of the asymmetry and salience arguments are so similar despite the differences in logic. Whether it results from qualitative differences in the way people respond to different kinds of information or from the fluctuating salience of economic issues, these literatures predict a stronger economic vote during bad times than good times. This leaves open the possibility that a severe 1.9. THE GREAT RECESSION 33 global recession ought to produce a still stronger economic vote, beyond that which would be predicted by classical economic voting theory. The handful of comparative studies that have been published are largely based on aggregate data, which is probably because comparable aggregate data is more quickly available than cross-national survey data. Several studies investigated the relationship between government vote share and economic indicators. One study of EU countries in 2008–2011, which also included aggregated perceptions data, found evidence of an economic voting effect during the crisis, noting that most incumbents lost support, but their study design does not include a baseline for comparison so it is not clear whether this economic vote is stronger or weaker than expected (LeDuc and Pammett 2013). Similarly, a study of elections in 28 OECD countries in the years 2007–2011 found clear evidence of an economic voting effect during the crisis, but once again there is no baseline to compare this to (Bartels 2014). Other studies did compare Great Recession voting behaviour to an earlier baseline. Hernández and Kriesi (2015) looked at the relationship between economic indicators and the vote share of the dominant governing party at post-crisis elections in 30 European countries. They found different patterns in different parts of the continent, with an economic vote typically exceeding baseline expectations in Western European countries but not in Central and Eastern European countries, where the response appeared to be more moderate. Likewise, Bouvet and King (2016) investigated the relationship between incumbent vote share and economic indicators in 32 OECD countries at elections between 1975 and 2013, with particular attention paid to the Great Recession. They found evidence that voters were more likely to punish right-wing parties than left-wing parties during the recession. A further study looked at economic opinion in eleven Western European countries in the period 2007–2011, finding that economic opinion typically reflected the economic reality and that the perceptions of voters during the Great Recession were by and large not an overreaction (Anderson and Hecht 2014). In the few years since the Great Recession, a literature has emerged on economic voting during that time. The bulk of these have been studies of individual countries. Many of these studies seek to establish whether there was an economic voting effect in some country during the Great Recession. For example, a crisis economic voting effect was found in the United Kingdom, as well as qualified support for austerity policies, with evidence that this support is likely to wane unless the economy starts to improve (Borges et al. 2013). A study of British voters’ attributions of responsibility for the crisis found evidence that Conservative partisans were more likely to blame the government for the crisis compared to Labour partisans, who tended 34 CHAPTER 1. THEORY OF ECONOMIC VOTING to blame financial institutions (Hellwig and Coffey 2011). There is also evidence that Labour Party support in the years 2004–2009 was more related to unemployment among low income earners and to inflation among high income earners (Palmer and Whitten 2011; Palmer, Whitten and Williams 2013). On the other hand, Duch and Sagarzazu (2014) used panel studies from the UK and Germany to study perceptions of the Great Recession and economic voting, finding little difference in the economic vote of rich and poor voters, despite poorer voters feeling the effects of the recession more strongly. There is thus agreement that economic voting occurred in the UK during the crisis but not as to whether rich and poor voters behaved differently. Countries that were particularly heavily affected by the recession have tended to attract scholarly attention. Unsurprisingly, economic voting appears to have been a feature of elections in these countries as well. For example, a Greek study used a combination of individual and aggregate data to examine the economic vote in Greece both before and during the Great Recession (Nezi 2012), finding evidence of economic voting throughout the crisis, although a large shift in economic perceptions is necessary to produce a change in government. Turning to Spain, Fraile and Lewis-Beck (2012) use survey data from 1982 to 2008 to show that economic voting does exist in that country, despite some contrary claims in the literature. In a later study, they then look at the 2008 election specifically, finding a clear economic voting effect during the economic crisis, although they unfortunately do not compare 2008 directly with previous years (Fraile and Lewis-Beck 2013). A study of post-election surveys from Italian elections between 1990 and 2008 found that instability is not an inherent characteristic of Italian politics but rather the result of valence political behaviour such as economic voting (Bellucci 2012). And Marsh and Mikhaylov (2012) examined the 2011 Irish election, which is particularly notable for the extreme loss of support of the previously highly successful incumbent party Fianna Fáil. While they naturally place importance on the specific circumstances of the crisis and its aftermath, they unsurprisingly find support for a link between the economic and political events of that time. Economic voting is certainly not limited to those countries that suffered exceptionally from the recession. Germany is a particularly interesting case because it was governed by a grand coalition of the major centre-left and centre-right parties at the time of the recession, so economic voters potentially had a much more difficult to choice to make. In other words, despite the severe economic crisis, there was no viable alternative to the incumbent government. Anderson and Hecht (2012) used panel survey data from before and after the 2009 German 1.9. THE GREAT RECESSION 35 elections to examine the economic vote in this context, finding that voters personally affected by the recession used several strategies to shift their support away from the parties of the grand coalition but that sociotropic voters tended not to continue supporting the coalition. Clarke and Whitten (2013) used survey data of Germans in 2009 to compare valence models, which are a generalisation of economic voting models, to spatial models, finding that the valence model was best equipped to explain vote choice. These results suggest that, despite being governed by a grand coalition, economic voting still occurred in Germany during the recession. Economic voting effects during the Great Recession have also been found in Sweden (Martinsson 2013; Lindvall, Martinsson and Oscarsson 2013), Portugal (Freire and SantanaPereira 2012), Turkey (Çarkoğlu 2012) and Hungary (Stegmaier and Lewis-Beck 2011). Although this literature clearly establishes that economic voting during the Great Recession took place across many and varied European countries, there are two things that are missing. The first of these is a comparative, individual-level study of economic voting behaviour during the crisis. This is important because there is only so much that can be learnt from single-country and aggregate studies. Single-country studies are limited because they cannot possibly test or control for contextual effects, such as clarity of responsibility. Moreover, when looking at only one country, there is always the possibility, however remote, that any effect that is found is not a typical behaviour but one characteristic to the particular institutions of that country. Even though economic voting effects have been found in so many individual European countries, it is not yet clear whether these effects are similar in size, since each study uses different data and different methods. Aggregate studies are also limited because there are so many different individual behaviours that can explain any observable aggregate effect. Therefore, in order to gain a deeper understanding of the economic vote during this crisis, a comparative individual-level study is needed. The published study that comes closest to meeting these criteria is Whiteley (2016), who used European Social Surveys data to compare voters from 21 countries in 2006 and 2012, in other words shortly before and shortly after the crisis. He modelled incumbent support according to spatial, valence and cleavages theories of voter behaviour, finding more similarities than differences before and after the crisis in each case. This was not, however, a study of economic voting specifically and leaves open questions about the nature and level of economic voting during the crisis. The second thing missing from this literature is a study specifically designed to contrast the economic vote before, during and after the recession. This is important because such a study would make it possible to test the hypothesis that the economic vote was stronger than 36 CHAPTER 1. THEORY OF ECONOMIC VOTING expected during the crisis. Without a time comparison, the possibility cannot be excluded that the economic vote seen during the crisis was simply a continuation of the normal economic voting response that is seen at other times. There have been a small number of single-country studies that have specifically made this comparison but no comparative studies. For example, Martinsson (2013) found that the economic vote in Sweden was unusually strong at the postcrisis 2010 election and Lindvall, Martinsson and Oscarsson (2013) compared the economic vote in Sweden during the Great Recession to that during an earlier crisis in 1991–1993, finding that economic status was a stronger predictor of economic voting behaviour during the Great Recession than it had been during the earlier crisis. On the other hand, Freire and Santana-Pereira (2012) found the economic vote in Portugal to be slightly depressed at the 2009 elections compared to previous years and Çarkoğlu (2012) found a stronger economic vote in Turkey in 2007 than in 2011. Others still have argued that the immediate economic voting response to the recession was muted and that it was not until the implementation of unpopular austerity programmes that voters started to turn against their governments (Bermeo and Bartels 2014, 3–4). In the face of such contradictory results, there is a need for a systematic cross-national individual-level study designed to compare the economic vote before, during and after the Great Recession, a need which this thesis fills. 1.10 Conclusion The basic idea behind economic voting theory is that voters are more likely to support incumbents when the economy is performing satisfactorily than they are when it is performing poorly. This basic idea is simple but there are many different theoretical behaviour models that could support this idea. This chapter has reviewed the key theoretical debates in the economic voting literature and discussed the empirical evidence in support of the various positions. Although some of these questions are more settled than others, it is not possible to proceed without making some assumptions about the nature of the economic vote. This theoretical model is a selection model, which means that it is assumed that voters use their votes in order to select the best possible government rather than to send a reward or punishment signal to the incumbent. The assumption that voters are not entirely egocentric but rather sociotropic economic voters is probably the least controversial, in light of the large body of evidence that sociotropic economic voting exists. This thesis is based on a prospective theory of economic voting. This is partly for data reasons, as the next chapter will show. Although retrospective 1.10. CONCLUSION 37 Figure 1.2: Outline of economic voting theory This illustrates the specific theory of economic voting used in this thesis. A voter’s level of support for a particular party is influenced by his or her perceptions of the economy and the direction of this influence depends on whether that party is incumbent or not. The strength of this economic vote is in turn influenced by contextual factors such as clarity of responsibility and the Great Recession. Figure 1.3: Vote choice process Vote choice is not modelled as being directly influenced by the economic vote. Rather, the economic vote independently affects a voter’s level of support for each party and these levels of support determine the final vote choice. 38 CHAPTER 1. THEORY OF ECONOMIC VOTING studies tend to predominate, the empirical evidence does not strongly favour either alternative. This thesis prefers an economic perceptions model over an objective indicators model because, despite the criticisms of perceptions models, individual voters are not necessarily objective and do filter information in idiosyncratic ways. In light of the fact that almost all of the countries under study have multiparty systems, a party support model is preferred to a vote choice model. Finally, it is theorised that the strength of the economic vote may be affected by contextual features such as clarity of responsibility or the Great Recession, as an example of a deep international economic crisis. Taken together, these features describe a cohesive theory of the economic vote, which is outlined in Figure 1.2. As the diagram shows, the level of support that a particular voter has for a particular party is influenced by both the prospective economic assessment of that voter and the incumbency status of the party—which may have more than two levels if importance within the governing coalition is taken into account. These two influences interact with each other, as the effect of a particular economic assessment on support for a government party is expected to be different from the same effect on support for an opposition party. It is this interaction of effects that is referred to as the economic vote. It is worth noting that, although the basic principle of economic voting appears straightforward, even obvious, it necessarily describes an interaction effect.7 This explains some of the complexity of economic voting models, including those introduced later in this thesis. This economic voting effect is itself affected by contextual factors, such as the clarity of responsibility in a particular country and events such as the Great Recession. It is of course the latter that is the focus of this thesis, the primary objective of which is to establish whether that recession did indeed have an effect on the economic vote. Figure 1.3 illustrates that a citizen’s final vote choice is determined by his or her level of support for each of the parties that could potentially receive the vote. It is assumed that voters simply select the party that they currently support the most. This chapter has also discussed the existing literature on economic voting in the Great Recession. Although there have been a number of studies of economic voting in individual countries during that time frame as well as a handful of aggregate-data cross-national studies, there are limits to what can be learned from these. Even among these studies, few explicitly contrast what was observed during the crisis to what was observed at other times. In order to gain a fuller understanding of how the economic vote was affected by the Great Recession, 7 Except in the special case of a two-party system, where support for the government and support for the opposition can be reduced to a single difference in support variable and the incumbency effect can be eliminated entirely. This special case describes the United States but is otherwise rare, especially among the European countries studied in this thesis. 1.10. CONCLUSION 39 there is a need for an individual-level cross-national study comparing the economic vote before, during and after the crisis. This thesis fills this need. The next chapter discusses the data used to undertake this study as well as the specific methods used to analyse that data. Chapter 2 Measuring the economic vote The previous chapter introduced the theory of economic voting and explained the specific theoretical framework that informs this thesis. The following chapters use this framework to develop statistical models describing the economic vote, which are then used to test hypotheses that shed light on the research questions driving this thesis. The purpose of this chapter is to prepare the ground for these statistical models by describing the data sources that are used, the key variables that are analysed and the methods that are used to perform this analysis. This chapter focuses on the details that are relevant for the entire thesis. Other details that are more specific to individual analyses are discussed as needed in the chapters where they are relevant. As the purpose of this thesis is to examine whether and how economic voting behaviour was affected by the Great Recession, it is important to be able to measure the economic vote both during the crisis and at other times. As will be shown, it happens that the European Election Studies have conducted multinational voter surveys at ideal times for making such a comparison. These surveys include questions that indicate respondents’ levels of support for various parties as well as their economic assessments. When combined with incumbency data from other sources, this makes it possible to model the economic vote according to the framework introduced in the previous chapter. It will also be shown that there is a structure to this data, which has to be taken into account by the statistical methods used. This structure is accounted for by using multilevel analysis. This chapter begins by introducing the data sources that have been used, and shows how the timing of the three survey waves used coincides with the course of the Great Recession. Following this, there is a discussion of the particular measurements used. This includes a description of the key variables and the precise question wording where appropriate, along with some comments on the distribution and level of measurement. Finally, the methods used to analyse all of this data are introduced and the reasons behind these choices are given. 41 42 CHAPTER 2. MEASURING THE ECONOMIC VOTE 2.1 Data sources and timing As the previous chapter explained, this study is intended to be an individual-level crossnational study comparing the economic vote before, during and after the Great Recession. In order to achieve these goals, there is a need for survey data satisfying three key criteria: it must include the necessary questions to measure the economic vote, it must be comparable across nations and it must consist of appropriately timed survey waves. Fortunately, the European Election Studies satisfy all three of the requirements.1 The EES surveys are a series of post-election surveys, which are collected in each European Union member state shortly after every European Parliament election. As will be seen later in this chapter, these surveys include the required questions. These surveys are specifically designed to be comparable across countries. They are based on a single questionnaire which is translated into the appropriate local language or languages. It should be noted that this is not a study of European Parliament elections but rather of hypothetical national elections. The advantage of this approach is that it makes it possible to measure the economic voting tendency across all of the countries at the same point in time, whereas the actual national elections are invariably spread out across many years, which makes it very difficult to compare countries. Although the EES surveys correspond to European Parliament elections, they also include questions about national politics and these are the questions that are used. The EES surveys are also suitably timed. This thesis uses the 2004, 2009, and 2014 waves (EES 2004, 2009, 2014; Schmitt et al. 2009; van Egmond et al. 2010; Popa et al. 2015), which were all conducted shortly after the European Parliament elections in those years. Figure 2.1 shows the quarterly GDP growth rate across the current 28 member states of the EU. The Great Recession began in the aftermath of the global financial crisis of 2007–2008 and by the end of 2008 the EU was in recession, following the common definition of a recession as two consecutive quarters of negative growth. The dashed vertical lines show when the European Parliament elections occurred and correspondingly when the three EES surveys were collected. As the figure shows, the 2004 election took place well before there was any sign of crisis, while the 2009 election took place shortly after its peak. Although there was a brief apparent recovery, conditions worsened again in 2011, with a further recovery in 2013. By the time of the 2014 European Parliament elections, the EU had been out of recession for eighteen 1 The survey data used in this thesis was originally collected by the 2004, 2009 and 2014 EES research groups. Those studies have been made possible by various grants. Neither the original collectors of the data nor their sponsors bear any responsibility for the analyses or interpretations made here. The data is available from the home page of the European Election Study (http://eeshomepage.net/) and from the Archive Department of GESIS– Leibniz Institute for the Social Sciences (http://www.gesis.org/). 2.1. DATA SOURCES AND TIMING 43 Figure 2.1: GDP growth in the European Union, 2000–2015 1.0 GDP growth (%) 0.5 0.0 -0.5 -1.0 -1.5 -2.0 -2.5 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 time This shows the seasonally adjusted GDP growth rate across the entire 28-country European Union by quarter, each compared to the previous quarter. The dashed vertical lines show when the European Parliament elections took place in 2004, 2009 and 2015. Source: OECD months. These three time points thus offer a before, during and after snapshot of the Great Recession. It should be noted that this is the overall picture, as the recession took a slightly different course in each country. Nonetheless, the only two EU member states to avoid the recession altogether were Poland and Slovakia. The EES surveys typically encompass each member state of the EU. The EU was enlarged during the time frame of this study, with Bulgaria and Romania joining in 2009 and Croatia joining in 2014. Since it would be difficult to separate any Great Recession effect from that of joining the EU, these countries have been excluded from this study. This leaves the 25 countries that have been member states since 2004.2 The political parties included in the study are those for which there is a measure of the dependent variable, party support. These are the parties that were chosen by the EES coordinators in each country as being the most important parties in that country. These typically include all of the parties that could reasonably expect 2 Unless otherwise specified, the Swedish data from 2004 has been excluded from the analysis. This is because some variables were measured on a different scale from that used elsewhere. Most problematically, this includes the economic assessment questions, which were measured on a three-point scale instead of a five-point scale. Since these responses could not be reconciled satisfactorily with those from other countries, the decision was made to ignore the Swedish survey in that year. Sweden is however still included in the other years. Also, whenever party support is the dependent variable, Belgium, Lithuania and Luxembourg in 2004 also had to be excluded because the party-specific questions were not asked in those countries. 44 CHAPTER 2. MEASURING THE ECONOMIC VOTE Table 2.1: Sample size and interview mode of EES surveys Country Austria Belgium Cyprus Czech Republic Denmark Estonia Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Ireland Italy Latvia Lithuania Luxembourg Malta Netherlands Poland Portugal Slovakia Slovenia Spain Sweden United Kingdom Sample 1010 889 500 889 1317 1606 900 1406 596 500 1200 1154 1553 1000 1005 1335 — 1586 960 1000 1063 1002 1208 2100 1500 2004 Mode phone mail face face phone face phone unknown phone phone face mail mail face face phone — mail face phone face phone face face phone Sample 1000 1002 1000 301/720 1000 300/707 1000 1000 1004 1000 300/705 1001 1000 300/701 300/705 1001 1000 1005 302/700 1000 301/715 1000 1000 1002 1000 2009 Mode phone phone phone phone/face phone phone/face phone phone phone phone phone/face phone phone phone/face phone/face phone phone phone phone/face phone phone/face phone phone phone phone 2014 Sample Mode 1114 1084 530 1177 1085 1087 1096 1074 1648 1085 1104 1081 1091 1055 1096 538 544 1101 1223 1033 1095 1143 1106 1144 1421 face face face face face face face face face face face face face face face face face face face face face face face face face The 2004 wave used telephone, mailback and face-to-face interviews, depending on the country. The 2009 wave used telephone interviews in every country, which were supplemented by face-to-face interviews in certain countries. All interviews in the 2014 wave were conducted face-to-face. Source: EES to win a seat at a general election. Table 2.1 shows the sample size and interview mode of each survey in each of the three waves. At least five hundred responses have been collected in each country and one thousand responses is typical, except for some particularly small countries. Malta was not surveyed at all in 2004. Various interview modes have been used, with telephone and face-to-face modes the most common. A mix of modes was used in 2004, including mailback surveys in four countries. It is not known which method was used in France in that year.3 Interviews were predominately conducted by telephone in 2009 but these were supplemented with face-to-face interviews in several countries where a representative sample could not be otherwise obtained (van Egmond et al. 2010, 5). All interviews were face-toface in the 2014 wave. Although there are a mix of modes in this data, mode effects are not 3 The codebook simply states that ‘France did not report the technical implementation of its study’ (Schmitt et al. 2009). 2.1. DATA SOURCES AND TIMING 45 expected to influence the findings, since economic voting is not something that respondents might be embarrassed to admit. In fact, it cannot be determined if any individual respondent is an economic voter since these patterns are only observable in the aggregate. Although the EES survey data forms the primary dataset for this thesis, some contextual data has been drawn from other sources. The main contextual information required is the incumbency status of each party at the time the surveys were collected. This information was taken from the Parliaments and Governments Database (Döring and Manow 2015), also known as ParlGov, which aggregates information about election results and parliament and cabinet composition from EU and other countries. Since multiple governments may be in power in a country during a single calendar year, it was necessary to decide precisely which dates to use to measure incumbency. In most cases, the measurement date chosen was the first day of the survey fieldwork, namely 14 June 2004, 8 June 2009 and 22 May 2014. Whichever party held the post of head of government on this date is designated the prime minister’s party4 in that year. Parties holding other positions in the government are designated cabinet parties.5 All other parties are coded as opposition parties. This approach makes sense because survey respondents were asked to reflect on the government currently in power at the time. In two cases, however, slight adjustments were made in order to accommodate the peculiar circumstances. On 7 May 2009, the Czech government was replaced by a nonpartisan caretaker government, in advance of elections in October of that year (Linek and Lacina 2010). Since this caretaker government was not officially associated with any particular parties, it is treated in this thesis as an extension of the preceding coalition government led by the Civic Democratic Party. Similarly, the Prime Minister of Hungary Ferenc Gyurcsány resigned from the minority Hungarian Socialist Party (MSZP) government on 21 March 2009, being replaced by Gordon Bajnai on 14 April (Várnagy 2010). Although he was an MSZP appointment and a government minister, Bajnai was a compromise candidate proposed to appease other parties, and he is recorded as a nonpartisan prime minister in the ParlGov database. In light of these circumstances, this thesis treats the MSZP as the party holding the office of prime minister at the time of the 2009 surveys. Other cases worth special mention are Luxembourg in 2004 and 2009 and Belgium in 2014. In these instances, the national elections coincided with the 4 This also includes the party holding the presidency of Cyprus, which is the only EU country with a full presidential system. Since the phrase ‘party of the head of government’ is rather unwieldy, the term ‘prime minister’s party’ is used throughout this thesis instead and should be understood to include the party of the President of Cyprus. 5 Note that in some countries, the official cabinet does not include all government ministers. The term is not used here to refer to such an inner cabinet but rather to all government ministers, irrespective of seniority. This usage applies throughout this thesis. 46 CHAPTER 2. MEASURING THE ECONOMIC VOTE European Parliament elections, so there was the potential for a change of government to have occurred during the survey fieldwork, which would have been problematic. In practice this was not an issue, as both Luxembourg elections led to only minor changes to the cabinet, which in any case did not take place until after the fieldwork period (Dumont and Poirier 2005; Dumont, Kies and Poirier 2010), and the Belgian election did not result in any change to the party composition of the cabinet (Rihoux et al. 2015). The full list of parties analysed in their thesis along with their incumbency status in each year can be found in Appendix A. The most important sources of data are those discussed already, the EES surveys and the ParlGov database. These are used throughout the thesis. There are also some supplementary data sources that have been used to supply additional variables that are only required by certain chapters. Chapter 4 extends the basic economic voting model to test the clarity of responsibility theory developed by Powell and Whitten (1993). This requires country-level variables measuring various aspects of the political system. Some of these, such as whether the country has a presidential or a parliamentary system, were generated from the literature or common knowledge. Other variables, such as the composition of the parliament, were complex enough to require a systematic approach to measurement and these were mainly taken from the European Journal of Political Research Political Data Yearbook (PDY). Chapter 5 extends the basic model to examine how party support is influenced by the party’s spatial position. The spatial position data was collected from the Chapel Hill Expert Survey (CHES). Some of the remaining chapters also use extra variables from the EES surveys in addition to what is described in this chapter. In all of these cases, the measurements are discussed in the relevant chapters before they are used. There are two further complexities that had to be considered when coding political parties. The first of these is the phenomenon of regional and regionalist parties. Regional parties are those that are only active in parts of a country, such as the Christian Social Union in Bavaria (CSU), which does not operate outside the German federal state of Bavaria. The CSU is a special case, since it works very closely with the Christian Democratic Union of Germany (CDU), which operates everywhere else in Germany. In practice, the CDU and CSU tend to be seen as a unit at the national level—the CDU/CSU faction—and this is how they are treated in the EES surveys as well. A more difficult example of regional parties are the parties in Belgium, which are typically organised along linguistic lines, with French-speaking parties and Flemish-speaking parties, rather than at the national level. These are not normally part of a de facto greater unit, like the CDU/CSU faction. Regionalist parties are those that 2.1. DATA SOURCES AND TIMING 47 seek independence or at least greater autonomy for their region, such as the Scottish National Party in Scotland and Plaid Cymru in Wales. There are further examples in Flanders and many regions of Spain, namely the Basque Country, Navarre, Galicia and Catalonia. The problem posed by these parties is that the analysis takes place at the level of the nation-state. In the case of Belgium, this is sometimes dealt with by treating Flanders and Wallonia as separate states but this is not the approach used here, since they do share a national government, despite their different party systems. Moreover, this approach does not scale to the other countries mentioned. Instead, a record has been made of the regions where each party is active. For most parties, these comprise the entire country. The EES surveys also include a variable noting where each respondent was interviewed. When the stacked dataset was produced, any rows matching voters to parties not active in their region were discarded. Thus the analysis is affected by all British voters’ opinions of the Labour Party but only Welsh voters’ opinions of Plaid Cymru, for example. The second complexity encountered when coding political parties was that the party systems of the various countries in the EU feature varying degrees of fluidity. Northern European countries, such as Germany, Ireland, Sweden and Denmark, tend to have stable party systems whereas the party systems of Mediterranean countries, such as France, Spain and Italy, are characterised by frequent mergers and splits, which still occur today despite some increased stability in recent decades (Krouwel 2012, 49–78). This means that, in many cases, it is far from straightforward to identify political parties in 2004 with the same parties in 2009 and 2014. The Irish party named Fianna Fáil in 2004 is obviously the same party as the Fianna Fáil of 2014 but can the now defunct Democratic Movement of France be identified with the Union for French Democracy, which succeeded it in 2007? The Italian party Forza Italia eventually merged with several other parties in 2009 to form The People of Freedom, which later dissolved in 2013, reviving Forza Italia. Should these all be treated as the same party? This question is even more difficult to answer in the case of a party split, in which case a party may have multiple successors. To make matters worse, political parties frequently form short-lived electoral alliances for the European Parliament elections and often the EES surveys ask voters about these alliances, rather than the constituent parties. In order to avoid making arbitrary decisions, each party is treated as a discrete unit in each year. This means, for example, that responses to questions about the Fianna Fáil of 2004 are not pooled with those about the Fianna Fáil of 2014. This only applies to the pooling of responses. Measurements of a party’s time in office are unaffected by this decision. 48 CHAPTER 2. MEASURING THE ECONOMIC VOTE Table 2.2: Key variables used to measure the economic vote Variable Scale Level Source Party support Year 2009 Year 2014 Left–right distance Party ID Cabinet party Prime minister’s party Prospective assessment Female Age High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce 0 (low) to 10 (high) 1 = yes, 0 = no 1 = yes, 0 = no 0 (close) to 10 (far) 1 = yes, 0 = no 1 = yes, 0 = no 1 = yes, 0 = no −2 (worse) to +2 (better) 1 = yes, 0 = no 18 to 101 years 1 = yes, 0 = no 1 = yes, 0 = no 1 = yes, 0 = no 1 = yes, 0 = no 1 = yes, 0 = no 1 = yes, 0 = no measurement measurement measurement measurement measurement party party individual individual individual individual individual individual individual individual individual EES EES EES EES EES ParlGov ParlGov EES EES EES EES EES EES EES EES EES These are the variables used in every chapter. Most chapters include further variables, which are introduced as used. The dependent variable is party support, unless otherwise specified. The measurement level is shown for each variable. This indicates whether the variable is specific to the party or the individual. Variables that depend on both are said to be at the measurement level. Although none are shown here, some chapters also include variables measured at the country level. The source is either the European Election Studies or the ParlGov database. 2.2 Measurement and variables There are a number of key variables that are fundamental to this thesis and appear in every chapter. This section introduces the main dependent variable, party support, and several independent variables, including party identification, ideological distance, incumbency, economic assessment and some control variables. For each variable there is a discussion of why it is important and how it is measured. These variables are listed in Table 2.2. There is an inherent structure to the data used, which should not be ignored. Each EES survey wave consists of a number of national surveys. Random sampling is used for each national survey but some countries are more heavily sampled relative to their population sizes than others. Individual responses are thus nested within countries. Furthermore, individuals are asked about each of the important parties in their country, so these responses are nested within both individuals and parties because they relate a particular individual to a particular party. This will be referred to as the measurement level. Thus measurements are nested within individuals and parties, each of which is nested within with countries. The problem of structured data is ad- 2.2. MEASUREMENT AND VARIABLES 49 dressed later in this chapter. For now, it will simply be noted at which level a particular variable is measured. The dependent variable used for the economic voting models is party support. Party support relates a particular individual to a particular party and is thus measured at the measurement level. This variable is intended to measure the voter’s current preference level for the party. It is derived from EES questions asking voters the likelihood that they would vote for that party at a future national election.6 The precise wording of the question in 2009 is: We have a number of parties in [country] each of which would like to get your vote. How probable is it that you will ever vote for the following parties? Please specify your views on a scale where 0 means ‘not at all probable’ and 10 means ‘very probable’. If you think of [party]: what mark out of ten best describes how probable it is that you will ever vote for [party]? The wording is almost identical in the other years, except for that fact that the 2004 wave used a scale starting at one instead of zero. These were transformed to a zero to ten scale for comparability with the 2009 and 2014 data. In order to ensure that this did not bias the results, several potential transformations were considered. These included variations on scaling the data and recoding particular points. The transformation that was ultimately used was to recode one on the ten-point scale as zero and to leave the other levels unchanged. This approach was chosen because it produced a distribution very similar to the distribution of the 2009 variable. It seems that most scores correspond directly on the two scales except of course that parties that are strongly disliked were given the score zero where that was available or one where it was not. Using the alternative transformations yields similar results in any case. The decision to use party support rather than vote choice as the dependent variable was explained in the previous chapter. It is based on the theory that vote choice is a two-stage process, the first stage determining party support levels based on economic and other considerations and the second stage determining vote choice based on those party support levels (van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin 2007, 31–53). In this model, it is assumed that the second stage is deterministic, with voters always selecting the party that they have the highest level of support for. In order to test whether this assumption is reasonable, the pattern of support levels was examined among those voters who answered the question asking which party they would vote for at a national election held the following day. Among these voters, a 6 Q12 in 2004, Q39 in 2009 and QPP8 in 2014. 50 CHAPTER 2. MEASURING THE ECONOMIC VOTE Figure 2.2: Distribution of raw and centred party support raw centred normalised count 1.00 0.75 0.50 0.25 0.00 0 2 4 6 8 10 -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8 10 party support The left panel is a histogram of raw party support and the right panel is a histogram of party support centred around the individual-level mean, from the three surveys combined. The bin size is 0.5 in both instances. Source: EES consistently high proportion nominated the party they had the highest reported support for.7 The proportion of voters matching this criterion was 92.7 percent [92.3%, 93.2%]8 in 2004, 93.7 percent [93.3%, 94.1%] in 2009 and 94.4 percent [94.0%, 94.8%] in 2014. Although a small number of respondents have not responded as expected, these results confirm that this vote choice model is a reasonable approximation of actual behaviour. The party support variable has been centred around each individual’s mean reported party support. The distributions of the raw and centred variables are shown in Figure 2.2. As the figure shows, the distribution of the raw variable is both multimodal and highly skewed. A disproportionate number of reported party support levels were zero, corresponding to 40.9 percent of the total measurements. These are the instances in which a voter reported that they would never vote for a particular party. There are secondary modes at five and ten. These properties are problematic for regression analysis, which assumes that residuals are normally distributed (Gelman and Hill 2007, 46).9 In fact, the raw level of support reported by a particular individual depends on that individual’s interpretation of the eleven-point scale. 7 In many cases, respondents assigned the same support level to multiple parties and in some of these instances multiple parties shared the distinction of being a particular respondent’s most preferred party. As long as the response to the party choice question was one of those parties, the statistics reported here treat these cases as matches. 8 Square brackets indicate 95% confidence intervals. 9 Just because the dependent variable is not normally distributed does not necessarily mean that the residuals will not be. For this to be the case, however, the independent variables would need to be distributed in a very particular way, so as to compensate for the non-normality of the dependent variable, which they are not. 2.2. MEASUREMENT AND VARIABLES 51 By centring the scores around the individual-level mean, the differences between the scores are preserved and it is these differences that are of substantive interest, not the absolute levels. This is because the theory predicts a change in vote choice whenever the voter’s support for a new party exceeds their support for their previous choice, not when it exceeds some absolute bar. As the figure shows, the distribution of the centred variable is somewhat positively skewed and it appears to be bimodal, although the mode at zero is an artefact resulting from the fact that some individuals give all the parties an equal score. Nonetheless, the distribution of the centred variable is far more appropriate for regression analysis than that of the raw variable. The timing of the survey is indicated by two dummy variables. The base case is the 2004 survey wave and there is a dummy variable indicating the 2009 wave and one indicating the 2014 wave. As discussed earlier, the 2009 survey wave took place when the initial crisis was at its peak, so this dummy variable indicates the mid-crisis time point. Similarly, the 2014 wave took place after the end of the recession, so its dummy variable indicates the post-crisis time point. The reference case is naturally the pre-crisis time point. As well as predictors related to economic voting specifically, the economic voting model developed in the next chapter also includes other variables known to be predictive of vote choice. The first of these, left–right distance, is derived from the spatial theory of voting (Downs 1957; Hotelling 1929; Davis, Hinich and Ordeshook 1970). According to this theory, individual voters prefer the parties that are closest to themselves in some political space, which is most frequently conceived of as a single dimension stretching from left to right. The left– right distance variable measures this closeness between a voter and a party. This is known to be a strong influence on vote choice (van der Eijk, Schmitt and Binder 2005; Kroh 2009). Two survey questions were used to produce this measure. The first measures the individual’s spatial position.10 The precise wording of this question in 2009 was: In political matters people talk of ‘the left’ and ‘the right’. What is your position? Please indicate your views using any number on a scale from 0 to 10, where 0 means ‘left’ and 10 means ‘right’. Which number best describes your position? The second question measures the individual’s opinion of the spatial position of each party.11 This question immediately follows the self-location question and is worded: ‘And about where would you place the following parties on this scale?’ The wording of these questions was very similar in the other years, except for the fact that the 2004 survey used a 1–10 scale instead 10 11 Q14 in 2004, Q46 in 2009 and QPP13 in 2014. Q14_i in 2004, Q47 in 2009 and QPP14 in 2014. 52 CHAPTER 2. MEASURING THE ECONOMIC VOTE Figure 2.3: Distribution of left–right distance count 60000 40000 20000 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 left–right distance This is a histogram of the left–right distance between each individual and party, from the three surveys combined. A distance of zero indicates that the individual believes the party to be perfectly aligned with them ideologically. A distance of ten indicates the belief that the individual and party occupy the opposite extremes of the spectrum. Source: EES of a 0–10 scale, as was the case for party support. These were adjusted in the same way as party support, described above, placing all values on the 0–10 scale. The left–right distance between a particular voter and a particular party is the absolute difference between that voter’s reported left–right position and his or her assessment of that party’s left–right position. This effectively measures the distance an individual perceives between him- or herself and the relevant party. This can be expected to be a reliable measure of spatial distance, as there is evidence that most voters are able to place themselves on a left– right spectrum (Mair 2007) and that in most countries there is a strong correlation between left–right self-identification and views about the desirable level of government intervention in the economy as well as certain social issues (Dalton, Farrell and McAllister 2011, 81–108). Additionally, the relative positions of parties according to the aggregated placement of survey respondents tends to coincide well with other measures of party position (109–141). The measure of left–right distance described here ranges in value from zero, in the case of perfect alignment, to ten, which means the voter is on the far left and the party the far right or vice versa. The distribution of this variable is shown in Figure 2.3. The mean value is 3.13 and the standard deviation is 2.66. Frequency falls off quickly as the distance increases past five, 2.2. MEASUREMENT AND VARIABLES 53 which is to be expected because most voters place themselves near the centre and extreme distances are only possible for voters placing themselves near the endpoints. The other key predictor derived from non-economic voting theories of voter behaviour is party identification. The theory of party identification originated with Campbell et al. (1960), who argued that a key determinant of vote choice was an individual’s sense of identification with a particular party, this identification being largely inherited from parents or social milieu. Green, Palmquist and Schickler (2002, 24–51) have investigated some of the characteristics of party identification. Identifying with a party is not the same as supporting it or voting for it, but rather a deeper and longstanding attachment to a particular party. People may vote against their identification on occasion but it changes only rarely. Not everyone identifies with a party but those who do are more engaged with politics. The original analysis of party identification in the United States has been replicated in recent years (Lewis-Beck et al. 2008). The theory of party identification has its origin in studies of the United States and its application to European politics has not been uncontroversial but there is evidence that party identification models do have some applicability to European countries (Berglund et al. 2005). Party identification is, like party support and left–right distance, measured at the measurement level, that is it relates a particular individual to a particular party. It is a dummy variable, taking the value one if the individual identifies with the party and zero otherwise. No individual identifies with more than one party12 but some individuals identify with no party. The question used to measure this variable13 was: Do you consider yourself to be close to any particular [political]14 party? If so, which party do you feel close to? Overall, 55.4 percent of respondents reported identifying with a particular party. As a result, the party identification variable takes the value one for 7.7 percent of the party–individual pairings. Further independent variables are needed to measure the economic vote. In the previous chapter, a theoretical model of economic voting was developed. According to that model, party support is influenced by both the party’s incumbency status and the individual’s prospective economic assessment. Incumbency status is measured at the party level of course and consists of two dummy variables, one indicating that the party held the office of prime minister (or 12 There is some evidence that people can identify with multiple parties (Schmitt 2009) but the EES surveys did not ask about secondary identifications. 13 Q29a in 2004, Q87 in 2009 and QPP21 in 2004 14 In the 2014 survey only. 54 CHAPTER 2. MEASURING THE ECONOMIC VOTE Figure 2.4: Distribution of prospective and retrospective assessments 2004 2009 2014 9000 prospective 6000 count 3000 0 9000 retrospective 6000 3000 0 -2 -1 0 1 2 -2 -1 0 1 2 -2 -1 0 1 2 economic assessment This shows the distribution of prospective and retrospective economic assessments in each year. Both range from −2 (much worse) to +2 (much better). Source: EES president in the case of Cyprus) and the other indicating that the party held at least one cabinet post at the relevant time. These are not mutually exclusive categories and in particular the prime minister’s party is always a cabinet party, since the prime ministership is itself a cabinet post. The method used to determine a party’s incumbency status has already been explained earlier in this chapter. Of the 504 parties in the pooled dataset, 69 (14%) were prime ministers’ parties, a further 96 (19%) were other cabinet parties and 339 (67%) were opposition parties at the time the surveys were conducted. Prospective economic assessment is measured at the individual level using the following survey question:15 And over the next 12 months, how do you think the general economic situation in this country will be? Will it get a lot better, a little better, stay the same, a little worse or get a lot worse. 15 Q21 in 2004, Q49 in 2009 and QPP16 in 2014. 2.2. MEASUREMENT AND VARIABLES 55 Figure 2.5: Relationship between prospective and retrospective assessments 2004 2009 2014 prospective 1.0 0.5 0.0 -0.5 -1.0 -2 -1 0 1 2 -2 -1 0 1 2 -2 -1 0 1 2 retrospective Each panel shows the mean prospective economic assessment for a particular retrospective assessment in the given year. These are shown with their 99% confidence intervals, although owing to the high sample size many of these are not visible. Source: EES The responses to these questions have been recoded so that they range from −2 to +2, with negative numbers indicating a pessimistic assessment and positive numbers an optimistic one. Zero means the economy is expected to stay the same. The surveys also include an equivalent retrospective question asking the respondents to assess whether the economy has improved or worsened over the past twelve months. It was explained in the previous chapter that this thesis uses a prospective voting model for both theoretical and data-driven reasons. The latter can be seen from Figure 2.4, which shows the distribution of both the prospective and retrospective variables. In both 2004 and 2014, the distributions of both variables resemble the binomial distribution, but for the fact that extremely positive assessments are remarkably rare. In 2009, however, this is not the case. Voters’ retrospective assessments are very skewed in that year, with 79.2 percent of respondents reporting a negative assessment, 13.7 percent a neutral assessment and only 7.1 percent a positive assessment. While such a negative retrospective assessment of the economy was certainly justified at that time, this sort of consensus among respondents is at odds with the variance desired in a key independent variable. The prospective assessment in 2009 is also a little more skewed than in other years but the skewness is much more tolerable, with 39.9 percent reporting a negative assessment compared to 26.4 percent a neutral and 33.7 percent a positive assessment. It is also interesting to look at the relationship between prospective and retrospective economic assessments in each year. These are shown in Figure 2.5. It can be seen that the relation- 56 CHAPTER 2. MEASURING THE ECONOMIC VOTE ship between these variables is approximately linear in 2004 and 2014 but once again 2009 is different. In that year, not only does the relationship appear to be somewhat less linear but retrospective assessment is also a weaker predictor of prospective assessment. Another way of seeing this is to look at the correlations between the two variables in each year. This is 0.56 in 2004, 0.28 in 2009 and 0.63 in 2014. In other words, there is a strong correlation between the two before and after the crisis but only a weak correlation during the crisis. These observations about the pattern of responses to the economic perceptions questions, combined with the theoretical reasons outlined in the previous chapter, have led to the decision to base the economic voting analysis in the following chapters on prospective, rather than retrospective, economic assessment. In addition to these key independent variables, demographic variables are used as controls. These are gender, age, education, urban density and workforce participation. Gender is a dummy variable taking the value one for women and zero for men. Women make up 54.4 percent of the sample. Age is measured in years but this is sometimes expressed as decades in the models used in the coming chapters so that all of the estimated coefficients are on similar scales, since the effect size of age in years is typically very small. Unfortunately, the other demographic questions were often measured on very different scales in the different survey years and sometimes even countries within a survey year. This makes it difficult to find granular correspondences between the different years, so responses have been grouped into coarse categories instead, aiming to keep the size of the categories roughly equal. Education has been divided into low, medium and high groups. Low education respondents are those who did not complete high school. Medium education respondents are those who have completed high school but do not have a university degree. Current students are included in this category. High education respondents are those who have a degree or higher. Medium education is the most common category and also the reference case, covering 39.9 percent of respondents, followed by high education, covering 36.9 percent, then low education, covering 23.3 percent. Urban density indicates the density of the area where the respondent lives. This is also divided into three groups. These groups are necessarily rather subjective, owing to the phrasing of the questions. The reference case is a small or medium-sized town. The other groups are rural, which indicates a village or rural area, and city, which also includes large towns. Town was the most frequent response (35.1%) followed by city (34.0%) and finally rural (30.9%). The final control variable is workforce participation. Once again this is divided into three 2.3. METHOD OF ANALYSIS 57 groups. The reference case is those who are employed, with the other groups being the unemployed and those who are not in the workforce for any other reason. The latter group is mostly retired people but also includes stay-at-home parents and disabled people, among others. Unsurprisingly, a majority of respondents (50.2%) indicated that they were employed, with only a small number (8.0%) claiming to be unemployed. The remaining 41.8 percent are not in the workforce. All of these variables are coded as dummy variables indicating each of the non-reference cases. 2.3 Method of analysis This thesis uses a stacked dataset design, which was strongly influenced by van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin (2007, 40-46), although the methods used are different. The motivation for this design is that the key variables of interest exist at the measurement level, which relates particular individuals to particular parties. For instance, the dependent variable, party support is such a variable. The degree to which individual i supports party j cannot be said to belong completely to either the individual level or the party level—it belongs to both. Since this party × individual, level, which is referred to in this thesis as the measurement level, is where the most important measurements occur, it is appropriate for the unit of observation to be a party–individual pair. This objective was achieved by transforming the EES survey dataset, which was measured at the individual level. Parties are represented by repeated questions— that is, each party-related question is asked once for each party. The dataset was transformed such that each individual appears in the dataset once for each party they were asked about, with only the questions about the relevant party included in each new row. Figure 2.6 illustrates this process. The key analytical method used in this thesis is multilevel modelling. Multi-level modelling is an extension of linear regression and generalised linear modelling that explicitly models variation between groups. This is achieved by giving the model coefficients a probability model of their own (Gelman and Hill 2007, 1). The decision to use multilevel modelling was motivated by the clustered nature of the data. One of the consequences of stacking the dataset as described above is that individual observations have been repeated in the stacked dataset many times. If linear regression were used this would artificially deflate the estimated standard errors but multilevel modelling can account for this sort of structure. In any event, the data used in this thesis is inherently structured. For one thing, there are twenty-five countries in the analysis and to ignore this would be to assume implicitly that there is minimal variance 58 CHAPTER 2. MEASURING THE ECONOMIC VOTE Figure 2.6: Data stacking process country resp_id age support_p1 support_p2 support_p3 UK UK UK 1 2 3 88 21 40 0 7 3 8 3 8 5 8 0 ⇓ country party_id resp_id age support UK UK UK UK UK UK UK UK UK UK-Lab UK-Lab UK-Lab UK-Con UK-Con UK-Con UK-LD UK-LD UK-LD 1 2 3 1 2 3 1 2 3 88 21 40 88 21 40 88 21 40 0 7 3 8 3 8 5 8 0 In the original dataset, each observation corresponds to an individual and variables relating to particular parties are repeated for each party. In the stacked dataset, each observation corresponds to a party–individual pair, eliminating the need to repeat variables. between these countries, which is a strong assumption to make. Furthermore, many of the variables that are of interest, including party support, the dependent variable, involve opinion about specific parties. Since there may be variation between a country’s parties as well as variation between countries, there are clusters within clusters. While ignoring this clustering would lead to deflated standard errors, it must be acknowledged that there are other ways of addressing this particular problem. It has been shown that robust standard errors and aggregation can produce the same results as multilevel models under the appropriate conditions (Arceneaux and Nickerson 2009). Nonetheless, each of these other methods is limiting in some specific way. Aggregation cannot be used to estimate individual-level effects and robust standard errors are not recommended for clusters of fewer than about twenty observations (188). The number of parties in each country in this study varies from five to fifteen. Furthermore, multilevel modelling is sufficiently flexible that is possible to include predictors at multiple levels within the same model. This is particularly important for this study, since economic voting theory relates variables that necessarily relate to multiple levels. Incumbency is only meaningful at the party level. Economic performance is measured at the national level. And it is individuals who make vote choices. A key advantage of multilevel modelling is that these variables and their interactions can be included in a single 2.3. METHOD OF ANALYSIS 59 model (Gelman 2007a, 7-8). Of course, it would be possible to aggregate all of these together and estimate everything at the national level. It would also be possible to model separate equations for every political party of interest. Both approaches are problematic however. The former approach, complete-pooling analysis, ignores all variation between groups and the latter, no-pooling analysis, is statistically inefficient. A key strength of multilevel modelling is that it offers a compromise between these extremes (Gelman and Hill 2007, 256). Multilevel models produce both fixed effect and random effect estimates. The fixed effects are those of primary substantive interest given the research questions behind this thesis. The decision to use multilevel modelling is motivated by the need to account for the structure of the data, rather than interest in the random effects specifically. As a result, the discussion of random effects is limited to discussions of variance and sometimes covariance. Individual countries are not normally discussed, as the purpose of this thesis is to gain an understanding of large cross-national trends. The decision to use multilevel linear regression models distinguishes this study from previous survey-based research into economic voting behaviour. As discussed in the previous section, the stacked dataset design of this thesis was influenced by van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin (2007), but they chose not to use multilevel modelling in their study. They reason that the chief advantage of multilevel models is that they avoid the biased standard errors that would result from naive regression modelling and they observe that the this problem can be avoided equally well by using robust standard errors, which they do (47). They also argue against multilevel modelling on the grounds that it is not well equipped to handle the cross-classified data structure that results from the stacked dataset design (48). While there is merit to these arguments, there is still much to be said for multilevel modelling in this context. Although it is true that the use of robust standard errors can avoid the problem of deflated standard error estimates, there are other advantages to using multilevel modelling, particularly in that they permit greater flexibility in the models. As for the problem of cross-classification, it must be acknowledged that this does add complexity to the models but modern computing power combined with Bayesian estimation techniques makes it possible to estimate these complex models. Duch and Stevenson (2008), on the other hand, do use some multilevel modelling. They adopt two different methods for their analysis, a one-stage and a two-stage strategy. Their one-stage strategy uses multilevel models to estimate all of the parameters together, whereas their two-stage strategy involves estimating the level of economic voting in national surveys and then using those estimates in cross-national models (94-100). 60 CHAPTER 2. MEASURING THE ECONOMIC VOTE One of the key differences between their methods and the methods used in this thesis is that they use multinomial logistic regression to predict vote choice, whereas this thesis uses linear regression to predict party support, for the reasons given in the previous chapter. Most of the independent variables in the models presented in the following chapters have been centred around the grand mean. By contrast to the centring of the dependent variable, the reasons for which have been given earlier, this centring of the independent variables has been done for technical reasons. Specifically, centring in this way markedly increases the convergence speed. It is also helpful for variables which are involved in quadratic and interaction terms. One consequence of this centring is that some caution is required when interpreting intercepts and interactions. Because of this and also owing to the complexity of some of the models, model coefficients are typically not interpreted directly in this thesis. Instead, postestimation simulation is used to derive quantities of more direct interest. The method used is that described in Gelman and Hill (2007, 140–143). Because the predictions resulting from this method take into account the uncertainty of many predictors, the error bands around them can be deceptively wide. In particular, it is very often the case that two predictive intervals overlap even though there is a significant difference between the actual predictions. In order to minimise confusion, predictive intervals are not normally shown in any plots but instead the question of significant difference is tested directly and discussed in the text. Standard errors are of course quoted in the text for most predictions as well. The full model coefficient tables can be found in Appendix B. There are multiple methods for computing p-values for multilevel models. The p-values shown in the coefficient tables are based on Satterthwaite estimates of the degrees of freedom, although these values play no part in the analysis in this thesis. The Pseudo R2 reported for these models is based on Xu (2003). One challenge that arises with any use of survey data is that of missing data. This has been dealt with using listwise deletion. Owing to the stacked dataset design, a respondent does not have to be excluded using this method simply because he or she has not answered a question about a particular party. Only the row corresponding to that party–individual pair is removed, while rows are included for each party that the individual did answer questions about. This means that the only individuals that had to be excluded completely were those who refused to answer any party related question—and those voters leave very little basis to impute missing values—and those who did not answer questions at the individual level. As people typically did not refuse to answer the demographic questions posed, the only problematic question was prospective economic assessment. The proportion of respondents who declined 2.3. METHOD OF ANALYSIS 61 to answer this question was 13.3 percent in 2004, 4.1 percent in 2009 and 5.4 percent in 2014. Other techniques for managing missing values were also considered. Multiple imputation in particular has much to be said for it (Rubin 1978; King et al. 2001, 50) but that approach did not prove viable here because multiple imputation techniques and software have not yet been developed for all of the multilevel models that are used in this thesis. Ultimately, the structure of the data was considered a more important issue than missing data and that is what led to the decision to use listwise deletion and multilevel modelling. The survey response rate has also been given some consideration. Response rates in the EES surveys typically ranged from 60–80 percent for the face-to-face mode but were lower for the telephone mode, sometimes below 20 percent. One approach to the issue of potential bias resulting from low response rates is post-stratification survey weighting. Survey weights have been included in the EES survey data to correct for non-response bias. These weights were computed using a raking procedure on the variables of age, sex, region, education and, in some countries, whether or not the household has a fixed phone line. In principle, weighting in this way allows for the more accurate estimation of population parameters from the survey data by reducing the effect of non-response bias. These weights are not however used in the multilevel models in this thesis. Instead, non-response bias is minimised by including all relevant demographic variables in the models as controls. Since the weights are conditioned on variables that are already being controlled for in the models, they add no extra information. There has long been a controversy in the literature about the relative merits of weighted and unweighted least squares estimators for linear regression (DuMouchel and Duncan 1983, 535) and the relative merits of model-based and sampling-based approaches to the problem of unit non-response continue to be debated today (Gelman 2007a, 2007b; Bell and Cohen 2007). The decision to use a model-based approach is motivated by the fact that the parameters of most interest are regression coefficients rather than simple means or proportions. There is also the problem that weighted estimators simply have not been developed for certain crossclassified multilevel models, so the sampling-based approach would severely limit the types of analysis that could be undertaken using these methods. The statistical analysis described in this thesis has been performed using the statistical programming language R (R Core Team 2016). In addition to the core language and its libraries, the analysis was supported by the lme4 (Bates et al. 2015), lmerTest (Kuznetsova, Brockhoff and Christensen 2016) and ordinal (Christensen 2015) packages. Most of the plots in this thesis were produced using the ggplot2 package (Wickham 2009). Finally, the arm (Gelman 62 CHAPTER 2. MEASURING THE ECONOMIC VOTE and Su 2015), dplyr (Wickham and Francois 2015) and RSQLite (Wickham, James and Falcon 2014) packages were all used heavily for utility purposes. 2.4 Conclusion This chapter has introduced the dataset and the methods that will be used throughout the rest of the thesis, as well as discussing how the key variables have been measured. This study will undertake a multilevel analysis of survey responses collected in twenty-five European Union member states. The primary data source is the pooled responses from the 2004, 2009 and 2014 waves of the European Election Studies surveys. These waves correspond to time points before, during and after the Great Recession. This survey data is supplemented with contextual data from other sources. The key dependent variable is party support, the degree to which a voter states that he or she is likely to vote for a particular party in the future. Important independent variables are the survey year, spatial distance between party and voter, party identification, incumbency and prospective economic assessment. The next chapter will introduce the basic models used with various extensions throughout this thesis. Owing to the complexity of the complete model, several simpler models are presented first, examining the first hypothesis from various angles. These simpler models are easier to interpret but only the complete model takes advantage of all of the available data, which provides a clearer overall picture. The intention behind this approach is to use the simpler models to illustrate various aspects of economic voting behaviour and then use the complete model to obtain definitive estimates. Later chapters of the thesis extend or alter these models in various ways, so as to test the remaining hypotheses. Chapter 3 Voting in a time of crisis: how the Great Recession affected the economic vote After the global financial crisis of 2007–08, most developed countries slipped into recession, in an event that has become known as the Great Recession. This was the worst event of its kind since the Great Depression of the 1930s and a number of governments suffered catastrophic electoral defeats in the following years. The example of Ireland was introduced earlier, where the formerly dominant party Fianna Fáil was reduced to approximately half of its previous vote in 2012 (Marsh and Mikhaylov 2012, 478). Such results accord with the established theory of economic voting, which predicts that poor economic conditions will lead to voters turning against their governments at the ballot box. On the other hand, this theory was almost entirely developed using evidence relating to less turbulent economic conditions, what might be described as the ordinary boom and bust cycle of the economy. Whether or not voters respond to a severe transnational crisis in the same way as a typical recession is not yet clear. This chapter explores this question by comparing voters’ party suport levels in 2004, well before the crisis, to those in 2009, at the height of the first wave of the Great Recession, and in 2014, after the initial shock had subsided. In the immediate aftermath of the Great Recession, some political commentators argued that the situation would benefit the Left, since they are traditionally critics of the economic system which produced the crisis (Bartels 2012, 44) but these expectations have not been borne out. There is little evidence of an ideological shift in OECD countries as a result of the crisis (Bartels 2014). Commenting on the United States, Bartels (2013, 70), observes that: The truth of the matter is that ideological mandates are exceedingly rare in American politics, even in times of economic crisis. Indeed, what may be most striking about the politics of the Great Recession is how ordinary they look. In bad times, as in good times, ordinary citizens have a stubborn tendency to judge politicians 63 64 CHAPTER 3. VOTING IN A TIME OF CRISIS and policies not on the basis of ideology or economic doctrine, but of perceived success or failure. Economic voting theory offers a more plausible account of electoral behaviour during the crisis. In an analysis of aggregate data from twenty-eight OECD countries, Bartels (2014, 188–194) shows that governments generally received an increased vote when GDP growth was positive and a decreased vote when negative. Kriesi (2014, 305–315) similarly finds a relationship in European countries between incumbent vote share and the economic indicators, particularly inflation in Central and Eastern Europe and unemployment in Western Europe. Kenworthy and Owens (2011, 212–216) examined US voter attitudes in survey data since the 1970s and found that voters do tend to lose confidence in whichever party is governing at the time but they also found that this effect was actually quite weak during the Great Recession. Others have also found the electoral response to the crisis to be weaker than might be expected (for example, Kriesi 2012).1 These results suggest that the electoral response to the Great Recession was an economic voting one, rather than one motivated by a deep ideological shift among voters, but they still leave questions unanswered. The key question concerning this chapter is: was the economic vote stronger during the Great Recession than at other times? Given that the recession was far deeper, this seems likely, but some of the studies just mentioned have found clues that the opposite might actually be the case. On the other hand, such findings might also be artefacts of the particular methods used by those studies, since there has not yet been enough research done to know how different approaches affect the results found. This chapter has two key purposes. First, it describes how a multilevel model was constructed to measure the economic vote using the particular theoretical framework of this thesis, and second, it uses this model to compare the economic vote before, during and after the recession by using multinational survey data from the 2004, 2009 and 2014 waves of the European Election Studies in order to shed light on the relative strength of the economic vote during the Great Recession. The chapter begins by reviewing some relevant theory and introducing the hypotheses that will be tested. After a brief discussion of measurement, a series of models is constructed, starting with a simple spatial voting model and proceeding to models that measure the economic vote using first prime ministers’ parties alone and eventually all parties. Finally, the findings will be summarised and the implications discussed. 1 See Chapter 1 for a more thorough review of the literature on economic voting during the Great Recession. 3.1. PARTY SUPPORT THEORY OF ECONOMIC VOTING 3.1 65 Party support theory of economic voting The theoretical framework of economic voting underlying this thesis was described in depth in Chapter 1. Following van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin (2007, ch. 2), the vote choice decision is conceptualised as a process in which voters have a certain level of support for each of the parties in their country and this support level is informed by such considerations as their ideological congruence with each party or how competent they believe that party to be in government. Individuals are assumed to vote for the party for whom their level of support is greatest, irrespective of the absolute level of that support. According to this model, voters form an assessment about the condition of the economy and this assessment affects their beliefs about the relative competence of the current government and opposition, which in turn affects their party support levels and potentially their vote choice. This process can thus be seen as having three stages: economic assessment, party support adjustment and finally vote choice. The focus of this thesis is on the second stage—how does a particular sociotropic economic assessment affect an individual’s party support levels? Although economic voting is conceptually straightforward, there is no consensus as to how it should be measured. In order to make the claim that one election had more economic voting than another election, the concept of economic voting has to be precisely defined and operationalised. Different scholars have used different approaches towards this end. For example, earlier studies used aggregate data, such as parties’ national vote share as well as national production or unemployment rates to make an argument about economic voting. For example, Kramer (1971) examined incumbent vote share in US House of Representatives elections. These were the only sorts of data available during the last comparable crisis, the Great Depression of the 1930s. These methods are limited, however, as it is not generally possible to make inferences about individual behaviour based on aggregate data. More recent studies tend to use individual-level data and most of these define economic voting implicitly, using regression analyses with interacting predictors to determine which contextual variables influence economic voting. It is however possible to define an explicit measure of the economic vote so that a specific figure can be estimated for the level of economic voting at a particular election. Duch and Stevenson (2008, 44–46) did just this, constructing their measure of the economic vote from survey questions asking for a respondent’s vote choice and retrospective economic assessment. An important criterion for their vote choice question was that respondents had to be explicitly offered the option of declaring no intention to vote, in which case they were excluded from the analysis. The criteria used for selecting 66 CHAPTER 3. VOTING IN A TIME OF CRISIS an economic assessment question was that it had to be retrospective, ask about the national economy and ask how the economy had changed rather than its absolute condition. They explain that the choice of retrospective rather than prospective analysis was largely dictated to them by practical concerns, particularly in that the majority of surveys available to them only included the retrospective question. In order to produce a measure of economic voting from these questions, Duch and Stevenson (2008) estimate a multinomial logistic regression model to predict the likelihood of a change in vote choice as a result of a change in retrospective assessment, with relevant controls included. For each respondent they construct a vector of the change in vote choice probabilities corresponding to an arbitrary change in assessment. They define their measure of the ‘general economic vote’ as the average size of this vector across the entire survey (49–52). This is described as the ‘general’ economic vote because this approach requires no measure of incumbency—any economically motivated change in vote choice is included in this measure. Because this is more general than most current definitions of economic voting, which see economic voting as an activity discriminating between government and opposition parties, they define several refinements of their measure conditioned on various measures of incumbency (55–59). Others are sceptical of the widespread tendency to measure economic voting in terms of vote choice, preferring to measure party support levels instead (van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin 2007, 33–36). Party support questions ask voters to assess their level of support for each of the relevant parties in their countries. They prefer a two-stage model of vote choice, in which voters decide who to vote for by selecting the party that they have the greatest level of support for at that moment, it being the party support levels rather than the vote choice directly that are influenced by the usual variables, such as economic conditions. They argue that the widespread use of vote choice as a dependent variable has contributed to the instability of economic voting results (15–16). Their argument is that when party support levels are quite close a small change in predictors can cause a change in vote choice but when those support levels are far apart, it requires a large predictor change to see a change in vote choice. Hence, according to them, it makes more sense to use party support as a dependent variable and this should lead to more consistent results. Although their study used individual-level survey data, they chose to measure economic conditions using national indicators of unemployment, inflation and economic growth, arguing that these indicators best reflect the information that voters use to form their own judgements (69–71). 3.2. HYPOTHESES 67 This study is influenced by both Duch and Stevenson (2008) and van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin (2007), and combines features of both approaches. The latter’s argument in favour of measuring party support levels rather than party choice is persuasive, particularly in light of the fact that the majority of the countries examined in this thesis are multiparty systems and therefore any analysis reducing the party system to a government–opposition dichotomy necessarily treats disparate significant parties as identical. Furthermore, using party support instead of vote choice offers the possibility of measuring not just which party a voter most prefers but also by how much. This difference in support between a voter’s first and second choice is important because if that difference is large then even a strong economic vote might not be sufficient to cause a change in vote choice but it will cause a change in party support. This choice of dependent variable is combined with Duch and Stevenson’s method of measuring the degree of economic voting at a particular election by simulating the effect of an arbitrary adjustment in economic assessment. This study also uses an individual measure of economic assessment, but a prospective measure is used, rather than their retrospective measure. There are theoretical reasons behind this choice, which are discussed extensively in Chapter 1, as well as data-driven reasons discussed in the next section. 3.2 Hypotheses This chapter tests three specific economic voting hypotheses. The first is: Hypothesis 3.1 Individuals’ party support levels were influenced by their prospective sociotropic economic assessments in each survey year. This hypothesis tests whether the specific framework of economic voting developed in this thesis so far accurately describes the intended voting behaviour of the respondents in these surveys. As this framework is built on very well-established principles of economic voting theory, a failure to confirm this hypothesis ought to be seen as a sign of flawed operationalisation, rather than a deficit in the theory. This hypothesis makes no reference to incumbency as it is concerned with the most general form of economic voting, namely any change in party support attributable to economic voting, irrespective of which parties benefit and which suffer. The second hypothesis relates to the more specific and most usual conception of economic voting, in which voters are supposed to treat government and opposition parties differently: 68 CHAPTER 3. VOTING IN A TIME OF CRISIS Hypothesis 3.2 There was an observable tendency for citizens to vote economically in each year. In particular, voters holding an optimistic economic assessment are more inclined to support government parties and less inclined to support opposition parties than those holding a pessimistic assessment. This builds directly on the first hypothesis. If it can be shown that the general form of economic voting does occur then the next step is to show that voters discriminate between these different groups of parties. One of the central claims of this thesis is that voter behaviour during times of severe global recession cannot necessarily be predicted from theories developed to describe the typical boom and bust cycle of a national economy. It has long been suspected that economic issues play a larger role in voting behaviour as they become more severe (for example, Bloom and Price 1975, 1240). Although some recent studies found the crisis response to be weaker than expected (Kenworthy and Owens 2011; Kriesi 2012), these were studies of government vote share, so they may be concealing movements that would be observable with a party support measure. This chapter’s third and final hypothesis is thus: Hypothesis 3.3 The economic voting effects were heightened during the Great Recession. Specifically, there was a greater observable tendency to vote economically in 2009 than in either 2004 or 2014. As the 2009 survey took place at the peak of the first wave of the crisis, unlike the 2004 survey, which was conducted during a time of normal economic activity, any form of crisis-specific behaviour should be observable in a comparison between the two surveys. As the economy was naturally a highly salient issue during the crisis, it is predicted that the inclination towards economic voting became stronger at that time. Similarly, once the initial shock of the recession had passed, it would be expected that normal patterns of behaviour would reassert themselves, so it is predicted that the inclination to vote economically had receded to their pre-crisis levels by 2014. 3.3 Measuring the economic vote There are strong theoretical arguments for both retrospective and prospective models of voting, and it has even been argued that the two are in many respects equivalent, as the former informs the latter (Downs 1957). Often the choice of which measure to use is driven by the 3.3. MEASURING THE ECONOMIC VOTE 69 Figure 3.1: Support for incumbent prime minister’s party by economic assessment 2004 2009 2014 7 6 prospective 5 mean support 4 3 2 7 6 retrospective 5 4 3 2 -2 -1 0 1 2 -2 -1 0 1 2 -2 -1 0 1 2 economic assessment Mean support for the incumbent prime minister’s party according to the respondent’s prospective and retrospective economic assessment in each survey year, shown with 95% confidence intervals and accounting for party-level variance. Both forms of economic assessment are measured on a five-point scale ranging from −2, indicating a very negative assessment, to +2, indicating a very positive assessment, with 0 indicating a neutral assessment. Source: EES available data, and this is an important consideration here too. Although each survey includes both retrospective and prospective economic assessment questions, descriptive analysis shows that these questions are not equally useful, particularly in 2009 during the crisis. In both 2004 and 2014, responses to the prospective and retrospective questions are similarly distributed, appearing approximately binomial besides a marked tendency for respondents to avoid the most positive category. In 2009, the prospective assessment variable is similarly distributed but the distribution of the retrospective assessment variable is heavily skewed towards the negative responses, with fewer than eight percent of respondents giving a positive response. This is not surprising, since the condition of the economy at that time had in fact worsened badly, but it does mean that the retrospective evaluation in 2009 is not suitable for use in this analysis, as there is too little variance. 70 CHAPTER 3. VOTING IN A TIME OF CRISIS Prospective assessment can be predicted from retrospective assessment by a simple linear model with moderate success in both 2004 (R2 = 0.30) and 2014 (R2 = 0.39), which confirms the Downsian view that the two measures can be seen as related. On the other hand, this relationship breaks down in 2009, with the same model no longer able to predict prospective assessment with any accuracy (R2 = 0.08). It is interesting that, despite the consensus among respondents about the worsening of the economy over the past year, there was still a diversity in opinion regarding its future course, with a similar distribution to that of the other years. Furthermore, since the dependent variable is prospective in orientation too, it is more consistent to choose a prospective orientation for the economic assessment measure as well. Finally, the relationship between support for the prime minister’s party in each country and both economic assessment measures was examined. As Figure 3.1 shows, the relationship between these measures is approximately linear, except in the case of retrospective assessment in 2009. For these reasons, only the prospective measures are used in this thesis. A measure of party support has been constructed from a sequence of questions included in each of the EES surveys asking voters the likelihood that they would ever vote for each of a number of parties in their countries, on a scale from zero to ten, where zero is described as ‘not at all probable’ and ten as ‘very probably’. Although the question does ask respondents if they would ‘ever’ vote for a particular party, this interpretation treats the responses as current support for that party instead, and there is some evidence that the respondents interpret the question that way as well. For example, even people who stated that they identify with a particular party do not overwhelmingly respond with ten for that party. Furthermore, the fact that there is a relationship, as will be shown, between this measure and questions about recent economic conditions does suggest that the current feeling interpretation is more appropriate than a strict reading of the question as posed. As each individual responds to several party support questions, corresponding to the key parties in their country, there is one measurement for each party–individual pair, and these measurements have been centred around the group mean for each individual.2 3.4 A spatial model of party support Naturally the economy is not the only consideration that influences a person’s party support levels. As outlined in Chapter 1, there is an enormous vote choice literature describing the various influences that are known to affect the vote choice decision. In order to obtain unbiased 2 More details on the measurement of this and other variables can be found in Chapter 2. 3.4. A SPATIAL MODEL OF PARTY SUPPORT 71 Figure 3.2: Relationship between party support and left–distance mean support 5 4 3 2 1 0 2 4 6 8 10 left–right distance Mean support for parties according to the left–right distance between the party and the respondent, shown with 95% confidence intervals and accounting for variance at the individual, party and country levels. Source: EES estimates of the influence of economic considerations on party support, other key influences need to be controlled for. There are two key predictors that will be taken into account, spatial proximity and party identification. In order to measure spatial proximity, survey questions asking respondents to place both themselves and each major party in their country on the left–right spectrum are used. It is expected that those voters who consider themselves close to a party on the left–right spectrum will generally have a greater level of support for that party than those who consider themselves further away. There is however no reason to expect that relationship to be linear, as the difference between zero and one point of distance, representing a change from a complete alignment to a close alignment, is conceivably of greater significance to a voter than the difference between nine and ten points of distance, both of which represent a fundamental mismatch. Plotting the mean party support for each level of left–right distance confirms that this relationship is indeed negative and non-linear, as Figure 3.2 shows. As well as spatial proximity, party identification is known to be an important predictor of vote choice. Accordingly, it is expected to be a strong predictor of party support as well and cursory analysis of the data confirms that these two variables are closely correlated. Plotting 72 CHAPTER 3. VOTING IN A TIME OF CRISIS mean party support against left–right distance for party identifiers and non-identifiers separately shows that the effect of left–right distance is different for the two groups. In order to model these characteristics accurately, the model needs to include both a linear and quadratic term for the left–right distance variable as well as an interaction between left–right distance and party identification. This leads to the following regression equation for a single party: y = β0 + β1 ∆ + β2 ∆2 + β3 I + β4 ∆I + ε, where y represents an individual’s support for that party, ∆ represents the mean-centred left– right distance between that individual and that party and I is a dummy variable indicating that the individual identifies with that party.3 The dependent variable, party support, has been centred around the mean for each individual. Most individuals surveyed recorded a level of support for each of several parties, so the mean response for a particular individual was subtracted from that individual’s response for each party. This was done because it is the difference between the levels of support for each party that is of most interest in this models and the absolute levels may be misleading if different respondents adopted different conceptual reference points when responding to these questions. Another advantage of centring the dependent variable in this way is that the centred variable is more approximately normal than the raw variable, which is heavily skewed because respondents are much more likely to assign low scores than high scores. The assumption of residual normality is therefore more plausible using the centred variable. The means are examined separately later in the chapter. The predictors have also been centred in order to improve the efficiency of the estimation process. This should not in principle change the particular coefficient estimates but it does mean that the intercept estimate can no longer be directly interpreted. The left–right distance variable has been centred around the mean for each election, that is each country and year. The party identification dummy variable was centred around the grand mean. In addition to these predictors, a number of further predictors were included to control for personal attributes generally known to influence voting behaviour. These predictors were age, sex, education, population density and labour force status. Age is measured in decades, so that the corresponding coefficient is not too small to be conveniently interpreted. Education level is divided into three groups, the first being those with a university degree, the second 3 An argument could be made for the inclusion of an interaction between the quadratic distance term and the party identification dummy variable but empirical tests have shown that the models including that term are not significantly more accurate, so it has been omitted for the sake of parsimony. 3.5. THE PRIME MINISTER’S PARTY AND THE ECONOMIC VOTE 73 being those who have not completed high school and the reference group being those who have completed high school but who do not possess a university degree. Population density is also divided into three groups, those residing in cities, those residing in towns and those in rural areas, the reference group being towns. Lastly, labour force status is divided into working, unemployed and other groups. The other group consists of people who are not in the workforce for any reason, such as retirement. The reference group is workers.4 All of these control variables were centred around the grand mean. An interaction has also been included between party identification and age, since it has been known for some time that party identification tends to be stronger among older people (Campbell et al. 1960, 161–164; Converse 1976; Berglund et al. 2005). As was mentioned earlier, the dependent variable, party support, has been centred around each individual’s mean response, so as to control for differing centres of support. Modelling the uncentred variable with these control variables has shown that there are relationships between some of the controls and an individual’s mean party support. For example, women tend to report higher levels of party support than men do, irrespective of the party, although the difference in levels of support between the parties does not appear to be related to these variables. A naive analysis of an arbitrary party would thus be likely to conclude that women are more likely to support that party, even when this is not the case. Centring party support in this way avoids this problem, while preserving the differences in support between the parties. 3.5 The prime minister’s party and the economic vote There are several ways this spatial model can be extended in order to test the hypotheses posited at the beginning of this chapter. One of the most straightforward ways to do this is to analyse support for only the prime minister’s party in each country. As this is the party that could be expected to be most strongly affected by any economic voting effect, if the hypotheses are true then this ought to be reflected in such a model. This does not mean that the other parties in each country are ignored. Since the party support variable is centred around the individual’s mean response, it is not measuring absolute support for the prime minister’s party but rather the relative support for that party. Therefore, even situations where the absolute level of support for the prime minister’s party remains steady while that for opposition parties increases would be observed by such a model. Another advantage of this approach is that the multilevel structure of the data can be simplified considerably. The data can be described by 4 Further details on how these variables were measured can be found in Chapter 2. 74 CHAPTER 3. VOTING IN A TIME OF CRISIS Table 3.1: Prime ministers’ parties model Fixed effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Left–right distance Left–right distance2 Party ID Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Distance × party ID Age × party ID Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 Coeff. 0.067 0.490 0.159 −0.428 0.023 4.706 0.323 0.054 −0.007 0.084 0.028 −0.018 0.065 −0.083 0.052 0.280 0.179 −0.051 −0.038 SE (0.095) (0.183) (0.130) (0.019) (0.001) (0.129) (0.053) (0.021) (0.008) (0.025) (0.031) (0.026) (0.027) (0.043) (0.025) (0.029) (0.015) (0.048) (0.065) p 0.492 0.014 0.235 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.011 0.353 0.001 0.357 0.495 0.016 0.055 0.038 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.310 0.565 Fixed effect coefficient estimates from Model 3A. The dependent variable is support for the incumbent prime minister’s party in the respondent’s country. Several country-level random effects terms are also included in the model and the corresponding variance estimates can be found in Appendix B. Sample size is 51962 individuals within 25 countries. Pseudo R2 is 0.541. Source: EES a two-level model, where individuals are grouped within countries. No party level is required as each country only has one prime minister’s party. Several things have to be done in order to extend the spatial party support model to measure economic voting intention for prime ministers’ parties in each of the studied countries. The intention of Model 3A is to measure the effect of economic assessment on party support, so a prospective economic assessment predictor was added to the model, centred around the grand mean. The survey year is indicated by the addition of dummy variables for 2009 and 2014, using 2004 as the reference case. Interaction terms between the time and economic assessment variables were also added, so that it can be ascertained whether the degree of economic voting differed among the three years. As this is a multilevel model, a random intercept for the country was added, along with several random slopes. The economic assessment and time variables, as well as their interactions, were given random slopes so that it is not assumed that the degree of economic voting intention was equal in every country. Similarly, the party identification and left–right distance variables and their interaction were given random 3.5. THE PRIME MINISTER’S PARTY AND THE ECONOMIC VOTE 75 Figure 3.3: Predicted support for prime minister’s party by left–right distance predicted support 8 6 group party identifiers others 4 2 0 2 4 6 8 10 left–right distance Predicted support for the incumbent prime minister’s party in 2004 according to the left–right distance between the respondent and party as well as whether the respondent identifies with that party or not. Predictions are derived from Model 3A and are shown with 95% predictive intervals. These predictions assume a neutral prospective economic assessment. Source: EES slopes because single-party analysis showed that the shape of these relationships differed often considerably from party to party. Random slopes were considered for each of the control variables as well but the estimated variances of these slopes were very small and the resulting models did not fit the data significantly better, so these were not included in the final model. The key results from this model are shown in Table 3.1. As most of the variables have been centred, it is not trivial to interpret the intercept or the interaction coefficients. For this reason, post-estimation simulation has been used to derive estimates of the quantities of interest.5 As expected, spatial proximity is an important predictor of party support. Figure 3.3 shows the relationship between left–right distance and predicted party support for both the party identifier and non-party identifier groups in 2004. In both groups, it is assumed that the individual has a neutral prospective assessment of the economy.6 From this plot it can be seen that party support falls as left–right distance increases but that the size of this drop diminishes 5 The post-estimation simulation approach to interpreting complex models is used throughout this thesis. Since the regression coefficients are usually not interpreted directly, the coefficient tables for most of the models discussed are not included in the main text but can be found in Appendix B. See Chapter 2 for a more detailed discussion of this decision and the reasons behind it. 6 Unless otherwise specified, these predictions are for a 40-year old male who has completed high school but not university, who lives in a town and is employed. 76 CHAPTER 3. VOTING IN A TIME OF CRISIS with increasing distance. In other words, the difference between zero and one point of distance is much more important than the difference between nine and ten points of distance. It can also be seen that party identifiers have a much stronger level of support than non-identifiers at any degree of proximity. In fact, the importance of distance is weaker for identifiers than nonidentifiers. There is one surprising feature of this plot, which is that after six points of distance, it appears that further distance is associated with increased party support. This is most likely an anomaly resulting from the fact that few respondents identify with a party on the other side of the political spectrum from themselves. In fact, the error around the predictions is large enough that a levelling off is perfectly plausible. The inclusion of prospective economic assessment in the model makes it possible to estimate the economic vote.7 Because interactions were included between this variable and the time dummy variables, the model gives a measure of the economic vote in each year. In particular, the economic vote for a particular party will be defined as the difference in party support between the optimists, those who believed the economy will be much better in twelve months time, and the pessimists, those who believed the economy will be much worse in twelve months time. In other words, this quantity is the total change in an individual’s support for a particular party that could be accounted for in the model by a change in economic assessment. For example, the party support predicted by the prime minister’s party model for an individual in 2004 who does not identify with that party but who occupies the same position on the left–right spectrum is 5.21 (SE = 0.19, p < 0.001) if that individual is an optimist but only 3.92 (SE = 0.12, p < 0.001) if that individual is a pessimist. The difference, and hence the estimated economic vote in 2004, is 1.29 points (SE = 0.21, p < 0.001). By contrast, the estimated economic vote for 2009 is only 1.09 points (SE = 0.13, p < 0.001). There was thus an apparent decline in the economic vote between the two years of 0.20 points (SE = 0.19, p = 0.30) but this was not significant. Similarly, the estimated economic vote for 2014 is 1.14 points (SE = 0.17, p < 0.001), which is not significantly different from either 2009 (∆ = 0.06, SE = 0.21, p = 0.79) or 2014 (∆ = 0.14, SE = 0.26, p = 0.58). In other words, this model suggests that the strength of the economic vote was approximately constant over the entire period, at least when considering prime ministers’ parties only. Figure 3.4 shows the relationship between prospective economic assessment and 7 The term ‘economic vote’ is used in this thesis to describe any change in voters’ support for the different parties in their countries that can be attributed to their assessment of the economy. This might not necessarily be manifested as an actual vote choice for several reasons, which are discussed in Chapter 1. The empirical focus of this thesis is on the stage of the voting process in which party support levels are formed, which precedes the vote choice stage. 3.5. THE PRIME MINISTER’S PARTY AND THE ECONOMIC VOTE 77 Figure 3.4: Predicted support for prime minister’s party by economic assessment 6.0 predicted support 5.5 year 5.0 2004 2009 2014 4.5 4.0 -2 -1 0 1 2 prospective economic assessment Predicted support for the prime minister’s party according to prospective economic assessment for each survey year, based on Model 3A. Economic assessment ranges from −2 (very pessimistic) to +2 (very optimistic). These predictions are for an individual who does not identify with the party and who occupies the same left–right position as the party. Source: EES predicted support for the prime minister’s party in each year. The slope of each line indicates the strength of the economic vote in the corresponding year, so the fact that the three lines are approximately parallel reflects its stability over time. It is interesting to note that the lines do not overlap, despite being approximately parallel. This suggests the level of support for the prime minister’s party was greater in some years than in others, irrespective of the individual’s economic assessment. In particular, it appears that support was greatest in 2009. For example, a typical voter holding a neutral economic assessment was 0.48 points (SE = 0.18, p < 0.01) more supportive of the prime minister’s party in 2009 and 0.32 points (SE = 0.18, p = 0.06) more supportive in 2014 than in 2004. Thus, although the economic vote for prime ministers’ parties was stable over time, those parties did receive a small boost in support at the height of the recession, irrespective of economic assessment. In general, the control variables have little if any effect. Women are slightly more likely to support the prime minister’s party than men, although the size of this effect is tiny, accounting for an increase in party support of only 0.05 points (SE = 0.02, p = 0.01). For comparison, an increase from zero to one point of distance accounts for a decrease of 0.57 points (SE = 0.02, 78 CHAPTER 3. VOTING IN A TIME OF CRISIS p < 0.001). Education also plays a modest role, with support 0.08 points (SE = 0.02, p < 0.001) greater among university educated voters than voters who have not attended university. The effect of employment status is likewise small. The employed and unemployed groups are not significantly different from each other (∆ = 0.08, SE = 0.04, p = 0.06) but the not in the workforce group is slightly more likely to support the prime minister’s party. Once again this effect is tiny, accounting for a mere 0.05 point (SE = 0.02, p = 0.04) increase in party support over the employed group. Age has an even smaller effect, with each extra decade of age associated with a 0.02 point (SE = 0.01, p < 0.01) decrease in support.8 There is also an interaction between the effects of age and party identification, and this is more substantial. At the age of twenty, party identification is associated with a 3.30 point (SE = 0.13, p < 0.001) increase in party support and this is increased by a further 0.18 points (SE = 0.02, p < 0.001) for each additional decade of age. In summary, Model 3A offers evidence that support for the prime minister’s party is linked to the individual’s prospective assessment of the economy, with optimistic voters being more supportive than pessimistic voters. These findings support the first two hypotheses. The third hypothesis predicted that the strength of the economic vote would be greater in 2009 but this was not supported by the model, which found the economic vote to be stable over time. It was however found that support for prime ministers’ parties was slightly higher in 2009 than at other times and this was true irrespective of economic assessment. This model has the advantage of being relatively straightforward to interpret but it is also limited by the fact that it only analyses support for a single party in each country. This is problematic because a change in support for the prime minister’s party is of limited import if support for all of the other parties moved in the same way.9 The next section discusses how this model can be extended to take into consideration support for multiple parties in this country and thus address this limitation. 3.6 A multiparty model of the economic vote The economic voting model developed thus far can be generalised to analyse not only prime ministers’ parties but also the other parties in each country. In principle, this requires a far 8 This may appear to contradict Table 3.1, which shows no significant age effect. This apparent contradiction arises because the model includes an interaction between party identification and age. Since the party identification variable has been centred, it is not actually zero for non-party identifiers. This illustrates why post-estimation simulation has been used to interpret model estimates rather than discussing regression coefficients directly. 9 As the dependent variable is centred around the individual’s mean party support level, parallel movement has already been eliminated, so this particular example would not be a problem in practice. Unfortunately, there are similar situations that are not neutralised by centring the dependent variable, so these possibilities do require serious consideration. 3.6. A MULTIPARTY MODEL OF THE ECONOMIC VOTE 79 Figure 3.5: Data classification structures Country Country Party Individual Party Measurement Measurement (a) Classification structure of the stacked dataset. Measurements are cross-classified into parties and individuals, which are also independently nested within countries. (b) Simpler, hierarchical classification structure in which measurements are nested within parties and parties are nested within countries. more complex model in order to be analysed accurately. This is because the same individuals responded to questions about each party within a country, so measurements such as the left– right distance between a party and an individual are cross-classified within both parties and individuals. Furthermore, both of those groups are nested within countries. Because of this data structure, which is illustrated in Figure 3.5a, it is important to be aware of the possibility that observations within these groups are more alike than observations from different groups. The degree of this within-group similarity can be measured by the intraclass correlation. The intraclass correlation of the uncentred party support variable is 0.08 by individual, 0.13 by party and 0.01 by country. This implies that measurements within a particular individual or a particular party are more similar than between those groups but once these effects have been accounted for there is very little further similarity between measurements within a given country. Since the party support variable has actually been centred around the individual-level mean, some of the within-group similarity can be expected to have been eliminated. In fact, the intraclass correlation of the centred party support variable is 0.14 by party and zero by both individual and country. This suggests that random intercepts are only required for the party level, despite the complex structure of the data. Even though the intraclass correlations of the other groups are low, it is still possible that random slopes might be required for these groups, so a subset of the data was used to explore various options but in every case the variance of the random slope was either too small for the model to be estimated successfully or a chi-square difference test showed the resulting model not to be a significant improvement over the equivalent model without the random slope. In other words, the full complexity of the cross-classified model is not required and the data can be modelled with the hierarchical structure shown in Figure 3.5b 80 CHAPTER 3. VOTING IN A TIME OF CRISIS instead. This means that the generalised model need only differ from the prime minister’s party model in two respects. First, it can include a number of parties in each country, rather than just the one. And second, whereas the random intercept and slopes are grouped by country in the simpler model, they are grouped by party in the generalised model. Of course, this difference is purely a question of interpretation, as with only one party per country in the prime minister’s party model, the party and country groupings are identical. Model 3B was formed in this way and differs from the prime minister’s party model in one further respect, which is the inclusion of party-level random slopes for each of the control variables.10 The results from this model are similar in most respects to those from the prime minister’s party model but there are some important differences. Since not just incumbent parties but also opposition parties are included in this model, it would be expected that the fixed effect for party support would no longer be significantly different from zero. That is, whereas a unit increase in optimism about the economy is associated with a small increase in support for the prime minister’s party, it is not expected to be associated with an increase in support for any arbitrary party. Using the same measure of economic voting intention as before, namely the change in predicted party support associated with the maximum possible increase in prospective economic assessment, the economic voting intention for an arbitrary party was −0.13 points (SE = 0.09, p = 0.14) in 2004, −0.07 points (SE = 0.08, p = 0.34) in 2009 and −0.13 points (SE = 0.08, p = 0.13). None of these is statistically significant, nor is any of the differences between them. This confirms these expectations. Although the economic voting intention for an arbitrary party is not significant, this is not necessarily the case for a specific known party. It has already been shown that for prime ministers’ parties this effect is positive. Furthermore, the theory predicts a negative economic voting intention for opposition parties. Because the model includes random slopes for the economic assessment and time variables as well as the interaction between them, it is possible to extract separate economic voting intention estimates for each party. Figure 3.6 shows the estimated economic voting intention for each party grouped by year and incumbency status. This shows that in each year, government parties were usually subject to a positive economic voting intention and opposition parties were mostly subject to a negative economic voting effect, although there are some exceptions, particularly among opposition parties. Note also that the points in 10 These random slopes make sense from a theoretical perspective because different parties can be expected to appeal to different groups in society, so the control effects ought to take different values for different parties. This argument applies equally well to 3A but in practice the variances were low enough to cause convergence problems with the smaller sample size, so they were omitted from that model. 3.6. A MULTIPARTY MODEL OF THE ECONOMIC VOTE 81 Figure 3.6: Economic vote by year and incumbency status 2004 3 2009 2014 ● ● ● ● economic vote 2 1 ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● 0 ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● −1 −2 ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● −3 op ine po t si tio n PM ca b op ine po t si tio n PM ca b op ine po t si tio n ca b PM ● Economic vote for each party according to the survey year and whether the party was the prime minister’s party, a junior coalition partner or an opposition party. Economic vote is the predicted increase in support for a party associated with the maximum possible increase in prospective economic assessment, based on Model 3B. Each point represents a single party. Source: EES & ParlGov each group are less spread out in 2009 than they are in the other years. The standard deviation of the party economic votes in 2009 was 0.77 points, compared to 1.20 points in 2004, and 0.91 points in 2014. This suggests that the overall amount of economic voting decreased during the recession and recovered partially in the following period. The above analysis suggests that an optimistic economic assessment is typically associated with an increased support for government parties and a decreased support for opposition parties but it does not test this hypothesis. In order to do so, the model was extended so as to include an incumbency term and the interactions between incumbency and the terms used to measure the level of economic voting intention. The resulting Model 3C allows for the possibility that economic voting intention differs for government and opposition parties. This was done by including a dummy variable to distinguish between government parties, those represented in cabinet, and other, opposition, parties. The model also includes a random slope at the country level for the interaction between incumbency and prospective economic assessment, which allows for the possibility that the amount of economic voting was different in different countries. A random intercept for the country level was also added. Random slopes 82 CHAPTER 3. VOTING IN A TIME OF CRISIS Figure 3.7: Predicted support by year and incumbency status 2004 2009 2014 ● ● ● predicted support 4.50 ● ● ● ● 4.25 ● ● ● ● 4.00 ● 3.75 3.50 ● ● ● −2 −1 0 1 2 −2 −1 0 1 2 −2 −1 0 1 2 prospective economic assessment status ● government opposition Predicted support for a party according to the respondent’s prospective economic assessment, the party’s incumbency status and the survey year, based on Model 3C. Economic assessment ranges from −2 (very pessimistic) to +2 (very optimistic). These predictions are for an individual who does not identify with the party and who occupies the same left–right position as the party. Source: EES & ParlGov were considered for related terms, such as the three-way interactions between incumbency, economic assessment and time, but these had a variance very close to zero and were therefore omitted. This extended model was used to estimate the net economic vote, that is, the total predicted change in support for governing parties relative to opposition parties that can be attributed to economic assessment. For example, in 2004, the economic vote for government parties was 1.02 points (SE = 0.15, p < 0.001) and the economic vote for opposition parties was −0.70 points (SE = 0.10, p < 0.001). This means that the net economic vote for 2004 was 1.72 points (SE = 0.20, p < 0.001). As expected, the economic vote is significant and positive for government parties in each year and significant and negative for opposition parties in each year. The net economic vote in 2009 was only 1.18 points (SE = 0.19, p < 0.001), which is 0.55 points (SE = 0.20, p < 0.01) less than in 2004. By 2014, the net economic vote was 1.22 points (SE = 0.19, p < 0.001), which is not significantly greater (∆ = 0.05, SE = 0.19, p = 0.81) than in 2009. In other words, the net economic vote became weaker during the recession and did not recover in the following years. 3.6. A MULTIPARTY MODEL OF THE ECONOMIC VOTE 83 The economic vote in the three different years can be seen graphically in Figure 3.7. The lines show the relationship between economic assessment and party support in each year. The solid lines show government support while the dashed lines show opposition support. The fact that an optimistic assessment is good for government parties and bad for opposition parties is reflected by the positive slope for each of the government lines and the negative slope for the opposition lines. The steeper slopes in 2004 show the stronger economic vote in that year. This figure also shows that support for government parties was greater in 2009 and 2014 than in 2004, irrespective of the voter’s economic assessment. As a result of this increase in government support, the intersection point of the lines appears to have changed over time. This would imply that a more strongly pessimistic assessment was required to cause a net shift in support towards the government in those later years. In fact, it is only in 2004 that the intersection occurs at a point corresponding to an economic assessment significantly different from completely neutral, specifically −0.79 [−1.50, −0.22].11 The corresponding assessments were −0.18 [−0.62, 0.25], in 2004 and −0.39 [−1.01, 0.16], in 2014. On the other hand, none of the differences between these assessments was significantly different,12 so it cannot be concluded that this apparent difference did not arise by chance. So far this discussion has only contrasted government and opposition parties. It has been suggested that the prime minister’s party ought to be more strongly affected by economic voting than junior coalition partners (van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin 2007, 56–58). The argument is that these parties are often able to criticise the government during election campaigns and make the case to voters that they ought to have more seats and so be in a position to demand greater influence within a government. The prime minister’s party naturally lacks this freedom to distance itself so easily from the government’s performance. In order to test this hypothesis, Model 3D was formed by adding further terms to distinguish prime ministers’ parties from other cabinet parties. Based on this model, it appears that prime ministers’ parties typically are subject to a somewhat stronger economic vote than other coalition parties. This stronger economic vote amounts to an additional 0.44 points (SE = 0.23, p = 0.06) in 2004, 0.61 points (SE = 0.21, p < 0.01) in 2009 and 0.70 points (SE = 0.22, p < 0.01) in 2014. These effect is not significantly different from year to year and the estimated variance of the corresponding random slope is very close to zero. This suggests that the extra economic vote that prime ministers’ parties receive is stable across both time and country. The results from 11 Square brackets indicate 95% confidence intervals. The difference between 2004 and 2009 was −0.61 [−1.42, 0.09], the difference between 2009 and 2014 was 0.40 [−0.41, 1.27] and the difference between 2004 and 2014 was −0.22 [−0.96, 0.50]. 12 84 CHAPTER 3. VOTING IN A TIME OF CRISIS this model are otherwise similar to the results from the previous model, which only distinguishes government and opposition parties. The multiparty approach to modelling the economic vote has confirmed that a positive economic vote is not only associated with increased support for governing parties but also decreased support for opposition parties. These results support for the first two hyptotheses. It was also found that prime ministers’ parties in particular are more strongly exposed to economic voting effects than other opposition parties. The net strength of the economic vote became weaker during the recession, rather than stronger as the third hypothesis predicted. This result also appears to contradict the earlier finding that the economic vote that prime ministers’ parties were exposed to remained stable over time. This is actually not a contradiction as the net economic vote takes into account the impact of economic assessment on both government and opposition parties. In fact, the results from Model 3D confirm both that the economic vote for prime ministers’ parties remained stable over time and that the net economic vote fell in 2009. This is interesting because it implies that the weakening in the economic vote occurred not because voters were more forgiving of their governments than usual but rather because they were less inclined to support opposition parties in their stead. 3.7 Influence of the economy on mean party support Since the dependent variable has been centred around its individual-level means, the analysis presented so far only takes into consideration relative changes in party support, not a shift in mean party support. That is, any increase in support for one party at the expense of another is observed but an increase in support for all parties would not be evident. Although it is this relative change that is of primary interest, it is worth exploring the possibility of absolute change in party support in order to gain a more complete understanding of voter behaviour. This can be done by examining the means of the various party support scores given by each respondent to the parties in his or her country. These are the same values that the scores were centred around to form the centred party support used as the dependent variable in the earlier models. Model 3E was constructed to predict mean party support from an individual’s prospective economic assessment, their demographics and the year, as well as the interaction between their economic assessment and the year. This corresponds to the basic economic voting model introduced earlier except that none of the party-specific variables are included as they are not meaningful here. As with earlier models, random slopes have been included for the time and economic assessment variables and their interactions. 3.7. INFLUENCE OF THE ECONOMY ON MEAN PARTY SUPPORT 85 The results from the mean party support model are consistent with the findings made so far. The predicted mean party support for an individual with a neutral economic assessment was 3.62 points (SE = 0.11, p < 0.001) in 2004, 3.27 points (SE = 0.10, p < 0.001) in 2009 and 3.19 points (SE = 0.10, p < 0.001) in 2014. This means that voters were less supportive (∆ = 0.38, SE = 0.15, p = 0.02) of all parties in 2009 than in 2004. There was no significant difference (∆ = 0.08, SE = 0.11, p = 0.48) between 2009 and 2014. The predicted increase in mean party support associated with a maximal increase in economic assessment was 0.52 points (SE = 0.10, p < 0.001) in 2004. This means that optimistic voters were more likely to to report higher support for all parties than pessimistic voters. By 2009, this had fallen by 0.21 points (SE = 0.09, p = 0.02) to 0.31 points (SE = 0.09, p < 0.001) and by 2014 it had risen by 0.49 points (SE = 0.13, p < 0.001) to 0.80 points (SE = 0.10, p < 0.001). This is also significantly greater (SE = 0.14, p = 0.04) than the 2004 level. Taken together, this means that voters became less supportive overall of their political parties during the recession and their overall support was less strongly influenced by their economic assessment. This is consistent with the earlier findings that economic voting effects generally were depressed in 2009. Some of the control variables were also shown to have a significant effect on mean party support. Each extra decade of age was associated with a 0.09 point (SE = 0.004, p < 0.001) decrease in mean party support. Women had a slightly higher mean party support level than men (0.10 points, SE = 0.01, p < 0.001). Those with a university education had a mean party support level 0.03 points (SE = 0.02, p = 0.02) greater than those who had only finished high school. The differences between the other education groups were not significant. There were also no significant differences between people living in cities, towns or rural areas. Unemployed voters had a mean support level 0.04 points (SE = 0.03, p = 0.10) greater than unemployed voters and 0.07 points (SE = 0.03, p < 0.01) greater than those not in the workforce. Although many of these differences are statistically significant, the effect sizes are very small. Furthermore, this model has a pseudo R2 of only 0.12, meaning that almost all of the variance in mean party support is unexplained by these variables.13 These results seem to confirm the assumption of the earlier models that it is primarily relative party support and not absolute party support that is affected by the key variables of interest. 13 It is well known that feeling thermometer scales and survey attitude measurements suffer from low reliability (Wilcox, Sigelman and Cook 1989; Alwin and Krosnick 1991; Alwin 1997), so it should not be surprising that there is so much residual variation. Individual variation in absolute scores need not affect the substantive results of this study, so long as relative party support is consistent. 86 CHAPTER 3. VOTING IN A TIME OF CRISIS 3.8 Conclusion This chapter has tested three main hypotheses. The first hypothesis was that party support was influenced by an optimistic economic assessment and the second was that this improved support for government parties and reduced support for opposition parties respectively. The evidence strongly supports both of these hypotheses. In all three years economic perceptions had a clearly observable effect on party support and this is apparent in the relatively simple prime minister’s party model as well as the more complex multiparty models. The former model further suggests that this operates in the expected direction, inasmuch as prime ministers’ parties benefit from a positive economic assessment. The multiparty model confirms that this is the case and demonstrates that other cabinet parties also benefit from such an assessment and that opposition parties benefit from a negative economic assessment. These results are not very surprising as they are in agreement with a large economic voting literature. What makes these results significant is that they demonstrate the validity of the multilevel party support approach to measuring economic voting. Although party support models have been pioneered by van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin (2007), the use of party support within a multilevel model is novel, so it is important to show that this method can replicate what is already known. The third hypothesis is that these economic voting effects were heightened during the Great Recession. This question has generated little prior comparative research, as these events were quite recent. The expectation was that the increased salience of the economy would have led voters to be more inclined than usual to hold their governments to account for the exceptionally bad economic conditions at the time. In fact, these findings show the opposite to have been the case. The size of the net economic voting effect was shown to be considerably smaller in 2009 than in 2004 and it had not recovered to its pre-recession levels by 2014. What this means is that a larger change in economic assessment was required to achieve a unit change in party support in 2009 than in 2004. However, this may not necessarily have been to the benefit of incumbents. The change in party support required for a change in vote choice depends on how close the prior party support levels were, so if the party support levels were close enough then even the smaller economic voting effect could have led to a change in government. Although surprising, others have also found the electoral response to the crisis to be weaker than expected (Kriesi 2012; Kenworthy and Owens 2011). How do we explain this surprising result? One possibility is that during the Great Recession, the economy may have been seen as a less useful tool to discriminate between parties. 3.8. CONCLUSION 87 As many opposition parties have previously been in government, if the crisis were seen as a structural issue then even opposition parties may have been held partly responsible for the situation, depressing the importance of the economic vote. If this were the case, then it would be expected to see a move away from the centre or that extreme or anti-system parties would benefit from negative perceptions of the economy. This possibility is explored in detail in Chapter 5. Another potential explanation is that voter dissatisfaction was not expressed by a change in party support but by an increased likelihood of abstaining from voting. This idea is explored in Chapter 6. A third potential explanation is that voters did not hold their own governments responsible for the crisis. They could hold the financial sector responsible, for example, or the European Union, which has centralised certain aspects of economic governance. This possibility is explored in Chapter 7, which looks at how attitudes towards the European Union have evolved over the same period studied in this chapter. Chapter 4 Clarity of responsibility during a global recession An enduring difficulty for the theory of economic voting has been the so-called ‘great instability’ of the economic vote, which refers to the fact that empirical studies of certain countries at particular times have found very strong evidence of an economic voting effect while similar studies of different countries or different times have found little if any evidence of such an effect (Paldam 1991, 26). One proposed explanation for this instability is that some countries and times provide more favourable contexts for economic voting behaviour than others (Powell and Whitten 1993). In particular, it is argued that citizens are most likely to engage in economic voting when there is a clearly recognisable authority who is seen to be responsible for the state of the economy. This ‘clarity of responsibility’ is stronger in some countries and at some times than others, depending upon both institutional design and the degree to which a single party controls the institutions of government (C. J. Anderson 2000; Nadeau, Niemi and Yoshinaka 2002). For example, institutional designs in which a single-party executive effectively dominates the government ought to have a higher economic vote than a country in which power is shared across multiple parties and multiple branches of government. Thus parliamentary systems ought to be expected to experience a higher level of economic voting than presidential systems, for example, since power is less divided. The economic vote should also be higher during periods of majority government than periods of coalition government, for the same reason. An alternative explanation for the instability of economic voting findings is model misspecification. Van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin (2007, 16) argue that this instability results from the widespread use of vote choice as a dependent variable and contend that party support models, such as the models developed in the previous chapter, are better suited for measuring the economic vote.1 It is worth noting that both the clarity of responsibility and party support approaches would explain the weak level of empirical support for economic voting in multiparty systems. In the former case, this is because the coalition governments and 1 See Chapter 1 for a detailed explanation of this argument. 89 90 CHAPTER 4. CLARITY OF RESPONSIBILITY DURING A GLOBAL RECESSION limited executive control that feature in many multiparty systems of government are among the key characteristics of low-clarity contexts (Whitten and Palmer 1999). In the latter case, one of the key intentions of the party support approach is to provide a better measure of the economic vote in contexts where the vote choice cannot meaningfully be described as a binary one (van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin 2007, 8–15). This overlap in intention between the two approaches raises the question as to whether a clarity of responsibility effect can be found when party support rather than vote choice is used to measure the economic vote. This chapter answers this question by extending the economic voting models from the previous chapter to take clarity of responsibility into account. The chapter begins by discussing the theory of clarity of responsibility and some recent relevant developments in that area. Following on from that is a discussion of how clarity of responsibility will be measured for this analysis. Next, three specific hypotheses are introduced, which test whether clarity of responsibility effects can be found and whether they appear to be constant over time. The following analysis is broken into two parts. The first part tests the chapter’s hypotheses by analysing citizens’ support for whichever party happens to control the office of prime minister at the time. The second part expands the analysis to take into account all of the parties for which support data is available. The results from these different analyses are then compared so as to determine whether or not the evidence overall supports each of the hypotheses. Finally, there is a discussion of the implications of these findings. 4.1 Clarity of responsibility: economic voting in different contexts The notion of ‘clarity of responsibility’ was first introduced into the literature by Powell and Whitten (1993). Motivated by the failure of earlier cross-national studies of economic voting to replicate the success of economic voting studies in the United States and the United Kingdom, they argued that these discrepancies could be explained by differences in the political systems of the different countries. In particular, they argue that economic voting depends on the ability of voters to attribute responsibility to the incumbent government: We suggest that the critical linkage of the voter’s assignment of responsibility to the government is not merely an individual-level idiosyncrasy or rationalization. Rather, it will strongly reflect the nature of policymaking in the society and the 4.1. CLARITY OF RESPONSIBILITY: ECONOMIC VOTING IN DIFFERENT CONTEXTS 91 coherence and control the government can exert over that policy. The greater the perceived unified control of policymaking by the incumbent government, the more likely is the citizen to assign responsibility for economic and political outcomes to the incumbents. (398) In other words, economic voting should be expected to occur predominantly in countries where power is visibly concentrated and less in countries where it is diffused among different parties or political actors. Powell and Whitten (1993, 399–402) nominated five features of a political system that were thought to interfere with clarity of responsibility and so reduce the level of economic voting in a country. The first of these was a ‘lack of voting cohesion among the major governing party or parties’, that is, a marked tendency for elected representatives of major parties to vote in accordance with their own views irrespective of their party’s official position. Although it is unusual for political parties to tolerate this, especially in parliamentary systems, four countries were identified as lacking voting cohesion, namely Italy, Japan, the United States and Switzerland. The second feature was a legislative committee system which allocates real power to non-government parties, for example, one that distributes committee chairs to parties proportionally to their representation in the legislature. They found this to be the case in several European countries at the time. The third feature they identified was the presence of an upper house that is both powerful, such as the US and Australian Senates or the German Bundesrat but unlike the British House of Lords, and controlled by opposition parties. The fourth and fifth features identified as reducing clarity of responsibility were the presence of minority government and coalition government respectively. Coalition governments in particular tend to be an enduring characteristic of most European political systems. The presence or absence of each of these features was used to classify countries as low or high clarity and it was then shown that the economic voting effects were stronger in the high clarity group than the low clarity group (405–409). These results were later replicated by Whitten and Palmer (1999) using a broader data set. Unlike the earlier study, they divided countries into three distinct groups, described as ‘most clear’, ‘mixed clarity’ and ‘least clear’ (57). Their results showed that high clarity countries generally experienced a greater economic voting effect than mixed clarity countries, with low clarity countries experiencing very little measurable economic voting (57–63). These findings offered further support for the idea that voters’ tendency to hold governments to account for economic conditions is mediated by their ability to identify an incumbent party as the clearly responsible political actor. 92 CHAPTER 4. CLARITY OF RESPONSIBILITY DURING A GLOBAL RECESSION Although groundbreaking, the Powell–Whitten index has been criticised for some details of its operationalisation. The decision to reduce all of the variation to a simple dichotomy between high and low clarity countries has been seen as limiting as is the fact that the index is almost constant over time (Nadeau, Niemi and Yoshinaka 2002, 404; Royed, Leyden and Borrelli 2000, 677). Scepticism has also been voiced about the idea that such highly technical features of the political system as the allocation of committee chairs could influence voters’ perceptions of responsibility (Royed, Leyden and Borrelli 2000, 678). At least one aggregatelevel study has been unable to find any clarity of responsibility effect at all (Chappell and Veiga 2000). Other explanations have also been suggested for the high variation in levels of economic voting in different times and different countries, such as that the salience of economic issues also varies across time and space (Singer 2011b). Nonetheless, the clarity of responsibility model is the most widely accepted. A number of scholars have since proposed revisions to the Powell–Whitten clarity index in order to incorporate various factors that are conjectured to contribute to or detract from the clarity of responsibility of a polity. Many of these proposals pertain to long-term institutional characteristics. For example, Cutler (2004, 2008), argued that federal structures cloud perceptions of responsibility. He found that, in Canada at least, federalism poses a real obstacle to voters’ ability to hold the appropriate government responsible for policy failures. On the other hand, Arceneaux (2006, 748) found that voters in federal states do hold politicans responsible in the areas where they actually exercise power but only under certain favourable conditions. C. D. Anderson (2006) extends this idea further, finding that multilevel governance in general tends to weaken the economic vote, since voters have to determine which level of government to hold to account. In an extensive comparative study of democratic systems, Hellwig and Samuels (2008) looked more broadly at the effects of different institutional designs on electoral accountability, arguing that certain designs impede voters’ capacity to hold governments to account even when they accurately recognise which political actors are responsible. For example, in parliamentary systems, members of parliament can replace the head of government mid-term, depriving voters of the opportunity to express their dissatisfaction electorally (69–70). Similarly, when legislative and executive elections are held separately in presidential systems, voters are only able to hold to account the particular branch of government that happens to be facing election on that occasion (Hellwig and Samuels 2008, 70; Samuels 2004). Thus parliamentary systems as opposed to presidential systems and concurrent elections within presidential systems are both linked to reduced clarity of responsibility. 4.1. CLARITY OF RESPONSIBILITY: ECONOMIC VOTING IN DIFFERENT CONTEXTS 93 Other proposed revisions to the Powell–Whitten clarity of responsibility index are concerned with characteristics of the incumbent government. For example, it has been suggested that divided government within presidential systems might impede clarity of responsibility, although there is evidence that American voters, at least, respond to this problem by simply holding the president accountable, irrespective of which branch is actually responsible (Norpoth 2001). C. J. Anderson (2000) has argued that both ‘governing party target size’—-the degree to which a single party dominates the incumbent government (154–155)—and ‘clarity of available alternatives’—the ease with which voters can identify a clear alternative government from among the opposition parties (155–156)—ought to mediate the economic vote. Using Eurobarometer data from 1994, he showed that both of these features were related to the level of economic voting measured in a country (160–168). Nadeau, Niemi and Yoshinaka (2002, 404) also proposed a revision to the Powell–Whitten clarity of responsibility index on the grounds that the original index is mainly composed of relatively static items, so it offers little scope to measure any changes over time. They extended the index to include measures of four transient characteristics that are hypothesised to affect clarity of responsibility. The first of these is Anderson’s notion of governing party target size. The second is the ‘ideological cohesion of the governing coalition‘, that is, the proportion of government members of parliament who share the dominant party’s ideology, defined as simply left or right. The third item is the length of time the current government has been in office. The final item is the number of parties holding a minimum threshold (three percent) of seats in the parliament, which is intended to measure Anderson’s clarity of available alternatives (409–411). These various developments in the clarity of responsibility theory were brought together by by Hobolt, Tilley and Banducci (2013), who argued that the concept of clarity of responsibility ought to be seen as a two-dimensional construct, with one dimension measuring institutional clarity and the other government clarity (168). Institutional clarity refers to those aspects of clarity of responsibility resulting from stable institutional arrangements, whereas government clarity refers to the clarity arising from the cohesiveness of the current national government. Items forming part of the institutional clarity dimension include formal divisions of government power such as a bicameral legislature, a federal state, clear separation between the legislative and executive branches and a strong committee system in which opposition parties routinely chair important committees (169). Items forming part of the government clarity dimension are those indicating the cohesion of the incumbent government, such as the number of parties in the cabinet, the ideological cohesion of the cabinet as a whole and the relat- 94 CHAPTER 4. CLARITY OF RESPONSIBILITY DURING A GLOBAL RECESSION ive strength of the head of government’s party in the cabinet (170). Using the 2009 European Election Studies survey, they hypothesised that both clarity dimensions would impact the level of economic voting measurable, with higher clarity countries experiencing a greater level of economic voting. What they found, however, was that only government clarity was a strong predictor of economic voting, with institutional clarity playing little if any role (175–178). They argue that it is not so much the case that institutional clarity is of no importance but rather that institutional clarity is likely to be a key determiner of government clarity, which in turn mediates the economic vote (180). One thing that remains unclear in this body of research is whether the clarity of responsibility mechanisms tend to operate the same way under extreme economic conditions. As with economic voting in general, most of the research that has been conducted has studied behaviour during fairly typical economic conditions. Even when studies have examined the Great Recession specifically, such as Hobolt, Tilley and Banducci (2013), who looked at the European Union in 2009, they have not explicitly contrasted those times with more typical periods. Given that the Great Recession was global in scale, it could be argued that individual governments can hardly be responsible for its occurrence, since that responsibility is presumably shared by the governments of the other affected countries. This is in fact a clarity of responsibility argument and so it is worth exploring whether the clarity of responsibility effect changed during the crisis or remained stable throughout. This chapter does just this, by comparing the impact of clarity of responsibility among EU countries at the height of the Great Recession, in 2009, to that well before the recession, in 2009, and that following the recession in 2014. 4.2 The dimensions of clarity of responsibility The two-dimensional approach to measuring clarity of responsibility developed by Hobolt, Tilley and Banducci (2013) forms the starting point for the measures used in this chapter. Their approach is used because it consolidates the various predictors identified by previous studies and because it groups these predictors into two cohesive dimensions, rather than combining into a single index items related to institutional design with those relating to the incumbent government. Each dimension is measured by an index composed of four variables, which are shown in Table 4.1. The first of their two dimensions, institutional clarity, is made up of three dummy variables and one scale variable. The three dummy variables indicate a 4.2. THE DIMENSIONS OF CLARITY OF RESPONSIBILITY 95 Table 4.1: Components of institutional and government clarity Item Scale Institutional clarity Weak committee system Parliamentary government Unicameral parliament Centralisation of government 1 = weak, 0 = strong 1 = parliamentary, 0 = semi-presidential 1 = unicameral or weak bicameral, 0 = strong bicameral From 0 (highly federal) to 4 (completely unitary) Government clarity Single-party government Absence of cohabitation Ideological cohesion Dominance of main party 1 = one party, 0 = coalition 1 = no cohabitation, 0 = cohabitation Proportion (1 means ideologically unified government) Proportion (1 means all cabinet posts held by same party) These are the component items of the government and institutional clarity of responsibility indices, according to Hobolt, Tilley and Banducci (2013). weak parliamentary committee system, a parliamentary as opposed to semi-presidential system of government and a unicameral or weak bicameral system respectively. The scale variable measures the centralisation of power at the level of central government, ranging from zero for highly federal states to one for completely unitary states. These items are summed and scaled so that the resulting measure ranges in principle from zero to one (174). Since these institutional features are not expected to change over short time periods (169), this chapter uses the institutional clarity index reported by Hobolt, Tilley and Banducci (2013, 181) for each of the countries in this study. The second dimension is government clarity, which they also measure by an index composed of four variables. The first of these is a dummy variable indicating that there is currently a single-party rather than a coalition government. The second is a dummy variable indicating, for semi-presidential systems, that the prime minister and president are of the same party. In other words, this variable indicates the absence of cohabitation. For parliamentary systems, this variable is fixed at one, since there can never be cohabitation. The third variable represents the ‘ideological cohesion’ of the government and this is measured by the proportion of government-held seats belonging to parties sharing an ideology with the head of government’s party. The final component is the ‘dominance of the main governing party’, which is measured by the proportion of cabinet positions held by the head of government’s party. Once again, the final index is scaled so that it ranges in principle from zero to one (174). Since the government clarity of a country can be expected to change frequently, it is not sufficient to use the values of the index reported in the original paper (181) as these values are specific to 2009. Instead, the index has been reconstructed from its components for each year 96 CHAPTER 4. CLARITY OF RESPONSIBILITY DURING A GLOBAL RECESSION and each country under study. In order to determine whether there was a single-party government and to find the dominance of the main governing party, information was needed about the cabinet composition of each country at the appropriate time. This data was collected from the European Journal of Political Research Political Data Yearbook.2 The absence of cohabitation variable only needs to be measured in the few countries using a semi-presidential system. Hobolt, Tilley and Banducci (2013, 184n16) follow Elgie’s definition of a semi-presidential system, which treats as semi-presidential any system in which there exists both a ‘popularly elected fixed-term president [and] a prime minister and cabinet who are responsible to parliament’, irrespective of the division of powers between those institutions (Elgie 1999, 13). Following from this definition, he includes Austria, Finland, France, Ireland, Lithuania, Portugal, Poland and Slovenia3 as examples of semi-presidential systems in Europe (14). This is a rather broad definition and includes countries that others would classify as parliamentary. For example, the description of modern Finland as semi-presidential is disputed,4 and in Ireland, the few constitutional powers reserved to the president are exercised sparingly in practice (Elgie 2012). On the other hand, Hellwig and Samuels (2008, 81) found that ‘the direct election of a president—whether powerful or weak—introduces a special element into electoral politics under semi-presidentialism not present in pure parliamentary systems’ (emphasis in original). This is a strong argument for using the broader definition of semi-presidentialism, so that practice has been continued here. Among all of these semi-presidential countries, the only instances of cohabitation coinciding with the relevant surveys were in Finland and Poland in 2009 and Portugal in both 2004 and 20095 (Döring and Manow 2015). Hobolt, Tilley and Banducci (2013, 174) operationalise ideological cohesion as ‘the proportion of seats held by parties in government that are of the same ideology as the dominant governing party’. In order to measure this, it is necessary to know which parties were in government at the appropriate times and how many seats each of them held in the parliament. This data has been collected from the ParlGov database (Döring and Manow 2015). It is also necessary to assign an ideology to each party. Following the original method, this was done 2 In many cases, this information was gathered from the ‘interactive’ interface to the PDY data (EJPR 2016). At the time of writing, only a subset of the required data has been made available through that interface, so the remaining data was gathered from the detailed annual reports published in the yearbook editions of the journal (EJPR 2003–2015). 3 Of the EU member states, Bulgaria, Croatia and Romania were also included in the list but they do not form part of this study because they acceded to the EU after 2004. Cyprus is the only EU member state with a pure presidential system of government but cohabitation is impossible in a pure presidential system. 4 Nousiainen (2001, 108) writes that, since the constitutional reforms of the 1990s, ‘there are hardly any grounds for the epithet “semi-presidential” ’ with reference to Finland. 5 There were also instances of an independent president in both Lithuania in 2009 and 2014 and Slovenia in 2009. These were not treated as instances of cohabitation, following the example set by Hobolt, Tilley and Banducci (2013). 4.3. HYPOTHESES 97 by dividing parties into ‘left’ and ‘right’ groups, according to their European Parliament party groupings. In particular, parties belonging to the European United Left–Nordic Green Left, the Progressive Alliance of Socialist and Democrats and the Greens–European Free Alliance groupings and are treated as ‘left’ and all other parties are treated as ‘right’ (Hobolt, Tilley and Banducci 2013, 184n18).6 In addition to government and institutional clarity, time in office is also treated in this chapter as a clarity measure. The fact that the EES survey dates coincided with different points in the electoral cycles of the surveyed countries means that some of the governments in power at the time were elected much more recently than others. For example, some ‘incumbent’ governments had only been in power for six weeks at the time the survey took place, whereas others had been in power for several terms. Time in government is only occasionally identified in the literature as an aspect of clarity of responsibility—one example is Nadeau, Niemi and Yoshinaka (2002, 410)—but it is not difficult to imagine that voters who had only recently elected a new government might be less willing to judge that government harshly for poor economic conditions—likely inherited from the previous government—than voters in countries where the same party had been in power for a considerable period of time. There are two types of models used in this chapter and time in government is measured slightly differently according to the type. For those models that analyse exclusively the prime minister’s party in each country, time in government is measured by the number of years that the party has held the office of prime minister. When multiple parties in each country are analysed together, this definition cannot be used because many incumbent parties do not hold the office of prime minister, so time in government is measured by the number of years that each cabinet party has held any cabinet posts at all. In both cases, the number of years is expressed as a fraction, accurate to the number of days in office. 4.3 Hypotheses The purpose of this chapter is to test whether clarity of responsibility effects existed during the period under study and whether the magnitude of this effect changed as a result of the Great Recession. Three potential effects have been derived from the clarity of responsibility 6 This method leads to a handful of surprising codings, particularly as some centrist parties could be plausibly regarded as belonging to either group. Given that some codings are effectively arbitrary, any consistent dichotomous coding will lead to some minor anomalies. An alternative operationalisation was developed, which amounted to the negated standard deviation of the left–right positions of each government member of parliament, where this position is assumed to be the same as that of the party that member belonged to, measured on an eleven-point scale. Although this eliminated the minor anomalies identified, the resulting measure was in fact less predictive than the original, so the analysis reported here uses the original dichotomous measure. 98 CHAPTER 4. CLARITY OF RESPONSIBILITY DURING A GLOBAL RECESSION literature: a time in office effect; a government clarity effect; and an institutional clarity effect. In each case, the chapter will test whether the effect in question exists and, if it does, whether the magnitude of that effect changed over time. To this end, the chapter tests three specific hypotheses. The first of these is: Hypothesis 4.1 Governments that have recently been elected are subject to less economic voting than governments that have been in power for some time. As was stated in the previous section, there is good reason to believe that a government that has been in power for a longer period of time, and therefore had more opportunity to influence the economy, might be more exposed to economic voting than a government that is relatively new to office. The second hypothesis is that there is a traditional clarity of responsibility effect: Hypothesis 4.2 Countries with high clarity of responsibility experience a greater level of economic voting than countries with low clarity. This applies to both government and institutional clarity. Since this chapter measures clarity of responsibility by the two different dimensions of government and institutional clarity, this effectively has two sub-hypotheses, which are tested separately. If this hypothesis is found to hold, then this would naturally be considered evidence in support of the clarity of responsibility theory. If, on the other hand, this hypothesis is rejected, then this would support the idea (van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin 2007, 16) that the instability problem of economic voting theory results from model misspecification, since the method used to measure the economic vote in this thesis is informed by suggestions for a better approach (26–29).7 The final hypothesis concerns clarity of responsibility during the recession period: Hypothesis 4.3 Clarity of responsibility had a smaller influence on the level of economic voting during the Great Recession than it did before or after. There are two reasons to expect that a global recession of such a scale might erode any economic voting differences between high- and low-clarity countries. The first reason is that the recession was presumably a highly salient issue for voters, so that even in low-clarity countries, voters might be more motivated than usual to hold someone accountable, even if it is 7 These ideas have not been adopted in their entirety. See Chapter 2 for a detailed explanation of how economic voting is measured in this thesis and the reasons behind this approach. 4.4. HOW CLARITY AFFECTS THE PRIME MINISTER’S PARTY 99 not necessarily as obvious who ought to be held to account as it is in other countries. The second reason is that the Great Recession was not a mere local recession but an international one that began outside of Europe. This being the case, it is possible that voters in high-clarity countries might find it difficult to hold their own governments to account for a crisis that those governments arguably had very little control over. 4.4 How clarity affects the prime minister’s party The economic voting models developed in the previous chapter have been extended in order to measure how clarity of responsibility impacts the economic vote. This analysis is divided into two parts. The first part focuses on the head of government’s party in each country and specifically those factors affecting the degree to which relative support for that party8 was influenced by economic perceptions. This single-party approach has the advantage of producing relatively simple models which are straightforward to interpret but they do not take advantage of all the data available. The second part of this analysis uses this extra data by looking at all parties together, not just the dominant government parties. The resulting model is inevitably more complex than the single-party model but it offers a different view of the evidence. Taken together, these two approaches allow for greater insight than either approach used alone. The first clarity of responsibility model, Model 4A, is based on Model 3A from the previous chapter, which predicts support for the head of government’s party in each country based primarily on the left–right distance between the voter and the party, whether that voter identifies with the party and, crucially, the voter’s prospective economic assessment. The effect of this economic assessment on support for the prime minister’s party is a measure of the overall level of economic voting. In order to test the hypothesis that clarity of responsibility influences the economic vote, therefore, this model must be extended to include an interaction between the economic assessment predictor and the chosen measure of clarity of responsibility. This allows the model to estimate different levels of economic voting for different levels of clarity. As the underlying model is a multilevel model, the fact that clarity of responsibility is a countrylevel variable is accounted for. The new model includes predictor terms for both institutional 8 As in the previous chapter, the dependent variable is a voter’s level of support for a particular party, centred around that voter’s mean level of support for all parties. This means that even the models that focus on prime ministers’ parties only still take some account of voter attitudes towards other parties, which is appropriate because a voter is not expected to switch their vote unless their support for a new party exceeds their support for the party they previously supported. 100 CHAPTER 4. CLARITY OF RESPONSIBILITY DURING A GLOBAL RECESSION Table 4.2: Alternative government clarity models Fixed effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Prospective assessment Time in office (PM) Government clarity Single-party government Absence of cohabitation Ideological cohesion Dominance of main party Institutional clarity Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × time in office Prosp. assess. × govt clarity Prosp. assess. × single party Prosp. assess. × no cohabitation Prosp. assess. × cohesion Prosp. assess. × dominance Prosp. assess. × inst. clarity Mod. 4A Mod. 4B Mod. 4C 0.54 (0.24) 0.33 (0.17) 0.04 (0.13) 0.13 (0.09) 0.02 (0.02) −0.89 (0.29) 1.91 (0.41) 0.31 (0.17) −0.06 (0.14) −0.13 (0.14) 0.01 (0.02) 1.40 (0.32) 0.34 (0.18) −0.06 (0.14) −0.11 (0.10) 0.01 (0.01) 0.05 (0.26) −0.08 (0.03) −0.07 (0.03) 0.01 (0.00) 0.19 (0.09) 0.14 (0.12) 0.21 (0.19) −0.27 (0.21) −1.58 (0.32) −0.14 (0.34) −0.15 (0.26) −0.07 (0.03) −0.04 (0.03) 0.01 (0.00) −0.05 (0.06) −0.03 (0.07) 0.39 (0.09) 0.04 (0.11) 0.19 (0.12) −1.39 (0.30) −0.08 (0.24) −0.07 (0.03) −0.03 (0.03) 0.01 (0.00) 0.38 (0.08) 0.15 (0.11) Comparison of clarity of responsibility models. The dependent variable is the individual’s support for the current head of government’s party. Only the key fixed effect coefficients are shown here, with standard errors in brackets. The full results can be found in Appendix B. Source: EES, ParlGov & PDY and government responsibility, as well as time in office.9 These three variables account for the different types of clarity discussed in this chapter. The model furthermore includes interactions between each of these and the voter’s prospective economic assessment. This model has been estimated and the key results are summarised in the first column of Table 4.2. Before interpreting any figures in detail, it is worth discussing some alternative model specifications. The government clarity index consists of four component variables, as discussed earlier. Model 4B replaces the index with its four components so that their relative impact can be assessed.10 The key results from this model form the second column of Table 4.2. Comparing the two models, it is striking that the interaction between economic assessment and ideological cohesion in the second model appears to be stronger than that between economic 9 This is specifically the number of years this party has held the office of prime minister, even if they held other cabinet posts before that. 10 Multicollinearity might be a concern, as the components of an index can be expected to be correlated with each other. In fact, the components are not so strongly correlated as to cause serious difficulties. The highest correlation is between dominance of the main governing party and single-party government variables (r = 0.70) but these variables are dependent since single-party government prevails if and only if the prime minister’s party completely dominates the government. The second highest correlation is between dominance and ideological cohesion (r = 0.31). 4.4. HOW CLARITY AFFECTS THE PRIME MINISTER’S PARTY 101 assessment and the government clarity index. Although it is not straightforward to compare model coefficients directly, given the similar scale of the two variables, this difference is suggestive. It is also surprising that the interactions involving the other three component variables are not even close to significance. This evidence is hardly conclusive but it does suggest that ideological cohesion alone may be a better predictor of economic voting than the complete index. In order to test this hypothesis, Model 4C was estimated, in which ideological cohesion alone replaces government clarity. The key results from this model make up the third column of Table 4.2. Comparing this to the other models shows that this model fits the data better (∆AIC = 26, ∆BIC = 27) than the government clarity model (Model 4A) and that the components model (Model 4B) does not improve the model fit enough to justify the extra complexity relative to this model (∆AIC = 7, ∆BIC = 61). These results support the hypothesis that ideological cohesion alone is a better predictor of economic voting levels than the complete index. Consequently, Model 4C forms the basis of this analysis. As in the previous chapter, post-estimation simulation is used to derive key quantities of interest rather than interpreting model coefficients directly. This chapter’s first hypothesis is that governments that have been power for some time experience greater levels of economic voting than governments which have been recently elected. The level of economic voting predicted from the model can be measured by the difference in support for the prime minister’s party between a highly optimistic individual and an otherwise similar11 highly pessimistic individual. Using this definition, the predicted level of economic voting for a government that has just been elected is 1.23 (SE = 0.16, p < 0.001). A party that has been in power for a full decade, on the other hand, has a predicted economic vote of 1.50 (SE = 0.18, p < 0.001). This amounts to a difference of 0.26 points (SE = 0.15, p = 0.07), which is not statistically significant. In other words, it is possible that a longer time in office is associated with a higher level of economic voting but the effect is weak if it exists at all. The second hypothesis is that clarity of responsibility increases the level of economic voting. This has two sub-hypotheses, relating to government and institutional clarity respectively. Since government clarity is measured in this model by ideological cohesion alone, the 11 Unless otherwise stated, all predictions in this chapter are made for a context in which ideological cohesion, institutional clarity and time in office are held at their means. This is 0.86 for cohesion and 0.61 for institutional clarity. The mean time in office is 4.03 years where this refers to the time the party has held the office of prime minister, as in this case, or 4.92 years where this refers to the time the party has been part of the governing coalition, which becomes relevant later in the chapter. As in the previous chapter, the individual is an employed 40 year old male, living in a town, who has completed high school but not university. 102 CHAPTER 4. CLARITY OF RESPONSIBILITY DURING A GLOBAL RECESSION first sub-hypothesis is tested by comparing high-cohesion to low-cohesion contexts.12 The predicted economic vote for a low-cohesion country is 0.79 (SE = 0.21, p < 0.001) whereas the predicted economic vote for a high-cohesion country is 1.54 (SE = 0.15, p < 0.001). This corresponds to a difference of 0.75 points (SE = 0.16, p < 0.001) between high- and lowcohesion countries. In other words, the economic vote is almost twice (1.94, [1.39, 3.54]13 ) as high when the ideological cohesion of the government is high than when it is low. The second sub-hypothesis pertains to institutional clarity. The predicted economic vote in highclarity countries14 is 1.08 (SE = 0.24, p < 0.001) and the predicted economic vote in lowclarity countries is 1.58 (SE = 0.23, p < 0.001). The difference of 0.50 points (SE = 0.38, p = 0.19) is not significant. Based on this model then, it appears that government clarity, and in particular ideological cohesion, is the strongest predictor of economic voting in a country. The third hypothesis is that these clarity of responsibility effects were weaker during the recession than at other times. As the models introduced so far assume that these effects are static over time, a new model is needed to test this hypothesis. Model 4D was created by extending Model 4C with interactions between the time dummy variables and the clarity of responsibility and time in government measures, thus allowing each of these effects to vary in strength over time. This model was used to predict the level of economic voting under different clarity contexts in each year. Figure 4.1 compares the predicted economic vote for a government that has just been elected with that of a government that has held office for a full decade. This plot shows that countries whose governments have held power for some time experienced a greater level of economic voting than countries who have experienced a recent change in government. This effect changes over time, appearing to vanish in 2009 and return much stronger in 2014. These impressions are mostly borne out by a numerical analysis except that the effect falls just short of significance (∆ = 0.77, SE = 0.40, p = 0.06) in 2004. The effect is clearly not significant (∆ = 0.12, SE = 0.19, p = 0.52) in 2009, and the difference between the two years is also not significant (∆ = 0.64, SE = 0.42, p = 0.13). By 2014, on the other hand, the decade in office accounts for a 1.98 point (SE = 0.43, p < 0.001) increase in the economic vote and this effect is significantly stronger than both earlier years (compared to 2004, ∆ = 1.22, SE = 0.58, p = 0.04). In other words, time in office was only a strong 12 High cohesion means a cohesion measure of 1, indicating no differences in ideology among government parties. Low cohesion means a cohesion measure of 0.5, indicating that half of the government-held seats are held by parties not sharing an ideology with the prime minister’s party. This value has been chosen because lower values are unlikely, since the prime minister’s party is typically to be the largest governing party. It is also the lowest value occurring in the dataset but it is by no means an outlier. 13 Square brackets indicate 95% confidence intervals. 14 High clarity means an institutional clarity measure of 1 and low clarity a measure of 0.18, these being the highest and lowest scores assigned to any country by Hobolt, Tilley and Banducci (2013). 4.4. HOW CLARITY AFFECTS THE PRIME MINISTER’S PARTY 103 Figure 4.1: Economic vote for dominant government party by time in office 2.5 economic vote 2.0 time in office 10 years 1.5 just elected 1.0 0.5 2004 2009 2014 year Predicted level of economic voting for the head of government’s party according to the time that the party has held office and the survey year. The economic vote is the difference in support for the party from a highly optimistic and a highly pessimistic voter based on predictions from Model 4D. Ideological cohesion and institutional clarity are held at their means. Source: EES, ParlGov & PDY predictor of economic voting in 2014. The fact that this effect was so weak in earlier years may explain why no effect was found when it was assumed not to vary over time. Figure 4.2 shows the predicted level of economic voting for a high-cohesion and a lowcohesion context in each year. A high-cohesion context is a country in which all of the governing parties are ideologically similar and a low-cohesion context is one in which half of the government-held parliamentary seats belong to parties not sharing the ideology of the prime minister’s party. This shows a similar pattern to the previous figure, in that there is an apparent difference between the two groups in 2004, which closes in 2009 before widening again in 2014. These observations are supported by numerical analysis, which shows that in 2004, the economic vote experienced in a high-cohesion context was 1.65 points (SE = 0.41, p < 0.001) higher than in a low-cohesion context. By 2009, this difference had fallen (∆ = 1.37, SE = 0.47, p < 0.01) to 0.29 points (SE = 0.27, p = 0.28) and by 2014 had risen once again (∆ = 0.68, SE = 0.33, p = 0.04) to 0.97 points (SE = 0.24, p < 0.001). In other words, high ideological cohesion was associated with more economic voting before 104 CHAPTER 4. CLARITY OF RESPONSIBILITY DURING A GLOBAL RECESSION Figure 4.2: Economic vote for dominant government party by ideological cohesion economic vote 1.5 1.0 cohesion high low 0.5 0.0 2004 2009 2014 year Predicted level of economic voting according to the ideological cohesion of the incumbent government and the survey year. The economic vote is the difference in support for the prime minister’s party from a highly optimistic and a highly pessimistic voter based on predictions from Model 4D. Institutional clarity and time in office are held at their means. Source: EES, ParlGov & PDY and after but not during the Great Recession. This supports the third hypothesis with respect to government cohesion. Similarly, Figure 4.3 shows the relationship between institutional clarity and economic voting by comparing the difference between high and low scores on the institutional clarity index. This figure shows little if any difference between high- and low-clarity contexts in 2004 and 2009 but a large difference in 2014. Numerical analysis confirms that there was no significant effect in either 2004 (∆ = −0.19, SE = 0.51, p = 0.71) or 2009 (∆ = 0.43, SE = 0.53, p = 0.42), nor is there a significant difference between these two years (∆ = 0.62, SE = 0.47, p = 0.18). In 2014 on the other hand, the economic vote was considerably stronger among high-clarity countries than low-clarity countries (∆ = 1.67, SE = 0.50, p < 0.001), which is a significant increase over both other years (compared to 2009, ∆ = 1.24, SE = 0.47, p < 0.01). This means that high institutional clarity was not a predictor of economic voting either before or during the Great Recession but it did become one in the aftermath of the recession. This evidence provides only qualified support for the third hypothesis with respect 4.5. THE EFFECT OF CLARITY ON OTHER PARTIES 105 Figure 4.3: Economic vote for dominant government party by institutional clarity economic vote 2.0 1.5 clarity high low 1.0 0.5 2004 2009 2014 year Predicted level of economic voting according to the institutional clarity of the country and the survey year. The economic vote is the difference in support for the prime minister’s party from a highly optimistic and a highly pessimistic voter based on predictions from Model 4D. Ideological cohesion and time in government are held at their means. Source: EES, ParlGov & PDY to institutional clarity, since it was predicted that the importance of institutional clarity would be weaker during the recession than either before or afterwards. 4.5 The effect of clarity on other parties The models discussed so far have focused on support for the current prime minister’s party. This approach has the advantage of simplicity but it also has the disadvantage that it disregards respondents’ levels of support for coalition partners and opposition parties, so it does not use all of the data available. This means that while it is possible to determine the degree to which prime ministers’ parties are supported relative to other parties in general15 it is not possible to compare them to opposition parties specifically or to examine support for government parties more generally using this approach. A further model (Model 4E) has been constructed using the available data for every party so that the contrasting effects of economic voting between 15 Since the dependent variable, party support, is centred around its individual-level mean, these models are measuring support relative to the other key parties in each country rather than absolute support. This centring has both theoretical and data-driven motivations, which are discussed in detail in Chapter 2. 106 CHAPTER 4. CLARITY OF RESPONSIBILITY DURING A GLOBAL RECESSION government and opposition parties in general can be examined in different clarity contexts. This model is based on Model 3D, which predicts party support based on, among other things, the individual’s prospective economic perceptions and whether the party is a government or opposition party. This was extended to take into account clarity of responsibility by allowing the key economic voting terms to interact with the clarity of responsibility predictors. In the base model, economic voting is measured by a three-way interaction between economic assessment, incumbency and time. This means that the model allows government and nongovernment parties to be affected differently by an individual’s economic assessment, which is the key claim of economic voting theory, and further allows the strength of this economic vote to change over time. Clarity of responsibility theory further asserts that the level of economic voting varies according to country-level clarity variables and if these effects are to be allowed to vary over time, this necessitates a four-way interaction.16 This is admittedly a high level of complexity but it reflects the complexity of the hypotheses.17 Without these interaction terms, it would not be possible to determine whether clarity of responsibility had a stable effect on economic voting propensity over time. Once again, post-estimation simulation has been used to interpret this model. The method used to ascertain the effect of the clarity of responsible variables on economic voting is to compare the level of economic voting under different clarity scenarios in each year. In this instance, the level of economic voting is defined in terms of relative government support. Relative government support is the difference between the individual’s support for a government party and that same individual’s support for an opposition party. This is positive if that individual generally prefers government parties and negative if that individual generally prefers opposition parties. The economic voting level is the difference between the relative government support of a highly optimistic individual and that of a highly pessimistic individual. The higher the economic voting level, the more influence economic conditions have on the decision as to whether to support the government or the opposition. If this is zero then the economy plays no role at all. A negative economic voting level would be surprising as this would indicate that governments are harmed electorally by good economic conditions. This model has been used to test the chapter’s hypotheses once again, as the different approaches offer different perspectives. The first hypothesis is that the economic vote is greater 16 Ideological cohesion and institutional clarity are both allowed to interact with the three-way economic voting interaction. Time in government is only meaningful for parties that are actually in government, so this variable only interacts with time and economic assessment. As always, the coefficient estimates are shown in Appendix B. 17 Van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin (2007, 210–212), who use the same dependent variable, also use four-way interactions in some of their economic voting models. Although their method of measuring the economic vote is quite different, this illustrates that this level of complexity inevitably arises when studying the economic vote through the lens of party support. 4.5. THE EFFECT OF CLARITY ON OTHER PARTIES 107 Figure 4.4: Government and opposition economic vote by time in office economic vote 1.2 time in office just elected 10 years 1.0 0.8 2004 2009 2014 year Predicted level of economic voting in each survey year for a party that has been in government for ten years compared to a party that has just been elected to government. The economic vote is the difference in relative support for the party compared to an opposition party between a highly optimistic and a highly pessimistic voter based on predictions from Model 4E. Ideological cohesion and institutional clarity are held at their means. Source: EES, ParlGov & PDY in countries where the government has been in power for a longer period of time. Figure 4.4 compares the predicted economic vote of a government that has been in power for ten years to one that has only just been elected. This figure shows that there is an economic voting effect favouring both short-term and long-term governments in all years. Surprisingly, governments that have only been in power for a short period appear to have been subject to slightly stronger economic voting than those that have been in power for a longer time in both 2004 and 2009. Neither of these differences is significant, however, the larger of the two being the 0.15 point (SE = 0.16, p = 0.35) difference in 2009. None of the three groups saw a significant difference in the economic vote between 2004 and 2009. By 2014, long-term governments were exposed to a greater level of economic voting than short-term governments (∆ = 0.35, SE = 0.18, p = 0.04). The increase in the economic vote experienced by long-term governments from 2009 to 2014 was 0.58 points (SE = 0.25, p = 0.02). None of the other differences over time were significant. Based on these results, it appears that time in office only played an important role in 2014. One possible explanation for this is that those parties who held power continuously since the Great Recession were seen differently by voters from parties that had 108 CHAPTER 4. CLARITY OF RESPONSIBILITY DURING A GLOBAL RECESSION Figure 4.5: Government and opposition economic vote by ideological cohesion economic vote 1.5 1.0 cohesion high low 0.5 0.0 2004 2009 2014 year Predicted level of economic voting according to the ideological cohesion of the incumbent government and the survey year. The economic vote is the difference in relative support for a governing party compared to an opposition party between a highly optimistic and a highly pessimistic voter based on predictions from Model 4E. Institutional clarity and time in government are held at their means. Source: EES, ParlGov & PDY been elected since that time. This would make sense as it means that parties who could be seen as responsible for the recession experienced a stronger economic vote. Figure 4.5 contrasts the predicted economic vote of highly ideologically cohesive governments with that of less cohesive governments. It can be seen that the economic vote experienced by highly cohesive governments was stronger than that experienced by less cohesive governments. This difference amounts to 2.07 points (SE = 0.59, p < 0.001) in 2004, before falling by 1.86 points (SE = 0.69, p < 0.01) before 2009, when the difference between the two groups almost vanishes (∆ = 0.21, SE = 0.37, p = 0.57). The difference between 2009 and 2014 is not significant (∆ = 0.74, SE = 0.50, p = 0.14) but the size of the gap between the two groups in 2014 is 0.95 points (SE = 0.33, p < 0.01). An anomaly arising from this analysis is that the predicted economic vote for low cohesion governments in 2004 is actually negative (∆ = −0.36, SE = 0.54, p = 0.50) but this is not statistically significant. In summary, it appears that the ideological cohesion of the government does mediate its exposure to the economic vote but it also appears that this effect was weakened by the Great Recession. These 4.5. THE EFFECT OF CLARITY ON OTHER PARTIES 109 Figure 4.6: Government and opposition economic vote by institutional clarity 1.8 economic vote 1.5 clarity 1.2 high low 0.9 0.6 2004 2009 2014 year Predicted level of economic voting according to the institutional clarity of the country and the survey year. The economic vote is the difference in relative support for a governing party compared to an opposition party between a highly optimistic and a highly pessimistic voter based on predictions from Model 4E. Ideological cohesion and time in government are held at their means. Source: EES, ParlGov & PDY findings support both the government clarity hypothesis and the hypothesis that this clarity effect was weaker during the recession than at other times. Similarly, Figure 4.6 compares the predicted economic vote of governments in countries with high institutional clarity to that of governments in low-clarity countries. Unfortunately, owing to the uncertainty in the model estimates, there is little that can be confidently said about the effect of institutional clarity. The only year in which there is a statistically significant difference between the groups is in 2004, when low clarity countries experienced a 1.18 point (SE = 0.53, p = 0.03) stronger economic voting effect than high clarity countries. This runs opposite to the hypothesised effect, which was that high clarity countries should have a stronger economic vote. The point estimate of the effect was in the opposite direction in both 2009 (∆ = 0.43, SE = 0.48, p = 0.37) and 2014 (∆ = 0.61, SE = 0.49, p = 0.21) but neither of these estimates is significant. There was significant difference in effect size between 2004 and 2009 (∆ = 1.60, SE = 0.72, p = 0.03) but not between 2009 and 2014 (∆ = 1.78, SE = 0.69, p = 0.80). Given that the clarity effect is either not significant or significant but opposite to the expected sign, the conclusion has to be drawn that this model does not support 110 CHAPTER 4. CLARITY OF RESPONSIBILITY DURING A GLOBAL RECESSION the institutional clarity hypothesis. Although there appear to be some significant time effects, in the absence of clear support for the basic hypothesis, it would be unwise to attempt to find support for the hypothesis that the effect varies overs time. In summary, institutional clarity does not appear to be a reliable predictor of economic voting, at least according to this model. 4.6 Conclusion This chapter has examined the impact of clarity of responsibility as a mediator of the economic vote before, during and after the Great Recession. Clarity of responsibility was divided into three facets, each representing a distinct quality of a political context expected to affect the ease with which voters can hold the incumbent government responsible for the prevailing economic conditions. These facets were government clarity, institutional clarity and time in government. Government clarity refers to those characteristics of the incumbent government, such as consisting of a coalition of parties, that might make it difficult for voters to identify a party to hold to account. Institutional clarity refers to institutional characteristics having the same effect, such as the presence of a strong upper house or a federal system of government. These concepts were measured using the indices proposed by Hobolt, Tilley and Banducci (2013), except that it was found that the government clarity index was outperformed by one of its component measures, the ideological cohesion of the government, which was therefore used in its place as the measure of government clarity. Finally, time in government refers to the amount of time that a party has held office, since a party that has only recently been elected could plausibly claim not to have had an opportunity to influence the condition of the economy. Three hypotheses were tested in this chapter, the first of these being that a longer period of time in government was associated with a stronger economic vote. This hypothesis was not supported by the data. When the effect was modelled as constant over time, there was no significant difference between parties that had been in power for a short period and those that had been in power longer. When the size of the effect was allowed to vary over time, a significant effect was only found in 2014. This was the case whether all parties were analysed together or the analysis was restricted to prime ministers’ parties, even though time in office was operationalised differently by the two approaches. This is certainly not strong enough evidence to claim that time in government is a mediator of the economic vote but it is interesting that there does appear to be some effect shortly after the Great Recession, since this 4.6. CONCLUSION 111 effectively means that time in government does matter when that time implies that the government held office during the recession. In other words, this suggests that voters were more closely monitoring the economic performance of governments that survived the recession. The second hypothesis is that greater clarity of responsibility is associated with a higher level of economic voting. There are two sub-hypotheses, in that this is expected to apply both to government clarity and institutional clarity. As mentioned earlier, government clarity is measured in this chapter by the ideological cohesion of the incumbent government. In each of the models, a positive relationship was found between government clarity and the level of economic voting. The same cannot be said for institutional clarity. No significant institutional clarity effect was found when the effect was assumed to be constant over time. Even when the effect was assumed to vary with time, no significant effect was found apart from in 2014 when considering only prime ministers’ parties. Even worse, when examining all parties together, the effect was found to be in the opposite direction to that hypothesised in 2004 and otherwise not significant. In other words, the data offers strong support for the hypothesis with respect to government clarity but little if any support with respect to institutional clarity. This mirrors the findings of Hobolt, Tilley and Banducci (2013, 177), who first made this distinction explicit and who also found that government clarity outperforms institutional clarity as a predictor of economic voting levels. The fact that some clarity effects were found using a contextual model of economic voting shows that existing clarity of responsibility findings cannot be completely explained away as an artefact of model misspecification. On the other hand, the lack of support for any clarity effect other than ideological cohesion supports the argument that model misspecification plays at least some role in the instability of economic voting results (van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin 2007, 16). The final hypothesis is that clarity of responsibility was a weaker predictor of the economic vote during the recession that it was at other times. With respect to government clarity, this hypothesis has strong support. Whether all parties were analysed together or the analysis focused solely on the parties of the heads of government, the findings were the same. The level of economic voting was considerably higher in high cohesion countries than in low cohesion countries in both 2004 and 2014. In 2009, during the recession, this effect was not nearly as strong and, in fact, was not significantly different from zero, although the point estimates were still positive. In other words, the recession temporarily eroded the distinction between high- and low-clarity countries. In principle this hypothesis also applies to institutional clarity 112 CHAPTER 4. CLARITY OF RESPONSIBILITY DURING A GLOBAL RECESSION but since institutional clarity was not shown to a predictor of the economic vote at all, this sub-hypothesis is not meaningful. In summary, it was found that there was a clarity of responsibility effect, in that voters in countries with highly ideologically cohesive governments were more likely to vote economically than those in countries with ideologically fragmented governments. It was further found that the level of economic voting was greater before and after the Great Recession than it was during its peak. Considered in conjunction with the finding from the previous chapter that the overall level of economic voting was reduced during the same period, this suggests that the event itself had the effect of clouding economic responsibility. This makes sense as the recession was international in scale and had begun in the United States before spreading to Europe, so governments could plausibly deny responsibility for it. By 2014, however, governments had had plenty of time to react to the crisis and economic voting levels as well as the mediating effect of government clarity had returned to their pre-crisis levels. Any governments that had held power continuously since the crisis were held responsible to an even higher degree than before for the condition of the economy. This chapter and the preceding chapter have looked at the circumstances under which poor economic conditions voters are likely to cause voters to abandon their support for their incumbent governments. This raises the question of which party or parties are likely to benefit from this shift in allegiances. The next chapter seeks to answer this question by examining whether some types of parties are more likely to receive the support of economic voters than others. Chapter 5 Extreme and Eurosceptic parties: the changing policy preferences of European voters In the Greek parliamentary elections of 25 January 2015, Syriza won 149 of the 300 seats in the Hellenic Parliament. This allowed the radical left party to seize power from the grand coalition that had governed Greece since 2012 (Matakos and Xefteris 2016). The coalition parties, which included the centre-right New Democracy, the centre-left PASOK and at various times other parties, had desired to maintain Greece’s membership of the Eurozone, which meant imposing the austerity measures demanded by their creditors (Rori 2016). Syriza, on the other hand, stood on an anti-austerity platform.1 Much has been written about the situation in Greece but it raises interesting questions about how voters respond to economic crises. Why did Greek voters turn to Syriza specifically? Was it because they were leftist, or because they were Eurosceptic, or simply because they promised to end austerity? Was this event part of a greater Europe-wide trend? This chapter explores these questions by examining which types of parties have benefited from the events of the Great Recession and which have not. It will be seen that there are many different ways that parties have been classified but for the purposes of this chapter they will be primarily classified according to their positions on economic issues, social issues and European integration. Previous chapters have shown that incumbent parties lost support from voters with a pessimistic economic outlook during the recession, although not by as much as at other times. The purpose of this chapter is to establish which parties gained support as a result. The focus is not on individual parties so much as types of parties. Syriza, for example, is a radical left party (Stavrakakis and Katsambekis 2014), so it could be argued that Greek voters shifted to the left. On the other hand, it could also be argued that they voted for Syriza not because 1 Despite this platform, the Syriza-led coalition government ultimately negotiated a new bailout programme as well as further austerity. They were nonetheless re-elected at the snap September election in the same year (Matakos and Xefteris 2016; Rori 2016). 113 114 CHAPTER 5. EXTREME AND EUROSCEPTIC PARTIES it is specifically left-wing but because it advocated a radical rejection of the status quo. In other words, a right-wing party that promised to abandon austerity might have been equally successful. Syriza has also been described as a ‘soft Eurosceptic’ party (Verney 2015, 280), although their leader Alexis Tsipras is reported to have rejected all forms of Euroscepticism (To Vima 2014). These are the three categories of parties that might be expected to benefit from the crisis: parties on one side of the spectrum, parties far from the centre, and Eurosceptic parties. This chapter begins by discussing the specific hypotheses that will be tested. After that, there is an explanation of how parties’ positions have been measured. Spatial position in particular is measured in two different ways, both as a single-dimensional left–right spectrum and as a two-dimensional space. The remaining sections discuss how parties’ positions towards European integration and their spatial positions, in both one and two dimensions, affected support for those parties before, during and after the crisis. This is done by extending the multilevel model of party support introduced in Chapter 3 so as to control for the economic voting effect that has already been observed. The results show that the parties who benefited most from the recession are Eurosceptic parties and those holding more extreme2 economic positions and conservative social positions. Since most of these changes took place well after the recession, it is argued that the political response to the recession, rather than the recession itself, has been the main driver of these changes. 5.1 Hypotheses The purpose of this chapter is to determine which types of parties benefited from the Great Recession. The previous chapter showed that there was an economic voting effect, that is, voters who held a pessimistic economic assessment preferred opposition parties over government parties. Not all opposition parties are equal, however. This chapter tests several hypotheses about which groups of parties were most likely to receive new support from voters as a result of the Great Recession. As in previous chapters, the primary sources of data are the 2004, 2009 and 2014 waves of the EES voter surveys. The first of these waves was collected well before for the beginning of the crisis, the second set of surveys was collected at a time when most of the EU countries were in recession as a result of the crisis and the third wave was collected well after the initial crisis but at a time when many countries were suffering from 2 The term ‘extreme’ in this chapter is used to mean positions that are relatively far from the political centre of the relevant country, irrespective of whether they lie to the left or the right. 5.1. HYPOTHESES 115 double-dip recessions or grappling with controversy resulting from severe austerity measures. It is therefore expected that the voter response to the recession would have first arisen in 2009 and perhaps receded somewhat by 2014 and this is the time frame used in each of the following hypotheses. One possibility is that there was a voter backlash against those parties that were seen as supportive of the institutions of the European Union. Given the international scale of the recession, domestic politicians may have been able to attribute some of the blame for the recession to the EU (Hobolt and Tilley 2014), particularly since EU institutions do control important aspects of European economic policy, notably including monetary policy for countries using the shared currency. Furthermore, the EU was also seen to play a role in the often unpopular austerity measures that were imposed in many countries as a result of the crisis. This being the case, it would not be surprising if parties advocating more national autonomy gained some support at the expense of those parties advocating further integration within the EU. This question has been addressed by Hobolt and Leblond (2014), who found that support for remaining in the Eurozone has remained consistently high throughout the crisis and its aftermath, even in countries with severe economic problems or stringent austerity measures. They argue that this is because citizens estimate the risks associated with leaving to be greater than those of staying. As theirs was an aggregate study, it will be interesting to see whether their results can be replicated with an individual-level model. The first hypothesis is thus: Hypothesis 5.1 The Great Recession provoked a shift in support away from parties supporting further European integration and towards those opposing it. Differing convictions about how best to manage the economy are one of the fundamental divisions underlying the political spectrum. This being the case, it is not difficult to imagine that a severe economic shock could shake voters’ confidence in some of these positions and lead them to prefer parties with somewhat different approaches. This naturally raises the question of whether voters should be expected to move to the left or the right following an event like the Great Recession. The popular expectation seems to be that voters should move towards the left. For example, commenting on the results of the 2009 European Parliament elections, one commentator described the left as having ‘failed to capitalise on an economic crisis tailor-made for critics of the free market’ (The Economist 2009). This analysis is typical of the newspaper commentary of those election results, with the left seen as the natural beneficiaries of the Great Recession, but somehow failing to take advantage of their position (Lindvall 2012, 514). 116 CHAPTER 5. EXTREME AND EUROSCEPTIC PARTIES Within the academic literature, on the other hand, the tendency is to find that poor economic conditions are typically followed by a rightwards shift. For example, Durr (1993) attempted to explain why the policy preferences of US voters were further to the left in some periods, such as the 1960s, than in other periods, such as the 1980s. He proposed that there was a link between support for redistributionary policies and economic conditions, namely that voters were more in favour of these policies when they felt economically secure but saw them as a form of discretionary spending to be reigned in when they felt the economy itself was threatened. This has been described as a ‘luxury model’ (Anderson and Hecht 2014, 57). It was found that support for leftist policies was indeed highest when optimism about the economy was high and low when attitudes were more pessimistic (Durr 1993, 167). These results were later replicated in a comparative study of fourteen European countries (Stevenson 2001). An alternative to the luxury model is the idea that the different kinds of economic troubles are associated with different policy preferences and there is some support for this idea too. Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson (2002) studied aggregate trends in US politics in diverse specifics between 1952 and 1996. One of their findings was that ‘policy mood’, a composite measure of survey responses to specific policy questions, tends to the left when unemployment is high and to the right when inflation is high (232–235). There have been some observations of a rightwards shift during the Great Recession but these are hardly decisive. Soroka and Wlezien (2014), for example, found that there has been a long-term drop in support for redistribution among British Labour supporters in particular and that the Great Recession has not arrested the long term trend. Bartels (2014) found that there did appear to be a general move towards the right following the Great Recession but also that the effect size is much smaller when controlling for economic conditions—the countries with left-wing incumbents were often those where the recession was worst (199). They conclude that ‘the Great Recession produced surprisingly little overall change in the ideological proclivities of voters—and that retrospective voting was a stronger and more consistent factor than ideology in accounting for observed shifts in electoral behavior in OECD countries’ (200). Lindvall (2014) argues that the change in preference over time is more complex than a simple leftwards or rightwards trajectory. By comparing the patterns of electoral results in the aftermath of the Great Recession and the Great Depression, he found that in both cases voters tended to move towards the right in the short term and back towards the centre or even the left as the crisis continued, even when controlling for economic voting. He proposes that this 5.1. HYPOTHESES 117 could be explained as a result of the different social classes becoming exposed to the severity of an economic downturn at different times (Lindvall 2013, 149). These studies inform the second hypothesis: Hypothesis 5.2 The Great Recession led to increased support for the parties of the right relative to those of the left, particularly in the short term. Alternatively, it may be the case that rather than turning to the parties of the left or the right specifically, voters have turned away from the mainstream parties and towards extreme or fringe parties. The argument behind this idea is that the mainstream parties suffered a loss of credibility by failing to prevent the Great Recession from taking place. Since this event had deep structural causes, even those mainstream parties that were in opposition at the time could have been tainted by the crisis. In any event, the parties in power across Europe were not uniformly of the left or the right, so neither the centre-left nor the centre-right could plausibly claim to be blameless so long as any blame could be attributed to national governments. This being the case, it might be expected that voters would turn to those parties who are critical of the established political order or who seek to advance radical or anti-system policy platforms. Aggregate cross-national election result data has already shown some evidence of an increase in support for the populist parties of the radical left and radical right, especially in Western Europe (Hernández and Kriesi 2015). This forms the basis of the third hypothesis: Hypothesis 5.3 The Great Recession led to a shift in support from centrist parties to more extreme parties. There have already been studies on whether the recession has helped more extreme parties but no consensus has been reached. For example, Allen (2015) studied support for extreme right parties, defined as those occupying the right–authoritarian corner of the political space, also using the 2004, 2009 and 2014 waves of EES survey data. He found some support for his hypothesis that economic grievances were associated with greater support for far right parties in the period after the crisis. Similarly, Mayer (2014) looked at whether the French working class moved to the far right as a result of the Great Recession. It was found that although the far-right National Front has increased its support, particularly among the working class, a former stronghold of communist support, the magnitude of this increase was actually quite small (288–290). Grittersova et al. (2015), on the other hand, argued that austerity actually suppresses support for extreme parties. Using election-year panel data from sixteen countries 118 CHAPTER 5. EXTREME AND EUROSCEPTIC PARTIES between 1978 and 2009, they found that austerity policies are associated with reduced support for both radical left and radical right parties. Importantly, their data does not extend to the period of austerity following the Great Recession, although the authors argue that there is no obvious cause to believe that this would change their results (21). Given this diversity in results, the hypothesis is worth testing here. Lastly, it should not be assumed that all voters would respond to the recession in the same way. One obvious question is whether poor and rich voters responded similarly. Duch and Sagarzazu (2014, 225) use panel data to examine voter behaviour from the 2009 German and 2010 British parliamentary elections. They measured the economic vote and economic preferences of different groups of voters, finding that both rich and poor voters had similar levels of economic voting but that the poor continued to prefer greater levels of redistribution than the rich (253). This still leaves open the possibility of an individual’s economic assessment influencing their policy preferences. It is also well known that voters are influenced by economic conditions when deciding whether to vote for the incumbent government and it was shown in Chapter 3 that this economic voting effect can be observed in the party support levels of survey respondents before, during and after the recession. In particular, it was found that a voter’s prospective economic assessment influenced that voter’s support for incumbent parties. Similarly, if any of the predicted trends are observed then it is also expected that these effects would be influenced by the voter’s economic assessment. For example, if support for extreme parties did increase as a result of the recession, it is expected that the size of this increase would be greatest among those voters who were pessimistic about the future of their national economy and least among those who were optimistic. The final hypothesis for this chapter is thus: Hypothesis 5.4 These effects are strongest among voters believing that the economy was worsening and weakest among those believing it was improving. 5.2 Classifying parties In order to test these hypotheses, the various parties need to be classified by some means. There is a large literature on the classification of political parties, beginning with Duverger (1959, 61–132), who drew a distinction between ‘mass’ and ‘cadre’ parties. This distinction pertains to the basic structure of the party. Cadre parties are elite organisations, loose associations of like-minded politicians, with no true membership beyond their candidates and 5.2. CLASSIFYING PARTIES 119 office holders. Mass parties, on the other hand, have a large membership drawn from the general population, who are committed to the party’s ideological project, pay dues to the party and exercise some influence over the party’s elites. The cadre party model is the traditional model of conservative parties, whereas the mass party model originated with European socialist parties and has been successful enough that some conservative parties have tried to emulate it. Kirchheimer (1966) later introduced the notion of the ‘catch-all party’, observing that large mass parties have a tendency to start trying to appeal to people outside of their traditional support bases in order to improve their electoral performance. Building upon both earlier works, Panebianco (1988, 262–274) argued that the key distinction among modern parties is now between ‘mass bureaucratic’ and ‘electoral–professional’ parties. Mass bureaucratic parties are still heavily membership-driven, depending upon financial dues and motivated by ideology, whereas electoral–professional parties have only weak ties between their elites and their membership, are often financed externally and seek primarily to appeal to the electorate. Katz and Mair (1995, 2009) take this further, arguing that the major parties have evolved into ‘cartel’ parties, which are effectively part of the state itself. On the other hand, they note that these parties face new opposition from emerging radical parties who challenge their close relationship with the state (Katz and Mair 1995, 24). These ideas are helpful for understanding the evolution of the party system but it is not clear that these terms are particularly useful for classifying individual parties (Koole 1996). Moreover, these approaches focus on party structure, whereas this thesis is concerned with individual behaviour. It may well be the case that party structure can explain why some parties are more able than others to capitalise on the crisis but the question motivating this chapter is which parties voters have turned to in response to the crisis. Given that party structure is not highly visible to most voters, this is unlikely to be a motivating factor for them. As a result, this chapter will instead focus on parties’ spatial location, which is also more congruent with the hypotheses introduced in the previous section. There is evidence that voters do understand the terms ‘left’ and ‘right’ and can accurately locate a party on the left–right spectrum (Busch 2016). It is thus reasonable to hypothesise that voters might treat parties differently according to their left–right location when responding to the crisis. There is also evidence that party positions tend to remain stable over time (Dalton and McAllister 2015), and that this continued to be the case during the Great Recession (Dalton 2016). This thesis focuses on those parties for which the EES surveys include party support questions. The set of these parties differs somewhat from wave to wave, as the researchers have 120 CHAPTER 5. EXTREME AND EUROSCEPTIC PARTIES tried to include whichever parties were deemed to be most important at the time. The number of parties in a particular wave varies from 147 to 195. In total, there are 274 unique parties included for the relevant countries. In order to test this chapter’s hypotheses, it was necessary to determine whether each of these parties was a left-wing or right-wing party, whether it was an extreme or moderate party and whether it was a pro- or anti-European integration party. Leftist parties are reasonably straightforward to identify, since the EES surveys ask respondents where they would place each party on the left–right political spectrum. Other datasets also include left–right placement data, such as the Manifesto Project, the Comparative Study of Electoral Systems and the Chapel Hill Expert Survey. Those parties which are generally agreed to be on the left by survey respondents or with leftist manifestos could be considered leftist parties. Another possibility is to use a qualitative descriptor of the party’s family, information which is also included in the CHES dataset. Parties which are classified as socialist or communist parties would then be considered leftist parties. It is less straightforward to identify extreme parties, as there are different kinds of parties that could be described as extreme. For example, extreme parties might be identified with anti-system parties, which oppose the existing political order. This can be problematic when it comes to regionalist parties who seek greater autonomy or even independence for a particular region. These parties are common in Europe and are sometimes seen as outsider parties and, as such, even subject to the cordon sanitaire, whereby mainstream parties informally agree to minimise cooperation with them or exclude them from any coalition (McDonnell and Newell 2011, 444). On the other hand, within the affected regions, these parties often occupy a mainstream position, making it inappropriate to categorise then as extreme. For example, the Scottish National Party has become the dominant party in Scotland, managing to win majority government in 2011 in a proportionally elected parliament (Johns, Mitchell and Carman 2013).3 The party does however argue for Scottish independence from the United Kingdom, a position that could well be seen as extreme in other parts of the UK, yet the party is clearly mainstream within Scotland. This illustrates the difficulty of classifying parties as centrist or extreme by using qualitative family descriptors. Another way to identify extreme parties could be to consider one of the same measures of left–right position discussed above. Those parties which are held to be far to the left or far to the right could be classified as extreme and the others as moderate. This too is not without problems, as there are some parties where EES respondents do not agree on a position. The 3 They have since lost that majority at the 2016 Scottish Parliament election but they remain the dominant party, having won 63 seats, more than twice the 31 seats won by the next biggest party (BBC News 2016b). 5.2. CLASSIFYING PARTIES 121 British National Party (BNP), for example, has been described as an extreme right party (Ford and Goodwin 2010, 1), owing principally to its positions on race and immigration (5). The respondents in the EES survey do not uniformly agree with this classification, however. In 2009, the only wave in which respondents were asked about the BNP, 30.4 percent of respondents assigned them a left–right position of ten, indicating a far-right position but 21.6 percent assigned a position of zero, indicating a far-left position. Some 16.3 percent of respondents assigned no position and none of the remaining possibilities attracted more than 5.5 percent of the response. Although the party’s positions on certain issues is right-wing, they also work hard to win support from traditional Labour voters (5). This could be behind the pattern of responses here, with some voters indicating that they would consider the party to be on the left and that they find it to be extreme, even though the party is certainly not a communist party, the usual meaning of far left. The problem of inconsistent party placement is likely to affect all populist parties, whose positions on various issues are not necessarily motivated by a coherent, or at least conventional, ideology. One way of addressing this issue could be to measure the mean distance from the centre reported by respondents, rather than aggregating the reported positions and then measuring the distance from the centre. This means that a voter reporting that a party is far left and one reporting that it is far right are considered to be in agreement that the party is extreme. This is an improvement but it still leads to some surprising classifications, such as the centre-right New Democracy party in Greece being classified as extreme—presumably as a reaction to the austerity measures they introduced when they were in government. An alternative to using the EES measures of left–right position is to use expert surveys of party positions. The CHES dataset includes a similar measure of general left–right position as well as separate measures of position on the left–right economic and authoritarian–libertarian scales. Parties could be classified as extreme according to their positions on any of these scales. Being an expert survey, the CHES dataset has highly reliable measures of party position and so does not suffer the same problems described above. In any event, Dalton, Farrell and McAllister (2011, 121) have shown that expert surveys, citizen surveys and manifesto assessments of party position display a ‘striking consistency’. Finally, parties need to be classified according to their position regarding European integration. The EES surveys include a question asking voters to assign parties a score from zero to ten, where zero means unification ‘has already gone too far’ and ten means it ‘should be pushed further’. This measure would be ideal except for the fact that there were problems 122 CHAPTER 5. EXTREME AND EUROSCEPTIC PARTIES with this particular variable in the 2014 wave of the survey, and as a result, this measure is simply unavailable in that wave at the time of writing of this thesis. Most of the parties asked about in the 2014 wave were also asked about in either or both of the earlier waves, and the data from those first two waves shows that party positions tended not to change by very much if anything between 2004 and 2009. By assuming that this was also true between 2009 and 2014, the missing data could be imputed for about three quarters of the parties in the 2014 wave, although this solution is not highly satisfactory, as some of the party position data is ten years out of date at that point. The CHES dataset also includes a question asking experts to assign parties a score indicating the party’s orientation towards European integration, as well as a question asking the relative salience of that position in the party’s public image. This is useful because it makes it possible to distinguish between parties that are overtly Europhile or Eurosceptic and those parties who may hold similar positions but are less strongly associated with them in the public mind. Unlike the leftism and extremism measures, there is no appropriate family classification that could be used for this, as even parties defined by their Euroscepticism are coded into other families. For example, the United Kingdom Independence Party is coded as belonging to the conservative family. The method this chapter uses to classify parties is to use the party position measures from the CHES dataset. The CHES project surveys experts regarding the parties in their countries. Each party is positioned on a variety of scales, such as left to right, authoritarian to libertarian and pro- to anti-integration.4 The experts use their own professional judgement to assign these positions rather than specified policy items but the mean scores assigned by each expert are a reliable measure of a party’s position. This approach has several benefits. There are a number of relevant scales, so party positions on a particular issue can be identified more precisely than with the other approaches. Because these are scales, rather than nominal measures, this method also makes it possible to compare party positions, unlike the party family approach. Finally, the CHES surveys include the relevant questions in each of its waves, unlike the EES data, which lacks a key question in the 2014 wave.5 It must be noted that the CHES data is not a perfect fit either. There have been five waves of the survey so far, taking place in 1999, 2002, 2006, 2010 and 2014, which do not correspond precisely with the three relevant EES survey waves, which took place in 2004, 2009 and 2014. 4 Most of these items are measured on an eleven-point scale ranging from 0 to 10. The support for further integration item is measured on a five-point scale, which has been recoded to range from −3 to +3 for this analysis. 5 Although the party unification position questions were intended to be included in the 2014 wave, this has not been released owing to ‘an error in the questionnaire development’ (Popa et al. 2015, 5). The project intends to address this omission with a follow-up survey but at the time of writing this data is not available. 5.2. CLASSIFYING PARTIES 123 Table 5.1: Variation in party position over time Fixed effect Left–right position Coeff. SE p Intercept Year 2006 Year 2010 Year 2014 5.206 0.028 0.030 0.094 (0.149) (0.055) (0.066) (0.073) Var. SD Var. SD 4.580 0.143 0.410 0.542 (2.140) (0.378) (0.640) (0.736) 2.643 0.208 0.421 0.514 (1.626) (0.457) (0.649) (0.717) Party random effect Intercept Year 2006 Year 2010 Year 2014 < 0.001 0.612 0.649 0.200 Integration position Coeff. SE p 0.996 −0.109 −0.071 −0.094 (0.115) (0.051) (0.061) (0.067) < 0.001 0.034 0.249 0.162 Multilevel model predicting expert assessment of party position for each year that the CHES survey was conducted. Sample size is 7661 responses for left–right position and 7878 responses for European integration position for 226 parties in both cases. Pseudo R2 is 0.785 for left–right position and 0.772 for integration position. Source: CHES A model was constructed to estimate the amount of variation in two of the key measures among the parties included in the CHES data. Table 5.1 summarises the results. The low magnitude of the fixed effects indicates no evidence for a shift affecting all parties, which is to be expected. The random effects are more interesting, as these show the degree to which individual parties changed position over time. The variance of the intercepts associated with the year increases over time, which is consistent with a random walk. The magnitude of these variances is also quite low, suggesting that parties do tend to change position over time but somewhat slowly. Since party positions appear to change slowly over time, the misalignment between the EES and CHES survey waves should not pose exceptional difficulties. This misalignment has been addressed by interpolating the party position at the required time.6 Luxembourg, Cyprus and Malta were not included in the CHES dataset so these countries were excluded from this chapter. The resulting data set includes 251 unique parties, or 464 total parties,7 within 22 countries. Using another dataset to measure objective party position represents a change from the practice used in Chapter 3, where each individual’s subjective measures were preferred. Apart from the issues discussed above, there is a further reason for this difference. In that chapter, it was argued that an individual’s support for a particular party ought to decrease as the distance 6 Not every party for which party support data exists in the EES surveys has corresponding data in the CHES surveys. This affects approximately one quarter of the EES parties, but these are mostly parties of little practical importance, such as parties that only existed for a short time or which had a very low vote share. These parties have been excluded from analysis in this chapter. 7 As in previous chapters, parties in different years are treated as different entities because some countries have highly fluid party systems. 124 CHAPTER 5. EXTREME AND EUROSCEPTIC PARTIES Figure 5.1: Relationship between party support and position European integration left–right mean party preference 3 2 1 0 -1 -2 -3 -2 0 2 0 party position 2 4 6 8 10 Scatter plots showing the relationship between the mean relative support for a party and that party’s position on European integration, from −3 (anti-integration) to +3 (pro-integration), as well as its position on the left–right spectrum, from 0 (left) to 10 (right). The best linear fit is shown for the European integration plot. The left–right plot shows a relationship that is clearly non-linear, so it is shown with the best quadratic fit. Both curves are shown with their 95% confidence intervals. Source: EES & CHES increases between the party’s position and their own on the left–right scale, which was found to be the case. In this spatial model of party support, it makes sense to use that individual’s subjective measure of the party’s position, since the measure of their own party position is necessarily subjective and this means the two positions can be meaningfully compared. Although the spatial model remains the underlying model of party support used in this chapter, and the subjective party distance variable is therefore still included, the focus here is on the parties themselves. This is why, when classifying the parties, the individual’s perception of the party is less important than its objective position. 5.3 How party position relates to voter support Before building an individual-level model, it is necessary to examine the relationship between aggregate party support and the new party position variables introduced in this chapter. The 5.3. HOW PARTY POSITION RELATES TO VOTER SUPPORT 125 mean relative party support8 was estimated for each party in the study, and this functions as a measure of that party’s support relative to the other parties in the same country. For this purpose, the data from all three survey years is combined but each party is treated as a separate entity in all three years since the party position variables are time-dependent as well. Figure 5.1 shows the relationship between mean party support and the party’s position on European integration, in the first panel, and its left–right position, in the second panel. The former ranges from −3 for strongly anti-integration parties, often referred to as ‘Eurosceptic’ parties, to +3 for strongly pro-integration, or ‘Europhile’, parties and the latter ranges from 0 for far-left parties to 10 for far-right parties. The scatter plot in Figure 5.1 shows that pro-integration parties are more popular than anti-integration parties and this relationship is approximately linear, as can be seen from the linear fit line also shown. Similarly, centrist parties are more popular than far left and far right parties. Curiously the parties that are in the very centre of the spectrum appear to be rather less popular than those on the centre-left and the centre-right. This plot is shown with a quadratic fit line, which is a good fit but does not account for the depressed support among centrist parties. The quadratic fit is preferred to one attempting to account for this anomaly for two reasons. First, there is a risk of overfitting the data. The quadratic fit is already a good fit and the residuals from this model are not significantly different from a normal distribution. Second, it has been shown in previous chapters that incumbent parties are more popular than opposition parties and these parties tend to occupy the centre-left and centre-right. When controlling for incumbency, the centrist parties are no longer outliers. It is also clear from these plots that party position on either of these scales only explains a small proportion of the variance in mean party support. The regression R2 is 0.18 for the party’s integration position and 0.14 for its left–right position. Although these are small numbers, it would be surprising if party position alone explained a large proportion of the variance in party support. It is remarkable that even eighteen percent of this variance can be explained by a party’s position on European integration alone, although it must be stressed that this proportion is likely to be less when controlling for other variables. This is particularly likely for the incumbency variable, as governing parties are generally more pro-integration than opposition parties. The mean position on European integration among the cabinet parties in the dataset is 1.85 [1.69, 2.02], and that for opposition parties is 0.46 [0.26, 0.67]. 8 Party support is a measure of how likely an individual is to support a particular party on an eleven-point scale. Relative party support is party support centred around each individual’s mean support level for the parties in their country. These measures are explained in detail in Chapter 2. Mean relative party support is thus an aggregate measure of a party’s support compared to other parties in the same country. 126 CHAPTER 5. EXTREME AND EUROSCEPTIC PARTIES Figure 5.2: Relationship between integration position and salience 1.0 salience 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 -3 -2 -1 0 position 1 2 3 Scatter plot showing the relationship between a party’s position on European integration, from −3 (anti-integration) to +3 (pro-integration), and the salience of the integration issue in that party’s public image, from 0 (low) to 1 (high). This is shown along with the best quadratic fit, which is clearly a better fit than a linear one. The shaded area represents the 95% confidence interval around the curve. Source: CHES The plots for the other party position variables are not shown here because they are similar to these. The social and economic dimensions follow similar distributions to the left–right spectrum. The integration salience measure is almost unrelated to party support, although parties with high salience are slightly more popular, even when controlling for the party’s position on that issue. It might be expected that salience would affect support differently for parties with different positions on integration but surprisingly the interaction between integration position and salience is not significant. There is no significant quadratic interaction either. This is likely because these two variables are actually related. As Figure 5.2 shows, salience is higher for parties that are more strongly pro- or anti-integration than it is for parties with more moderate positions. This makes sense because it is difficult to see how a party could make a moderate position on this issue an important part of its public image. Although the correlation is not high (R2 = 0.23), this may explain why the expected interactions are not observable. Because of this, the rest of the analysis will ignore the salience variable, focusing on integration position only. 5.4. THE CHANGING FORTUNES OF PRO-EUROPEAN INTEGRATION PARTIES 127 Table 5.2: Regression model predicting general left–right position Predictor Intercept Economic position Social position Coeff. −0.197 0.683 0.412 SE (0.117) (0.021) (0.019) p 0.094 < 0.001 < 0.001 This model predicts a party’s general left–right position from its position on the economic and social dimensions. Sample size is 434 parties. Adjusted R2 is 0.847. Source: CHES The relationship between the three left–right position variables was also explored. These variables are the party’s positions on the general left–right spectrum as well as an economic spectrum and a social spectrum. These latter variables allow parties to be positioned in a two-dimensional political space, rather than along a single line, according to the theory that positions on economic and social issues are often orthogonal (for example, see Lester 1994; Swedlow 2008). The correlation between social and economic position is r = 0.38, which suggests that these positions are not quite orthogonal but it is low enough that it may be worth examining the two dimensions separately. It should be expected that a party’s general left–right position can be predicted from its positions on the social and economic dimensions and this is in fact the case. As Table 5.2 shows, position on the social and economic dimensions explains 85 percent of the variation in general left–right position. It is interesting to note that economic position contributes more strongly to a party’s general position than social position does. This model shows that the economic and social position scores are a meaningful decomposition of a party’s left–right position, so party support models will be constructed using both the general left–right positions and the two-dimensional positions. 5.4 The changing fortunes of pro-European integration parties The first hypothesis is that support for pro-integration parties fell after the Great Recession. In order to test this, Model 5A was constructed. It is based on Model 3D, which measures the economic vote using a three-way distinction between prime ministers’ parties, other cabinet parties and opposition parties. That model was extended by including as a predictor the variable measuring each party’s position on European integration. As with the other terms in the model, this predictor has been centred around the grand mean. In the original model, economic voting is measured by the interaction between an individual’s prospective economic assessment and a party’s incumbency status. This is because economic voting theory posits 128 CHAPTER 5. EXTREME AND EUROSCEPTIC PARTIES that economic conditions affect government and opposition party support differently. A further term measuring the three-way interaction between economic assessment, incumbency and the survey year made it possible to discern how the strength of the economic voting effect has changed over time. The new model includes a similar interaction between economic assessment and party position on European integration, so that it can be tested whether support for pro-integration parties is higher among optimistic or pessimistic voters. In other words, this inclusion makes it possible to determine whether economic voting affected not just incumbent parties but also pro-integration parties. Furthermore, a three-way integration term between economic assessment, European integration position and survey year has been included so as to be able to determine whether these effects changed over time.9 The incumbency terms mentioned are still included so as to control for the standard economic voting effect, which has already been shown to have existed. In addition to the random effects terms included in the original model, corresponding random effects terms were considered for each of the new fixed effects. Since the European integration position variable was measured at the party level, it would only be meaningful to include these random effects at the country level. It was previously shown that the countrylevel variance in this data is almost zero, which is why the basic model does not include a random intercept for the country level, so it is not surprising that the variance of all of these random effects terms was also very small and in most cases their inclusion did not improve the model fit significantly. A random effect for the integration position variable alone was included because, although the measured variance was very low, it was large enough to improve the model fit significantly and does not hinder convergence. As in previous chapters, post-estimation simulation has been used to derive key predictions along with the corresponding uncertainty estimates from the model coefficients and it is these that will form the basis of the following discussion. The table of coefficients can be found in Appendix B. Figure 5.3 shows how support changed over time for parties with different positions towards European integration. The points plotted correspond to the predicted support of an individual with a neutral prospective economic assessment towards each type of party in each survey year. According to this plot, neutral voters were more likely to support pro-integration parties than anti-integration parties across all three years, although the 9 Although not always mentioned explicitly, the models discussed in this chapter also include the additional terms implied by any interactions mentioned. For example, where a three-way interaction is mentioned, all of the pairwise two-way interactions as well as the single factor terms are also included. 5.4. THE CHANGING FORTUNES OF PRO-EUROPEAN INTEGRATION PARTIES 129 Figure 5.3: Party support by position on European integration predicted preference 4.4 4.2 party position pro-integration 4.0 neutral anti-integration 3.8 3.6 3.4 2004 2009 year 2014 Predicted support in each survey year of a voter holding a neutral prospective economic assessment for a strongly pro-integration party, a neutral party and a strongly anti-integration party. These correspond to measured European integration positions of +3, 0 and −3 respectively. The modelled relationship between a party’s integration position and a voter’s support for that party in a particular year is linear, so the predictions for moderate parties lie between those shown here. Source: EES, ParlGov & CHES magnitude of this difference decreased dramatically over time. In 2004, a neutral voter has a predicted support of 4.54 points (SE = 0.10, p < 0.001) for a pro-integration party, 3.99 points (SE = 0.07, p < 0.001) for a neutral party and 3.44 points (SE = 0.14, p < 0.001) for an anti-integration party. This means that, compared to an anti-integration position, a pro-integration position was associated with an extra 1.10 points (SE = 0.20, p < 0.001) of support. In 2009, this difference had declined to 0.76 points (SE = 0.20, p < 0.001) and by 2014, the difference was no longer statistically significant (0.15 points, SE = 0.19, p = 0.41). This suggests that voters were quite supportive of a pro-European integration position before the beginning of the crisis, slightly less supportive after the crisis had begun and indifferent to such a position after the end of the crisis. So far, this analysis has only discussed voters with a neutral assessment of the course of their country’s economy. Figure 5.4 compares the predicted difference in support for prointegration and anti-integration parties for optimistic, neutral and pessimistic voters. A positive value in a given year, indicates that such a voter is expected to prefer a pro-integration 130 CHAPTER 5. EXTREME AND EUROSCEPTIC PARTIES Figure 5.4: Relative support for pro-integration parties predicted difference 1.0 group 0.5 optimistic neutral pessimistic 0.0 -0.5 2004 2009 year 2014 Difference in predicted support for a strongly pro-integration and anti-integration party in each year among voters holding different prospective economic assessments. This difference represents the relative support for a pro-integration party (measured position of +3) over an anti-integration party (−3). The economic assessments shown are those for highly optimistic voters (measured assessment of +2), neutral voters (0) and highly pessimistic voters (−2). Source: EES, ParlGov & CHES party and a negative value indicates that the voter would prefer an anti-integration party. In 2004, pro-integration parties were preferred by all three voter groups. The pessimistic group had a relative support towards these parties of +0.89 points (SE = 0.24, p < 0.001) and the optimistic group had a relative support of +1.31 points (SE = 0.20, p < 0.001). The difference between the groups was not significant however (0.42 points, SE = 0.28, p = 0.14). By 2009, it appears that this relative support had fallen in each group by an approximately equal amount but this change is not significant either (0.34 points for the neutral group, SE = 0.26, p = 0.18). By 2014, the three groups had become less similar to each either. Optimistic voters still had a strong relative support towards pro-integration parties, of +0.89 points (SE = 0.23, p < 0.001). This is a mere 0.04 points (SE = 0.31, p = 0.87) less than in 2009. Neutral voters had become almost indifferent to a party’s European integration position, with a relative support of +0.15 points (SE = 0.19, p = 0.41), a 0.60 point (SE = 0.23, p = 0.01) fall from 2009. Pessimistic voters in 2014 were the only group to prefer anti-integration parties, with a 5.5. LEFT–RIGHT POSITION: A SHIFT TO THE EXTREMES 131 relative support of −0.59 points (SE = 0.23, p < 0.001). This is a huge 1.16 point (SE = 0.30, p < 0.001) fall from 2009. In short, parties arguing for closer European integration were at an advantage in 2004, before the beginning of the recession and this was probably independent of a voter’s economic assessment. In 2009, during the recession, this was still the case, except that the size of that advantage had declined slightly. By 2014, well after the recession, voters with different economic assessments had started to behave differently in this respect. Optimistic voters continued to prefer the pro-integration parties but pessimistic voters now preferred those parties arguing for weaker European integration, with voters of a neutral assessment having no clear preference. This seems to be evidence in support of the hypothesis that the recession provoked a shift away from pro-integration parties. It is worth noting, however, that the bulk of the shift and the stratification according to economic assessment did not take place until well after the recession. 5.5 Left–right position: a shift to the extremes At the beginning of this chapter, it was hypothesised that voters shifted their support away from leftist parties and towards those on the right during the recession. This is not necessarily expected to be a long-term shift, as earlier work has found that such shifts tend to be shortlived (Lindvall 2014). It was also hypothesised that it was extreme parties that benefited from the recession. These hypotheses can be tested by modelling the impact of a party’s left–right position on voter support for that party. Model 5B is based on, once again, Model 3D, which has this time been extended to measure the impact of a party’s general left–right position on party support. It was shown earlier in this chapter that the relationship between mean support for a party and that party’s left–right position is approximately quadratic, with voters generally preferring centrist parties over extreme parties. The new model therefore represents this relationship quadratically. Both the linear and quadratic terms are interacted with economic assessment and time, allowing this relationship to be compared between the different groups of voters in each year, as with previous models. No further random effects terms have been included in this model because the variance of these terms is extremely low. This model was estimated and used to predict the support in each year of optimistic, pessimistic and neutral voters for various party left–right positions. These predictions are summarised visually by Figure 5.5. This figure shows that, in 2004, all groups of voters generally preferred centrist parties over extremist parties, leading to an inverted U-shaped curve for 132 CHAPTER 5. EXTREME AND EUROSCEPTIC PARTIES Figure 5.5: Party support by general left–right position 2004 2009 2014 5 optimistic 4 2 5 neutral predicted preference 3 4 3 2 5 pessimistic 4 3 2 0 2 4 6 8 10 0 2 4 6 8 10 0 party position 2 4 6 8 10 Predicted party support by party’s general left–right position in each year among voters holding different prospective economic assessments. These are shown along with their 95% predictive intervals. Party position ranges from 0 (far left) to 10 (far right). The economic assessments shown are those for highly optimistic voters (measured assessment of +2), neutral voters (0) and highly pessimistic voters (−2). Source: EES, ParlGov & CHES each. It can also be seen that optimistic voters leant slightly to the right and pessimistic voters leant slightly to the left, with neutral voters leaning in neither direction. This is an interesting pattern, because it suggests that before the recession, voters had a small tendency to support the right when they believed that the economy was likely to do well and the left when they believed otherwise. By 2009, this pattern had changed, with all three groups preferring the centre. This suggests that, rather than enhancing the tendency for optimists to support the right and pessimists the left, the recession in fact suppressed it. The year 2014 is particularly interesting because it shows a rather different pattern altogether. Optimists in 2014 still preferred centrist parties overall but the flatter shape of the curve indicates an increased openness to more extreme parties. The curve for neutral voters appears completely flat, suggesting that this group of voters was indifferent between extreme and centrist parties. Finally, pessimistic 5.5. LEFT–RIGHT POSITION: A SHIFT TO THE EXTREMES 133 Table 5.3: Left–right and extreme tendency by year and voter group Group Year Left–right tendency Extreme tendency Optimistic 2004 2009 2014 +1.45 [+0.08, +2.82] −0.54 [−1.72, +0.65] −0.08 [−1.29, +1.13] −0.102 [−0.149, −0.055] −0.079 [−0.120, −0.037] −0.036 [−0.078, +0.006] Neutral 2004 2009 2014 −0.23 [−1.29, +0.84] −0.60 [−1.53, +0.34] −0.30 [−1.24, +0.65] −0.076 [−0.113, −0.039] −0.069 [−0.101, −0.036] +0.003 [−0.030, +0.035] Pessimistic 2004 2009 2014 −1.90 [−3.22, −0.59] −0.65 [−1.82, +0.51] −0.52 [−1.70, +0.67] −0.050 [−0.095, −0.005] −0.059 [−0.098, −0.019] +0.041 [+0.001, +0.081] Left–right tendency is the difference between a group’s cumulative predicted support for rightwing and left-wing positions, positive for a right-wing tendency and negative for a left-wing tendency. Extreme tendency is the curvature of the quadratic function describing the relationship between party position and predicted support for that party. A positive curvature indicates a preference for more extreme parties and a negative curvature a preference against extreme parties. These figures are shown with their 95% predictive intervals. The three groups correspond to highly optimistic voters (measured assessment of +2), neutral voters (0) and highly pessimistic voters (−2). Source: EES, ParlGov & CHES voters in 2014 appear to be more supportive of extreme parties than centrist parties, with a U-shaped curve that is no longer inverted. In order to determine whether these apparent differences are statistically significant, it is helpful to find a relevant quantity that can be measured. In order to determine whether a particular group had an overall left-wing or right-wing tendency, the total area under the left half of the curve was compared to that under the right half.10 This difference is positive in the case of a right-wing tendency and negative in the case of a left-wing tendency. Similarly, support for extreme parties over centrist parties can be described by the curvature of the function.11 A positive curvature indicates that support increases towards the extremes and a negative curvature indicates that support decreases towards the extremes. A curvature of zero implies that the curve is in fact a line. This curvature will be referred to as the extreme tendency. The left–right and extreme tendencies for optimistic, pessimistic and neutral voters in each year are given in Table 5.3 along with their predictive intervals. These figures confirm the 10 A more precise description of this quantity follows: the party support curve for a particular year and group can be described by a quadratic expression of the form y = ax 2 + bx + c, where x represents the party’s left–right Rb position and y support for that party. Let the function C(a, b) = a ax 2 + bx + c d x be the cumulative support between a and b. Then ∆ = C(5, 10) − C(0, 5) = (875a/3 + 75b/2 + 5c) − (125a/3 + 25b/2 + 5c) = 250a + 25b describes the difference in support between all right-wing and all left-wing parties. This quantity was computed along with its predictive interval to produce the figures described here. 11 The curvature of a function is described by its second derivative. In this case, d 2 y/d x 2 = 2a. Once again, this was computed with its predictive interval to produce the figures given here. 134 CHAPTER 5. EXTREME AND EUROSCEPTIC PARTIES visual findings described above. In 2004, optimistic voters had a rightward tendency and pessimistic voters a leftward tendency. Neutral voters in 2004 and all voters in the other years had no significant left–right tendency. In 2004 and 2009, all groups of voters had support functions with negative curvature, that is, they tended to prefer parties with more centrist positions than parties at the extremes. By 2014, this was no longer the case. Pessimistic voters had a positive support curvature, meaning that extreme parties were supported more strongly than centrist parties. Neutral and optimistic voters had support curvatures not significantly from zero and the point estimate for neutral voters was very close to zero. The point estimate for optimistic voters was somewhat less than zero, hence the visibly curved shape in Figure 5.5, but a flat line or a curve in the other direction are both plausible. On this evidence, it is likely that both groups of voters were almost indifferent to a party’s left–right position in that year. 5.6 Beyond left and right: social and economic dimensions Political position is sometimes modelled in two dimensions rather than the traditional continuum. These dimensions are usually a left–right economic dimension and a libertarian– authoritarian social dimension. The argument for this more complex approach is that the two dimensions are in practice orthogonal, so it is not unusual to find that parties that are, for example, right-wing on economic issues still have a diversity of positions on social issues. This being the case, the hypothesis that voters moved to leftist parties as a result of the recession could be more accurately tested using a two-dimensional model, since movement along each dimension can be analysed separately. In two-dimensional terms, this hypothesis posits that voters would have moved left along the economic dimension, with no motion along the social dimension. The alternative hypothesis that voters were inclined to move to the extremes also applies particularly to the economic dimension. There is no expectation of movement along the social dimension. This is because in a harsh economic environment voters may be more open to more radical economic policies but there is no obvious reason why this should lead to a change in their other views. The one-dimensional model discussed in the previous section has been modified to produce a two-dimensional model, designated Model 5C. As discussed earlier in the chapter, party position has been measured along both the economic and social dimensions, as well as a general left–right dimension. The general dimension used in the previous model has been substituted with the economic and social dimensions, each of which is modelled quadratically like the original. The two dimensions are not modelled as interacting because it as assumed 5.6. BEYOND LEFT AND RIGHT: SOCIAL AND ECONOMIC DIMENSIONS 135 Figure 5.6: Party support by economic left–right position 2009 2014 optimistic 5.5 5.0 4.5 4.0 3.5 3.0 2.5 neutral predicted preference 2004 5.5 5.0 4.5 4.0 3.5 3.0 2.5 pessimistic 5.5 5.0 4.5 4.0 3.5 3.0 2.5 0 2 4 6 8 10 0 2 4 6 8 10 0 party position 2 4 6 8 10 Predicted party support by party’s economic left–right position in each year among voters holding different prospective economic assessments. These are shown along with their 95% predictive intervals. Party position ranges from 0 (far left) to 10 (far right). The economic assessments shown are those for highly optimistic voters (measured assessment of +2), neutral voters (0) and highly pessimistic voters (−2). Source: EES, ParlGov & CHES that motion along one dimension is completely independent of motion along the other. As before, no further random effects terms have been included owing to the very low variance of those terms. Figure 5.6 shows predicted support according to year and economic assessment towards a party at different positions along the economic dimension. In making these predictions, the party’s social position has been held to be in the centre. This only affects the vertical offset of the curve, not its shape, as the model does not allow the two dimensions to interact. Once again, it appears that optimistic voters in 2004 had a tendency to prefer right-wing parties and pessimistic voters left-wing voters, although these tendencies appear stronger than in the unidimensional model. Neutral voters still appear to prefer the centre. Similarly, the magnitude of these tendencies has declined by 2009 but unlike the unidimensional model, the optimistic and pessimistic voters still have a visibly right-wing and left-wing tendency 136 CHAPTER 5. EXTREME AND EUROSCEPTIC PARTIES Table 5.4: Directional and extreme tendency along economic dimension Group Year Directional tendency Extreme tendency Optimistic 2004 2009 2014 +3.09 [+1.50, +4.68] +1.06 [−0.40, +2.52] +0.72 [−0.64, +2.08] −0.042 [−0.093, +0.009] −0.057 [−0.102, −0.013] −0.015 [−0.058, +0.027] Neutral 2004 2009 2014 +0.07 [−1.19, +1.32] −0.52 [−1.69, +0.64] −0.54 [−1.59, +0.52] −0.048 [−0.089, −0.007] −0.064 [−0.099, −0.028] +0.005 [−0.029, +0.038] Pessimistic 2004 2009 2014 −2.96 [−4.47, −1.44] −2.10 [−3.50, −0.70] −1.80 [−3.10, −0.50] −0.054 [−0.103, −0.005] −0.070 [−0.112, −0.027] +0.025 [−0.015, +0.065] Similar to Table 5.3, except that the dimension analysed is the economic left–right spectrum rather than the general left–right spectrum. A positive directional tendency here indicates a preference for the economic right and negative a preference for the economic left. Source: EES, ParlGov & CHES respectively. Each group in both years prefers parties near the vertex over parties further away but given the extreme location of the vertices for optimistic and pessimistic voters in 2004, this may not be a particularly useful measure for those groups. In 2014, the directional tendency of each groups appears to be maintained, with optimistic voters preferring right-wing position and pessimistic voters left-wing positions, with neutral voters still close to indifferent. Each of the 2014 curves has flattened somewhat compared to the previous years. This suggests that voters in 2014 were more open to extreme positions and less open to centrist positions while retaining the same directional preference as voters in previous years. Numeric measures of each group’s directional and extreme tendencies are given in Table 5.4 along with their predictive intervals. These mostly confirm the predictions made above. Optimistic voters do have a rightward directional tendency in 2004, with rightward point estimates in the other years as well, although the latter are not significant. Similarly, pessimistic voters have a leftward directional tendency and this is significant in every year. Neutral voters have no significant directional tendency in any year. The extreme tendency, described by the quadratic curvature, of optimistic voters is negative but not quite significant in 2004. In the context of the strong rightward tendency for this group, this figure is not especially meaningful. In 2009, however, this figure is significantly negative suggesting that optimistic voters in this year generally preferred centrist parties over more extreme parties. By 2014, this figure was no longer significant with a point estimate close to zero, suggesting that these voters were less averse to extreme economic positions than they had previously been. Pessimistic voters had a similar trajectory, with their extreme tendency significantly negative in 2004 and 2009 5.6. BEYOND LEFT AND RIGHT: SOCIAL AND ECONOMIC DIMENSIONS 137 but with a positive albeit no longer significant point estimate in 2014. The extreme tendency for neutral voters was not significant in any year, although even in this group the point estimate in 2014 was significantly greater than in 2009 (difference is 0.068 points, SE = 0.025, p < 0.01). In summary, generally speaking, voters who believed the economy was improving generally supported economically right-wing parties and those who believed it was getting worse generally supported economically left-wing parties, even when controlling for the spatial distance between the party and the voter. Not much changed between 2004 and 2009, other than a slight weakening of this tendency. This suggests that the recession sparked no major immediate shift in economic policy preferences. There was little if any change in this tendency between 2009 and 2014 but there was an increased tendency to prefer more extreme economic positions over centrists ones. Since this took place in the post-crisis period, it suggests that the political response to the crisis did lead to a shift in policy preferences away from the economic mainstream towards the extremes. Turning to the social dimension, the relevant predictions are summarised in Figure 5.7. For these predictions, the economic position is held in the centre while the social position is varied. The expectation was that these relationships would not have changed over time but this does not appear to have been the case. Optimistic voters do have similar looking curves in each year, with a directional tendency towards libertarian positions in all years, though somewhat less so in 2014. Pessimistic voters appear to have a strong centrist tendency in 2004, with an evidently negative curvature and a vertex close to the centre. By 2009, the curvature has flattened considerably, though the vertex is still close to the centre. In 2014, the curve is still quite flat but there is now a clear tendency to prefer authoritarian positions. Neutral voters are quite similar, starting with a clear negative curvature and a preference for libertarian positions. In 2009, the curve starts to flatten and by 2014 the curve remains relatively flat but the vertex has moved to the centre. In other words, it appears that optimistic voters in 2004 were libertarian-leaning and pessimistic voters centrist but by 2014, all groups had shifted to the right, so that optimists were centrist and pessimists authoritarian-leaning. Table 5.5 presents the directional tendency and curvature of the relationships between party preference and social political position in the same manner as previously. Once again, these confirm the patterns shown in the visual analysis. In 2004, optimistic voters had a clearly libertarian tendency, neutral voters a not quite significant tendency in the same direction and pessimistic voters an approximately centrist tendency. The point estimates of directional tend- 138 CHAPTER 5. EXTREME AND EUROSCEPTIC PARTIES Figure 5.7: Party preference by social libertarian–authoritarian position 2004 2009 2014 5.0 optimistic 4.5 4.0 3.0 5.0 4.5 neutral predicted preference 3.5 4.0 3.5 3.0 5.0 pessimistic 4.5 4.0 3.5 3.0 0 2 4 6 8 10 0 2 4 6 8 10 0 party position 2 4 6 8 10 Predicted party preference by party’s social libertarian–authoritarian position in each year among voters holding different prospective economic assessments. These are shown along with their 95% predictive intervals. Party position ranges from 0 (libertarian/post-materialist) to 10 (traditional/authoritarian). The economic assessments shown are those for highly optimistic voters (measured assessment of +2), neutral voters (0) and highly pessimistic voters (−2). Source: EES, ParlGov & CHES ency have changed slightly between 2004 and 2009 but these changes are not significant. The largest of these differences, that for optimistic voters, is 0.53 points (SE = 0.92, p = 0.57). Between 2009 and 2014, on the other hand, the estimates for all three groups has shifted in the authoritarian direction. In the case of optimistic voters, this change is not significant (difference is 1.11 points, SE = 0.86, p = 0.20) but it is significant for neutral (1.38 points, SE = 0.69, p = 0.04) and pessimistic voters (1.66 points, SE = 0.84, p = 0.05). Interestingly, not only were pessimistic voters the most authoritarian group in 2004 but they were also the group with the greatest shift in that direction between 2009 and 2014. As for the extreme tendency or curvature, this was not significantly different from zero for optimistic voters in any year. For neutral voters, this was significantly negative in 2004 but not in 2009 and 2014 and the increase between 2004 and 2009 was not significantly different in any case (0.022 points, SE = 0.023, p = 0.34). The curvature for negative voters was significant and 5.6. BEYOND LEFT AND RIGHT: SOCIAL AND ECONOMIC DIMENSIONS 139 Table 5.5: Directional and extreme tendency along social dimension Group Year Directional tendency Extreme tendency Optimistic 2004 2009 2014 −1.90 [−3.21, −0.59] −2.42 [−3.65, −1.20] −1.32 [−2.50, −0.14] −0.014 [−0.057, +0.028] −0.013 [−0.051, +0.025] −0.020 [−0.060, +0.019] Neutral 2004 2009 2014 −1.08 [−2.12, −0.03] −1.27 [−2.24, −0.30] +0.11 [−0.82, +1.04] −0.036 [−0.070, −0.002] −0.014 [−0.044, +0.015] −0.014 [−0.045, +0.017] Pessimistic 2004 2009 2014 −0.25 [−1.50, +0.99] −0.12 [−1.28, +1.04] +1.54 [+0.40, +2.69] −0.058 [−0.099, −0.017] −0.016 [−0.052, +0.020] −0.007 [−0.046, +0.031] Similar to Tables 5.3 and 5.4, except that the dimension analysed is the social libertarian– authoritarian spectrum rather than the general left–right spectrum. A positive directional tendency here indicates a preference for the more traditional or authoritarian parties and negative a preference for more libertarian or post-materialist parties. Source: EES, ParlGov & CHES negative in 2004 but by 2014 this curvature was almost zero. This difference was not quite significant (0.051 points, SE = 0.029, p = 0.08). The changes in directional tendency over time are surprising. The fact that there is no significant change between 2004 and 2009 suggests that there was no immediate reaction to the crisis in terms of social preferences, which accords with the expectation that the social dimension would be unaffected by the crisis. On the other hand, the change in directional tendency between 2009 and 2014 indicates that in the years after the initial recession, there was a general shift in preference towards traditional or authoritarian positions. Furthermore, the more pessimistic the voter about economic conditions, the stronger the shift. This is particularly interesting, since pessimistic voters were also the least libertarian in the first place. This suggests that there is a link between concern for the condition of the economy and embracing traditional values. As for extreme tendency, given that the changes in curvature between the years was not significant for any of the groups, if there was any increase in openness towards extreme positions on the social spectrum, this would have been modest at best. In fact, in most of the cases the curvature is not significantly different from zero, suggesting that a linear relationship is possible. In these cases, there is also a clear preference for one or the other end of the social dimension. This suggests that, unlike for the general and economic dimensions, the social dimension is not one on which there is a strong tendency to prefer the centre over the extremes. 140 5.7 CHAPTER 5. EXTREME AND EUROSCEPTIC PARTIES Conclusion This chapter has tested four hypotheses relating to the changing patterns of support for parties occupying different political positions during the Great Recession and its aftermath. In particular, levels of support were examined for parties at different positions along several political dimensions. The first hypothesis concerned party position along the European integration spectrum. The hypothesis was that pro-integration parties lost support to anti-integration parties as a result of the recession. It was found that there was such a shift in support but that it mostly occurred not so much during the recession but in the following years. It was further found that this change was mediated by an individual’s prospective economic assessment—the more pessimistic the voter, the more likely that voter was to support anti-integration parties. This was only true in 2014, voters in previous years having preferred pro-integration parties irrespective of economic assessment. Taken together, these findings indicate that an increase in anti-integration sentiment did not arise during the recession but in the post-recession period and that this increase was economically motivated. This suggests that voters started to feel that the institutions of the EU were at least partly responsible for either the continuing economic problems or the unpopular austerity policies introduced in response. This would also explain the division according to economic assessment, as those voters who were optimistic about the economy at that point were presumably those who believed that austerity polices would be effective. The second and third hypotheses concerned support for parties at different positions along the left–right political spectrum. The hypotheses were that the Great Recession led to a shortterm increase in support for right-wing positions and to an increase in support for extreme positions respectively. The results supported the hypothesis of increased extreme support but not the hypothesis of increased right-wing support. It was found rather that voters became increasingly indifferent to whether a party was on the left or the right immediately following the recession, whereas voters beforehand had tended to prefer right-wing parties when they were optimistic about the economy and left-wing parties when pessimistic. Support for more extreme parties increased both during the recession and during the years following it. These findings challenge both the luxury goods model of Durr (1993), in which optimists are supposed to prefer the left and pessimists the right, and the idea that the Great Recession pushed voters to the right (for example, Lindvall 2013; Bartels 2014). This thesis differentiates itself from those earlier studies by controlling for the economic voting effect, so it is likely that this 5.7. CONCLUSION 141 discrepancy can be explained by left-leaning and right-leaning voters having different attitudes towards the economy. The second and third hypotheses were also tested using a two-dimensional model of the political space rather than the usual spectrum. The results for the economic dimension were similar to those for the single left–right spectrum. Before the recession, optimism was a predictor of right support and pessimism of left support but this difference closed over time. Most of the change occurred during the recession rather than in the period following it. Unlike the single dimension, there was still a discernible difference between optimistic and pessimistic voters by 2014. There was also an increase in support for more extreme economic positions and this mostly took place in the aftermath period. It was expected that the social dimension would be unaffected by the recession but this proved not to be the case. There was an increase in support for parties holding traditional or authoritarian values, particularly in the period between 2009 and 2014, and this increase was strongest among pessimistic voters. Unlike the economic dimension, voters seemed to be indifferent to the extremeness of a position on the social spectrum, a linear relationship between position and support being plausible in most cases. The final hypothesis was that the other hypothesised effects were strongest among those voters who believed their national economy was worsening and this was indeed found to be the case. This is an important finding because this links the other findings with the economy and is evidence that those results are in fact related to the recession and the timing is not merely a coincidence. Taken together, these findings suggest that the changes in party support during the recession itself were quite distinct from those of the following period, during which austerity measures were widely introduced. By far the most prominent change during the recession itself was a shift towards the centre on economic issues, regardless of economic perception. Then, in the period following the recession, support for extreme economic positions increased, with no strong pattern of preference for whether those positions were on the left or the right. At the same time, support shifted from parties holding libertarian or post-materialist social views to those holding traditional or authoritarian ones. Similarly, there was a shift in support from pro-integration to anti-integration parties. As previously mentioned, all of these effects were strongest among those voters who were pessimistic about the economy. This is interesting because it suggests that the most striking political effects of the Great Recession 142 CHAPTER 5. EXTREME AND EUROSCEPTIC PARTIES may actually have been induced more by the political response to the recession than by the recession itself. This and the two preceding chapters have examined patterns of party preference during the Great Recession from several different perspectives. In order to gain a more complete understanding of the political consequences of the recession, the following chapters explore the same time period using different dependent variables. The next chapter looks at the change in patterns of turnout during the crisis and whether that too is mediated by an individual’s prospective economic assessment. Chapter 7 then examines voters’ attitudes towards the EU and further European unification, so as to establish whether the voter response to austerity politics was indeed stronger than the response to the recession itself. Chapter 6 Economic abstention: turnout intention in the face of economic pessimism An understanding of what drives voter turnout is an essential part of electoral behaviour analysis. Studying vote choice alone risks missing an important part of the electoral decision process and therefore introducing a bias into the analysis, since voters usually have the option of not voting at all and the exercise of this option may depend upon some of the same factors that also influence the party choice of those who do vote. Despite this possibility, voter turnout has long been neglected in studies of economic voting (Weschle 2014). It is widely acknowledged that turnout is in long-term decline in most of the mature democracies (Gray and Caul 2000; Blais 2000, 34–36), so this omission is becoming increasingly problematic. Furthermore, low turnout potentially has serious implications for democratic government, since certain social groups may be less likely to vote than others, and if these groups would vote differently from those who do vote, then this would introduce biases into the electoral process. In fact, there is some evidence that these biases exist, particularly in the United States (Leighley and Nagler 2014). Recognising the importance of voter turnout in electoral behaviour studies, this chapter builds upon the economic voting analysis of the previous chapters by testing for the existence of a hypothesised economic turnout relationship. This chapter begins by discussing the previous research on the relationship between economic conditions and turnout, which has produced conflicting results. There were mixed results within the earlier literature, with some scholars theorising that harsh economic conditions would motivate more people to vote, either in order to alleviate the situation (Lipset 1981, 192; Schlozman and Verba 1979, 235–239) or to punish the incumbent government (Kernell 1977), and others proposing the opposite, that such conditions would lead people to become too preoccupied with day-to-day survival to become politically involved (Wolfinger and Rosenstone 1980, 20–22). There was also a third perspective arguing that in fact no relationship 143 144 CHAPTER 6. ECONOMIC ABSTENTION between economic conditions and voter turnout ought to be expected. The empirical evidence at that time largely supported either the no effect (Lane 1959, 329–331; Fiorina 1978) or the withdrawal viewpoints (Brody and Sniderman 1977; Schlozman and Verba 1979, 254; Rosenstone 1982, 23–26). More recent studies have tried to explain these contradictory findings, either by looking at individual rather than purely aggregate data (Arceneaux 2003; Stevens 2007; Passarelli and Tuorto 2014) or by examining multiple countries comparatively (Radcliff 1992; Martins and Veige 2013). Nonetheless, conclusions remain divided. This chapter contributes to this research in two key ways. First, although there have been a number of recent individual-level studies and cross-national studies of the economic influences on turnout, very few of them are both individual-level and cross-national. This chapter examines individuallevel behaviour across nations, which sets it apart methodologically from most of the existing literature. Second, this analysis focuses on the Great Recession, which as previous chapters have discussed is an excellent opportunity to examine voter behaviour under exceptionally difficult economic circumstances. If economic conditions do indeed affect voter turnout then this time is an excellent opportunity to examine these effects, since it represents an extreme case of adverse economic conditions. 6.1 Theory The extensive economic voting literature has largely focused solely on vote choice and not on voter turnout. This is an omission that has been noted as early as Radcliff (1992, 451), who argued that the same economic conditions that were expected to promote an increased opposition vote also discourage those same individuals from voting at all. This same observation has since been picked up by others. Lacy and Burden (1999, 235), for example, make the point that vote choice models that do not account for the option of not voting are potentially biased, as they necessarily exclude from consideration all individuals in the random sample who did not vote—even though the decision not to vote is likely to have been conditioned on some of the independent variables in the model—and these individuals may have different opinions from those who do vote. In other words this approach risks introducing a selection bias. Their empirical evidence supports this criticism (252). Even in more recent years, this criticism is still being made of the economic voting literature (Stevens 2007; Tillman 2008; Weschle 2014). Stevens (2007, 167) points out that abstention is in most cases an equally viable option to supporting one or other of the parties and should therefore be included in voting behaviour models. He even goes so far as to claim that the ‘the reward–punishment 6.1. THEORY 145 model of economic voting, which informs almost all research in this field, needs to broaden its focus [because it] misses a large and important part of the story’ (183). Given the increasing acknowledgement of the importance of abstention as an alternative to making a vote choice decision, this chapter examines the factors that explain the turnout decision. Despite the tendency for turnout to be overlooked in economic voting models, there is still a literature examining the influence of economic conditions on turnout alone. Unfortunately, this literature has long been divided about the direction of this influence. In his study of the economy’s influence on voter turnout, Rosenstone (1982) identified three competing schools of thought about the effect of poor economic conditions on voter turnout. The first of these is that citizens are more likely to vote, which he refers to as ‘mobilisation’ (25–26). The argument behind this claim is based on the reward–punishment model of economic voting. If economic adversity encourages a portion of the population to punish the government electorally, then they would need to vote in order to do so, hence turnout ought to increase. The second, ‘withdrawal’, school of thought is that rather than increasing turnout, poor economic conditions should have the opposite effect (26). The argument here is that a person whose livelihood is at risk is going to be heavily focused on meeting their material needs and will thus have few resources remaining for less immediate concerns such as politics. Lastly, Rosenstone (1982, 27–28) also identifies a third, ‘no effect’, school of thought, namely that neither the mobilisation nor the withdrawal theory is accurate and that there is no consistent link between economic conditions and turnout. The argument for this position is that voters might consider any economic suffering they experience to be a personal rather than a systemic issue and not blame the government or alternatively that the modern welfare state has reduced economic suffering to the point that it is no longer a dominant issue for voters. More recent studies have tried to explain these disparate sets of findings in different ways. For example, Radcliff (1992) argues that both mobilisation and withdrawal effects can be observed, the former in developing countries and the latter in developed countries. This claim is based on an analysis of aggregate national election data from 29 countries and US timeseries election data. He further argues that this effect is mediated by the level of development of the welfare state and that withdrawal is a characteristic of marginal welfare states, and mobilisation of both non-welfare and institutional welfare states. Martins and Veige (2013), on the other hand, argue mobilisation occurs under both extremely positive and extremely negative conditions, when the economy is presumably a salient issue, and that withdrawal occurs otherwise. This is based on an examination of turnout at local government elections 146 CHAPTER 6. ECONOMIC ABSTENTION in Portugal and Flanders. One limitation of these two studies is that they were both based on aggregate data and so cannot examine the effects of individual-level differences. Arceneaux (2003) criticises some previous papers, including Radcliff (1994), for trying to draw inferences about individual behaviour from aggregate data. He argues that this is the source of evidence supporting the withdrawal hypothesis and, using data from the American National Election Studies 1990–98, finds that economic adversity increases turnout, particularly for those individuals who blame the government for the state of the economy. Another recent individual-level study of turnout and vote choice at Italian elections during the Great Recession and its aftermath found that voters critical of the government’s handling of the economy divided their response between non-voting, voting for the mainstream opposition and voting for a new radical anti-establishment party (Passarelli and Tuorto 2014). In other words, this paper also offers qualified support for the withdrawal hypothesis. The withdrawal hypothesis is further supported by Stevens (2007), based on American National Election Studies data from 1956 to 2000. It is interesting to note that, of these studies, the individual-level single-country studies have tended to find some variety of withdrawal effect, whereas the cross-country aggregate studies have found the direction of the effect to be somewhat dependent upon context, although there is no agreement on precisely how this is mediated by the context. This chapter aims to unify these different approaches by conducting multilevel analysis of turnout across a number of EU member states. By using multilevel analysis, it is possible to conduct an individual-level analysis while still taking into consideration relevant contextual factors. This chapter also examines, as previous chapters have done, three survey waves, which took place before, during and after the Great Recession. Comparing these surveys allows for an analysis of the effect of unusual severity of economic conditions, which Martins and Veige (2013) found to be an important contextual variable. Looking beyond economic conditions, the turnout literature more generally identifies several factors that are linked to turnout. There are a number of studies looking into the political and systemic factors that influence turnout and these are widely acknowledged to outweigh the importance of individual variation. For example, Powell (1980) studied turnout in 30 democracies between 1960 and 1978 and found compulsory voting, ease of registration, proportional representation and strong party–group alignment to be important predictors of high turnout. In later studies he confirms the importance of compulsory voting, party–group linkage and ease of registration, although with the exception of the United States, automatic 6.1. THEORY 147 registration is the norm for countries where registration is not compulsory (Powell 1982, 111– 132; 1986). Crewe (1981, 240–250) also discusses the strong effect of compulsory voting on turnout rates. He discusses other administrative incentives, such as postal voting and automatic registration, but largely dismisses the importance of these apart from in the United States. He also finds that countries where the party system closely corresponds to social cleavages generally experience a higher turnout (251–253). Jackman (1987) similarly finds compulsory voting to be strongly correlated with high turnout. He also finds nationally competitive districts and unicameralism to have a positive turnout effect. Multipartyism and electoral disproportionality, on the other hand, were found to have a negative effect. This last is consistent with the earlier findings that proportional representation systems generally have higher turnout than majoritarian systems. These results were largely confirmed by Jackman and Miller (1995). In their aggregate study of elections in twenty Western industrialised countries between 1847 and 1982, Blais and Carty (1990) identify compulsory voting and use of proportional representation as the most important contributors to high turnout, with population size and female suffrage also having a modest negative effect on turnout. More recent studies have once again confirmed many of these same findings. Franklin (1996) compares turnout in 37 democracies, looking at both national-level and individuallevel differences, and finding that the differences between countries eclipse the differences between individuals. At the country level, compulsory voting was once again found to be an important predictor of high turnout, along with postal voting and proportionality. Blais (2000, 25–31) finds, in addition to the well-established effects of compulsory voting, multipartyism and proportional representation, that the closeness of the election, degree of literacy and level of economic development (but not economic growth) contribute to higher turnout rates. He also argued that turnout was higher in elections that voters perceived to be close contests (74). In his review of aggregate-level turnout research, Geys (2006) discusses the importance of a number of aggregate variables, including population size and concentration, perceived closeness of the election, campaign expenditure, political fragmentation, previous levels of turnout and the characteristics of the political system. Although the largest variation in turnout exists between countries rather than individuals, there have also been a number of studies seeking to explain this individual variation. Wolfinger and Rosenstone (1980, 102–103) found education to be by far the most important predictor of an individual’s likelihood to vote, with age the second most important. Students and married individuals were also more likely to vote. Blais (2000, 51–52) used the Compar- 148 CHAPTER 6. ECONOMIC ABSTENTION ative Study of Electoral Systems post-election surveys from 1996–97 to analyse some of the causes of individual variation in turnout. He argued that education and age were the most important factors, followed by religiosity then wealth and marriage. Lewis-Beck et al. (2008, 82–107), in their individual-level study of US electoral behaviour discuss the importance of vote preference, political involvement, sense of political efficacy, sense of citizen duty, closeness of the election, education and age, mobilisation and registration. Of the socio-economic variables, age and education consistently feature as the two most important in turnout studies (Blais 2007, 630–631). Franklin (2004) sought to explain the long-term decline in turnout among established democracies. This is a particularly interesting study because it uses both aggregate and individual data to test its hypotheses. Franklin found that the decline can be explained by a combination of changing demographics and political changes. Besides some idiosyncratic political changes, such as the abolition of compulsory voting in a couple of countries, he identifies the extension of the franchise to eighteen year olds in most countries as one of the key causes (213). He specifically rules out changes in civic virtue or disaffection as causes (215). It is clear from this review that the importance of particular variables has been confirmed again and again. Compulsory voting is undoubtedly an important predictor of high turnout, as is the use of a proportional rather than a majoritarian electoral system. Small population sizes and elections that are perceived to be close are also associated with higher levels of turnout. Some of the earlier studies considered the extension of the franchise to women and eighteen year olds to be of some significance but, owing to the universality of these practices within the European Union, these are no longer relevant considerations. Similarly, as none of the countries studied in this chapter have a policy of compulsory voting that is also not relevant here.1 As for individual-level variables, the most important variables mentioned in the literature are education and age. Religiosity, wealth and marital status are also noteworthy. 6.2 Hypotheses This chapter uses survey data to test several hypotheses drawn from the theory outlined above. The competing ideas about the nature of the relationship between economic conditions and turnout lead to the following two hypotheses: 1 Belgium, Cyprus and Luxembourg do use compulsory voting but they are not included in the analysis for this chapter. 6.3. MEASURING TURNOUT INTENTION 149 Hypothesis 6.1 Voters are more inclined to vote when they believe that economic conditions will worsen, that is, there is a mobilisation effect. and alternatively: Hypothesis 6.2 Voters are less inclined to vote when they believe that economic conditions will worsen, that is, there is a withdrawal effect. These hypotheses take a prospective orientation, that is, it is assumed that voters act upon their beliefs about the future course of the economy rather than their judgement about its past performance. This is because, as has been discussed in previous chapters, there is considerably more variance in reported prospective assessments immediately after the crisis than there is in retrospective assessments, which were almost uniformly negative at that time. The third hypothesis is based on the idea that an economic crisis intensifies economically driven electoral behaviour beyond what would normally be expected, which is one of the motivating ideas behind this thesis. The importance of unusual severity of economic conditions has also been advanced as a key factor in predicting turnout by Martins and Veige (2013). This leads to the hypothesis that: Hypothesis 6.3 The effect of economic perceptions on turnout was of a greater magnitude or a different sign during the Great Recession than during a period of relatively normal economic conditions. The null hypothesis then is that the sign and magnitude were the same at both times. It is important to note that this would still allow for a stronger apparent turnout effect during the Great Recession, simply because voters would be expected to have stronger views about the condition of the economy at that time. For this hypothesis to be supported, there would have to be evidence that any observable difference in turnout cannot be explained by a simple linear model. 6.3 Measuring turnout intention In order to test these hypotheses, the EES survey data is used once again. As in previous chapters, the 2004, 2009 and 2014 waves are compared, so as to be able to contrast behaviour during the Great Recession and its aftermath with behaviour during relatively normal economic conditions. Compulsory voting is presumed to dampen any abstention effect considerably, so this analysis excludes countries where compulsory voting is enforced. This means 150 CHAPTER 6. ECONOMIC ABSTENTION that Belgium, Cyprus and Luxembourg are excluded, while Greece is still included because compulsory voting is not enforced there and Switzerland is also included because voting is only compulsory in one canton (Birch 2008, 36). The dependent variable, turnout intention, was measured with the question ‘And if there was a general election tomorrow, which party would you vote for?’2 In the first two waves, this was asked as an open-ended question and no list of options was read out. Those respondents who named a party are coded as having turnout intention and those who said they would not vote, would spoil their vote or would vote blank are coded as having no turnout intention. Unfortunately, in the most recent wave, a list of parties was read out, and this appears to have affected the response. Whereas 89.6 percent and 87.8 percent of voters reported intending to vote in 2004 and 2009 respectively, a full 95.8 percent of voters reported intending to vote in 2014, when refusals are excluded. On the other hand, the proportion of refusals also increased considerably in 2014. Furthermore, it has been known for some time that survey respondents tend to overreport turnout (for example, see Traugott and Katosh 1979). It has also been shown that offering face-saving responses tends to mitigate this tendency (Zeglovits and Kritzinger 2014). Based on these ideas, it was decided to code refusals to answer this question as as non-intention to vote. Although not a perfect solution, this produces a similar turnout intention rate in year, with 72.7 percent, 76.4 percent and 65.9 percent of respondents coded as having turnout intention in 2004, 2009 and 2014 respectively. These estimated turnout rates are much closer to the actual recorded turnout rates than the implausibly high rates obtained by ignoring refusals. Figure 6.1 shows the average turnout at national elections in the EU since 1990, with the survey years indicated by dashed vertical lines. As the figure shows, the average turnout at national elections in the EU since the year 2000 has been between the mid-sixties and the low-seventies. The estimated turnout rates also lie in this range, although they are still slightly higher than the recorded turnouts in the corresponding years. This remaining discrepancy might result partly from the fact that the vote choice question is hypothetical and therefore not a perfect indicator of what voters would do at an actual election. Moreover, the recorded average turnout for a particular year is of course affected by which countries actually held general elections in that year, as typical turnout rates vary from country to country. It is also likely that the sample is not perfectly random.3 The effects of this are mitigated by including appropriate controls in the model but it means that 2 This question was worded identically in all three survey waves, except that ‘was’ became ‘were’ in 2014. As always, the local translations may vary. 3 Sampling, as well as related questions like interview mode and response rates, are discussed in Chapter 2. 6.3. MEASURING TURNOUT INTENTION 151 Figure 6.1: Average turnout at national elections in EU countries EU average turnout 77.5 75.0 72.5 70.0 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 year Average turnout at national elections in the European Union (EU-27) by year. The three dashed lines indicate the survey years of 2004, 2009 and 2014. Source: Eurostat there may be problems in estimating the population turnout rate from this data, which is not the purpose of this chapter anyway. It can also be seen from this figure that turnout has been in decline over the medium term. This decline has been seen across the developed world and has attracted much scholarly attention (see for example Lyons and Alexander 2000; Franklin 2004; Blais 2007, 2013). Its relevance to this chapter is simply that this medium-term decline should be kept in mind when making inferences about any change in the absolute turnout rate across the period 2004–2014. As was discussed earlier, the variables that are expected to predict turnout are largely the same as those predicting vote choice. The substantive independent variables are party identification and economic assessment. Additionally, whether the voter reported voting at the previous general election is a new independent variable for this chapter. This inclusion is based on the evidence that voting tends to be habitual (Green and Shacar 2000; Plutzer 2002; Coppock and Green 2015), so those who have voted before are more likely to vote again. This variable is measured in the same way as the dependent variable, except that it is based on a question asking voters who they voted for at the preceding general election in their country, rather than a hypothetical election held tomorrow. In addition to these, the same 152 CHAPTER 6. ECONOMIC ABSTENTION Figure 6.2: Proportion intending to vote by year and economic assessment 2004 2009 2014 0.9 0.8 prospective 0.7 0.6 proportion 0.5 0.4 0.9 0.8 retrospective 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 -2 -1 0 1 2 -2 -1 0 1 2 -2 -1 0 1 2 economic assessment Proportion of respondents intending to vote according to the respondent’s prospective (first row) and retrospective (second row) economic assessment in each survey year, shown with 95% confidence intervals. Both forms of economic assessment are measured on a five-point scale ranging from −2, indicating a very negative assessment, to +2, indicating a very positive assessment, with 0 indicating a neutral assessment. Source: EES control variables are used as in previous chapters. See Chapter 2 for a discussion of how these variables were measured. The mobilisation and withdrawal hypotheses (Hypotheses 6.1 and 6.2) predict that voters are respectively more or less inclined to vote when they believe that economic conditions are poor. The pattern of responses to the vote intention question suggests that voters were more likely to abstain from voting during the recession than they had been beforehand and that they became even more likely to abstain in the years after the recession. The mean proportion of respondents indicating an intention to vote was 72.7 percent [72.1%, 73.3%]4 in 2004, which fell to 67.7 percent [66.7%, 68.0%] in 2009 and 65.9 percent [65.3%, 66.5%] in 2014. These changes are all statistically significant. This decline in turnout intention over the 2004–2014 4 Square brackets indicate 95% confidence intervals. 6.4. AN ECONOMIC MODEL OF TURNOUT 153 decade is consistent with the decline in actual turnout at national elections shown over the same period in Figure 6.1. In order to shed light on the questions of mobilisation and withdrawal, it is necessary to look at the relationship between economic assessment and turnout intention. Figure 6.2 shows the proportion of respondents indicating that they would vote at an election held the following day disaggregated by their assessment of the economic conditions in their country. The first row shows the breakdown by prospective economic assessment. An estimate of zero indicates the belief that the economy will remain more or less the same over the following year; negative numbers indicate the belief that it will get worse; and positive numbers indicate the belief that it will improve. A similar pattern is observable in all three years. A positive assessment of future economic conditions is associated with a greater likelihood of voting. This pattern is preliminary evidence in support of the withdrawal hypothesis. The second row shows the proportion intending to vote according to their retrospective economic assessment. Here negative numbers indicate the belief that the economy has become worse over the past year and positive numbers the belief that it has improved. In 2004 and 2014 the pattern of turnout according to retrospective economic assessment closely resembles that according to prospective assessment. In 2009, however, the proportion intending to vote does not increase monotonically as the retrospective assessment improves and the confidence interval for the most positive category is very wide because only a handful of voters claimed that the economy in 2009 was much better than it had been previously. This mirrors the relationship between mean party support and both kinds of economic assessment, which was discussed in Chapter 3. Accordingly, the prospective measure will continue to be used, as it has throughout this thesis. 6.4 An economic model of turnout A multilevel logistic regression model (Model 6A) has been constructed so as to test whether there was a mobilisation or withdrawal effect and whether the magnitude of that effect was altered during the crisis. This has two main advantages. First, it makes it possible to control for confounding variables that might otherwise explain the differences discussed above. Second, because this is a comparative study of multiple countries, multilevel analysis helps to to separate the variance due to individual variation from the variance due to the cross-national design. This model predicts the probability of an individual intending to vote based primarily on his or her prospective economic assessment, party identification and past behaviour and past behaviour. Prospective economic assessment is on a five-point scale, with negative 154 CHAPTER 6. ECONOMIC ABSTENTION scores indicating a pessimistic assessment, positive scores an optimistic assessment and zero a neutral assessment. Since each country has its own set of political parties, the various party identifications have been grouped into government identifiers, those who identify with one of the parties included in the cabinet, opposition identifiers, who identify with any other party, and non-identifiers, who did not feel close to any particular party. The reference group is nonidentifiers. Past behaviour is represented by a dummy variable indicating whether or not the respondent reported having voted at the previous national election. Naturally, the survey year is also included in the model so that changes over time can be detected. As is usual, 2004 is the reference year and the other two years are represented by dummy variables. Interaction terms are also included between the survey year dummies and each of these primary predictors. In addition to these substantive variables, several demographic variables have also been included in the model. As previously, these control for the sex, age, level of education and labour force status of the respondent, as well as the population density of his or her area of residence. Interaction terms have also been included between age and the party identification variables, as in previous chapters. As a multilevel model, this model also controls for the country where the interview occurred by means of a random intercept. Random slopes were also included for the two party identification dummy variables, in order to account for the fact that these do represent different parties in the different countries. This model was used to predicted the probabilities of an individual reporting that they would vote at an election held the following day under various circumstances. Figure 6.3 shows these predicted turnout probabilities according to the survey year and whether the individual reported voting at the previous general election.5 These particular predictions are for an individual holding a neutral prospective economic assessment. The predicted likelihood of someone voting if they had voted at the previous election was 72 percent [68%, 75%] in 2004, 61 percent [57%, 66%] in 2009 and 71 percent [68%, 75%] in 2014. For people who had not voted at the previous election, these probabilities were much lower, at 29 percent [25%, 32%] in 2004, 20 percent [17%, 23%] in 2009 and 22 percent [20%, 26%] in 2014. All of these differences are significant, except for the difference between 2004 and 2014 among people who had previously voted (odds ratio 0.99, CI 0.91–1.07). It thus appears that people were less inclined to vote during the recession than beforehand or afterwards, although this inclination did not recover its previous level among people who had not voted previously. As the figure shows, having voted at the previous election is a very strong predictor of future 5 Unless otherwise specified, all predictions are for a 40 year old male, who has completed high school but not university, is employed and lives in a town. 6.4. AN ECONOMIC MODEL OF TURNOUT 155 Figure 6.3: Predicted probability of voting by past behaviour predicted turnout probability 0.7 0.6 at last election 0.5 voted did not vote 0.4 0.3 0.2 2004 2009 2014 year Predicted probability that an individual would vote in each survey year. The top line is for an individual who reported voting at the previous national election and the bottom line is for an individual who did not. These predictions are all for individuals with a neutral prospective economic assessment. Source: EES & ParlGov voting intention. This is unsurprising in light of the evidence that voting is a habit (Green and Shacar 2000; Plutzer 2002; Coppock and Green 2015). Voters in 2004 were 2.5 times as likely (odds ratio 6.3, CI 5.8–6.8) to vote if they had voted at the previous election, compared to 3.1 times as likely (OR 6.4, CI 5.9–6.9) in 2009 and 3.2 times as likely (OR 9.7, CI 8.0– 9.3) in 2014.6 The difference between 2004 and 2009 is not statistically significant (OR 1.01, CI 0.91–1.13) but appears larger owing to the lower base rate in that year. The difference between 2009 and 2014, on the other hand, is significant (OR 1.36, CI 1.22–1.51). This suggests that there was increased divergence between habitual voters and non-habitual voters in the years following the recession. The other key independent variables were party identification and prospective economic assessment. Figure 6.4 shows the relationship between these and the predicted likelihood of an 6 In order to keep the interpretation of these results as intuitive as possible, the effect sizes reported here are relative probabilities. This has the disadvantage that relative probabilities are sensitive to the initial conditions, that is, the same effect size can produce quite different relative probabilities if the base probability changes. For this reason, the corresponding odds ratios are also reported. The uncertainty of the estimates is indicated by giving the 95% confidence interval around the odds ratio. The reason confidence intervals are used for this model, rather than the standard errors and p-values used elsewhere in the thesis, is that standard errors are only meaningful on the log odds scale for logit models, not the odds ratio or relative probability scales. 156 CHAPTER 6. ECONOMIC ABSTENTION Figure 6.4: Predicted probability of voting by economic assessment and party identification predicted turnout probability 2004 2009 2014 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 -2 -1 0 1 2 -2 -1 0 1 2 -2 -1 0 1 2 prospective economic assessment party ID government opposition none Predicted probability that an individual would vote according to that individual’s prospective economic assessment as well as the survey year. Economic assessment ranges from −2 (very pessimistic) to +2 (very optimistic). The top line in each year represents an individual who identifies with one of the parties currently represented in the cabinet. The middle line represents an individual identifying with one of the other parties and the bottom line represents an individual who lacks any party identification. These predictions are for an individual who reported having voted at the previous national election. Source: EES & ParlGov individual voting in each survey year. It can be seen that party identification plays a large role in predicting the likelihood of someone voting. In all years, party identifiers are considerably more likely to vote than non-party identifiers and those identifying with opposition parties are slightly more likely to vote than those identifying with government parties. For example, in 2004, government identifiers were 27 percent more likely to vote (OR 4.3, CI 3.5–5.2) than those identifying with no party and opposition identifiers were a further 3.1 percent as likely to vote (OR 1.6, CI 1.3–1.9). The difference between non-party identifiers and government identifiers gradually widened (OR 1.33, CI 1.14–1.55) between 2004 and 2014, while the gap between government and opposition identifiers narrowed somewhat (OR 0.80, CI 0.66– 0.96) over the same period. The differences between 2009 and the other two years were not significant, or in one case barely significant. As the figure shows, the likelihood of voting dropped among all three groups in 2009 before recovering in 2014. It is interesting to note that 6.4. AN ECONOMIC MODEL OF TURNOUT 157 the likelihood of voting in 2014 actually exceeded that of voting in 2004 among government identifiers, with this group 2.0 percent more likely (OR 1.31, CI 1.14–1.51) to vote than before. The relationship of most substantive interest for this chapter is that between an individual’s economic assessment and his or her likelihood of voting. It can be seen from Figure 6.4 that optimistic voters were more likely to vote than pessimistic voters in all three years. This can be described as an economic abstention effect. Among non-party identifiers who had voted at the previous election, highly optimistic voters were 13 percent more likely to vote (OR 1.55, CI 1.33–1.81) than highly pessimistic voters in 2004, compared to 8.8 percent more likely (OR 1.24, CI 1.08–1.43) in 2009 and 23 percent more likely (OR 2.06, CI 1.75– 2.42) in 2014. These findings support the withdrawal hypothesis, which states that pessimistic voters are less inclined to vote, and contradict the mobilisation hypothesis, which asserts the opposite. This economic abstention effect was weaker (OR 0.80, CI 0.65–2.05) in 2009 than in 2004, which can be seen from the shallower slopes in the figure. The effect became stronger again (OR 1.65, CI 1.34–2.05) in 2014, actually exceeding (OR 1.32, CI 1.05–1.66) its 2004 strength. This is reflected in the steeper slopes in the 2014 panel in the figure. These findings contradict Hypothesis 6.3, which predicts that the Great Recession would either strengthen the magnitude or reverse the sign of any economic abstention effect. In fact, these findings suggest that the effect was partly suppressed during the recession. On the other hand, the effect was strengthened beyond its initial level during the post-recession period. This fits the pattern, found in previous chapters, of economic voting effects becoming weaker during the crisis itself, with the most striking effects occurring in its aftermath. In addition to these effects, there were also some small demographic differences in the likelihood of voting. Women were 3.7 percent less likely (OR 0.88, CI 0.84–0.92) to vote than men.7 The model allows age to interact with party identification, so the effect of age varies accordingly. For non-party identifiers a 30 year old was 3.0 percent less likely (OR 1.04, CI 1.01–1.07) than a 20 year old, compared to 0.4 percent less likely for either a government (OR 0.94, CI 0.92–0.97) or opposition (OR 0.92, CI 0.89–0.94) identifier. It is surprising that older people are apparently less likely to vote than younger people but this is only true because everything else is held equal. In particular, many older poeple are no longer in the workforce and older people are also less likely to hold a pessimistic economic assessment than younger people. Education had a small effect, with those who had not finished high school 2.7 percent more likely (OR 1.11, CI 1.04–1.18) to vote than those who had, when 7 All of these comparisons are for a non-party identifier in 2004 holding a neutral economic assessment. 158 CHAPTER 6. ECONOMIC ABSTENTION everything else is held equal. University graduates were not significantly different from high school graduates (OR 1.03, CI 0.98–1.09). Urban density had no significant effect on turnout. Employed people were not significantly different from the unemployed (OR 0.99, CI 0.91– 1.07) but those not in the workforce, which includes retired people, were 4.9 percent more likely (OR 1.20, CI 1.14–1.26) to vote than the employed. As this is a multilevel model, it is also possible to investigate the degree to which individual countries deviate from what has already been discussed. The intercept varies considerably between countries, which is unsurprising given that the actual level of turnout varies from country to country. According to this model, among those holding no party identification, respondents in the United Kingdom, Ireland and Denmark were the most likely to report intending to vote, whereas voters in Portugal, Malta and Poland were the least likely to do so. Among those identifying with government parties, however, respondents in Finland, Denmark and Slovakia were the most likely to indicate an intention to vote, whereas voters in Ireland were the least likely, followed by Slovenia and Malta. In fact, the random intercept is negatively correlated with the random slopes for both government (ρ = −0.70) and opposition (ρ = −0.89) identification, which means that the countries with the highest turnout among non-party identifiers also tend to be those with the lowest turnout among party identifiers. The two party identification random slopes are positively correlated (ρ = +0.55), indicating that turnout among the government and opposition identifiers of a country tends to be similar, given that the corresponding fixed effects are also close. 6.5 Conclusion Previous research has produced inconsistent findings on the nature of the relationship between economic conditions and voter turnout. The competing hypotheses are that voters are mobilised to vote by poor economic conditions in order to hold the government responsible and that voters withdraw under poor economic conditions because they are demotivated by the situation (Rosenstone 1982). A multilevel analysis of survey data collected from 22 countries in three different years was conducted in order to shed further light on this question. This approach has the advantage of being less sensitive to country-specific circumstances as well as the increased statistical power of the larger sample size. This analysis supports the withdrawal hypothesis and is inconsistent with the mobilisation hypothesis. In all three years, it was found that voters with a more optimistic prospective economic assessment were more likely to vote, often considerably more likely. 6.5. CONCLUSION 159 It was also hypothesised that any economic abstention effect would be either stronger or reversed in direction during a time of deep international crisis than under more typical economic conditions. Although the other hypotheses have been examined by earlier studies, there have been comparatively few that have studied voter behaviour under crisis conditions. It has previously been argued that withdrawal occurs during ordinary conditions but that mobilisation takes place under extremely positive or negative conditions (Martins and Veige 2013). By comparing the two surveys, one collected during the Great Recession and one well before it began, this chapter has been able to examine this hypothesis. It was found that the withdrawal effect still prevailed during the crisis, although it was weaker, as well as after the crisis, when it was even stronger than it had been previously. This evidence does not support the hypothesis. Rather, as in previous chapters, it suggests that the normal economicdriven electoral tendencies of voters were muted during the crisis itself, with the strongest effects taking place well after the initial crisis. This pattern suggests that voters may have been responding more to the political reaction to the recession than to its mere occurrence. Since this pattern has emerged in the findings made in this thesis, focus will now turn to establishing whether there is other evidence that the political reaction to the Great Recession has had a greater impact on voters than the crisis itself. A possibility that presents itself is that voters were primarily reacting against the austerity policies implemented in the wake of the crisis. If this is indeed the case, then it ought to affect attitudes towards the European institutions, which in many cases promoted those policies. The next chapter will examine European voters’ attitudes towards the European Union and the prospect of further integration. By examining the relationship between these attitudes and voters’ economic assessments, as well as the evolution in these patterns over time, further light will be shed on this question. Chapter 7 Attitudes towards European integration and institutions On 23 June 2016, the citizens of the United Kingdom voted to leave the European Union. Despite the government and all three major parties opposing the move, 51.9 percent of the votes cast in the referendum were in favour of leaving, with a high turnout of 72.2 percent (BBC News 2016a). This surprising result is just the most visible manifestation of increasing anti-EU sentiment. It follows the 2014 European Parliament elections, which delivered a record number of seats to overtly Eurosceptic parties. The three strongly pro-EU groups lost 65 seats at the election, largely to radical right, Eurosceptic groups (Brack and Startin 2015, 242). The Greek results, which saw a surge of support to the far left Syriza and far right Golden Dawn at the expense of the centrist parties, have been described as a ‘seismic shock’ (Verney 2015). These events followed not just the Great Recession but also a period in which many European governments introduced harsh austerity policies in attempt to stave off further economic troubles. Do these results represent an underlying shift in sentiment away from the institutions of the EU, and if so, can this shift be linked to the politics of austerity? This chapter explores these questions. A pattern has emerged in the findings made in this thesis so far, which is that the most striking shifts in voter behaviour took place later than expected. It was shown in Chapter 3 that the economic vote was strongest not in 2009, when the first wave of the Great Recession was at its peak, but in 2014 when this had given way to a period of austerity politics. A similar pattern was found for voter turnout in Chapter 6. It was also shown in Chapter 5 that voters were more likely to show support for parties holding far left and far right positions in this post-recession period than they were either before or during the recession. In all of these cases, voters holding pessimistic views about the economy showed stronger changes in behaviour than those holding optimistic views. These trends suggest that the instigator for 161 162 CHAPTER 7. ATTITUDES TOWARDS EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND INSTITUTIONS the change in voter behaviour may have been the unpopular austerity policies introduced after the recession, rather than the mere fact of the recession itself. These policies were strongly associated with the European Union, partly because the EU did encourage them and partly because national governments found it convenient to remind voters of the European scope of many of the economic problems facing their countries in order to diffuse responsibility for politically troublesome measures (Hobolt and Tilley 2014, 100–119). If this theory is true, then accordingly there ought to be evidence of a change in attitudes towards European institutions between 2009 and 2014. This chapter analyses survey data in order to test whether such a change took place. The chapter begins by discussing the data that was used to explore these questions. The European Election Studies surveys used throughout this thesis include a number of questions addressing attitudes towards different aspects of EU politics and this section explains which were used for this analysis and the reasons behind that selection. Following that, the chapter introduces the four hypotheses that will be tested and discusses the theoretical motivation behind them. Three statistical models have been constructed to test these hypotheses and these are discussed in the following sections. The first of these concerns attitudes towards European unification and whether voters believe that this should go further or that it has already gone too far. The second looks at whether voters believe that membership of the EU is a good thing or a bad thing for their country. The final model addresses the attribution of responsibility for the economy and the degree to which voters hold the EU as opposed to their national governments economically responsible. The evidence offered by these models supports the theory that the post-recession austerity period produced a greater response in voters than the recession itself did. The chapter concludes with a summary of these findings and a discussion of their implications. 7.1 Austerity and the European Union The European Union has had an active role in introducing austerity measures to four of its member states: Ireland, Greece, Portugal and Cyprus. This took the form of ‘economic adjustment programmes’—bailouts conditional on specified economic reforms—negotiated by the European Commission in conjunction with the European Central Bank and the International Monetary Fund. These three institutions are sometimes referred to collectively as the Troika.1 1 The term ‘Troika’ is occasionally even used in official documents, e.g. European Commission (2011b, 4). 7.1. AUSTERITY AND THE EUROPEAN UNION 163 In May 2010, Greece was the first country to negotiate such an agreement, receiving 80 billion euros in loans from other Eurozone countries and a further 30 billion euros from the IMF. In return, Greece was required to implement a number of structural reforms, including expenditure cuts amounting to seven percent of its GDP, much of which came from pensions and government wages, and new tax measures equivalent to four percent of GDP (European Commission 2010). In December 2010, in the wake of its banking crisis, Ireland was the second country to negotiate a bailout package with the Troika, receiving 85 billion euros of financial assistance while being required to increase taxation and cut expenditure drastically, among other things (European Commission 2011a). This pattern of loans granted by the Troika to member states contingent upon the imposition severe austerity measures was continued in the following years, with an agreement signed by Portugal in May 2011 (European Commission 2011b), a second agreement signed by Greece in March 2012 (European Commission 2012), and finally an agreement with Cyprus signed in March 2013 (European Commission 2013). Although European institutions have only been actively involved in the austerity policies of these four countries, their influence is broader than that. The rules of the Economic and Monetary Union, which are binding on Eurozone members, include a ‘Stability Growth Pact’ (SGP). The SGP requires member states to keep government deficits to within three percent of GDP and also requires that they aim for surpluses in the medium term, with strict sanctions specified for breaches, although these are not automatic in operation and have proven easily avoidable (Heipertz and Verdun 2010, 3–7). These rules have effectively institutionalised the monetarist position, which is favoured by German politicians, but conflicts with competing economic theories preferred by others, such as Keynesianism (Scharpf 2013, 109–114). It has been argued that monetarist policy has not been effective for the Eurozone, owing to the large size of the currency union (114–125). McBride (2015) argues that the SGP and other EU rules such as the limit the capacity of member states to adopt any expansionary policies—in other words, austerity is enforced from the centre. It has also been argued that not only do the economic adjustment programmes reflect a German belief in austerity as the only option, but they also put economic pressure on the remaining member states to adopt similar policies, if they wish to avoid losing competitiveness (Flassbeck and Lapavitsas 2015). The EU is thus directly responsible for the austerity programmes of four countries and arguably indirectly responsible for austerity measures taken elsewhere. Even in countries where austerity has not been adopted, taxpayers have funded a large proportion of the bailout loans paid out under the four economic adjustment programmes. Moreover, there is evidence 164 CHAPTER 7. ATTITUDES TOWARDS EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND INSTITUTIONS that national politicians have been able to persuade many voters that the European Union, rather than themselves, is responsible for disliked policies, economic or otherwise (Hobolt and Tilley 2014). It will also be shown later in this chapter that voters typically regarded the EU as having more responsibility for the economy in 2014 than they had done in 2009. This suggests that attitudes towards the EU would be likely to reflect any anti-austerity sentiment arising in the post-recession period. 7.2 Measuring attitudes towards the European Union One important question that arises when examining attitudes towards the EU is whether these attitudes are merely a reflection of the voter’s position on the left–right spectrum, or whether they represent an additional, orthogonal dimension to Europeans’ political views. There are competing views in the literature as to the relationship between these two dimensions. The ‘international relations model’ sees the European question as unrelated to domestic left–right questions, pertaining instead to questions of national interest, so that the major parties in a particular country might be expected to show some agreement on the question of integration (Steenbergen and Marks 2004, 5–6). Hix and Lord (1997, 26), on the other hand, argue that the integration question is a second, orthogonal dimension to the politics of EU member states. This still assumes that the two dimensions are independent but it also permits intranational contestation of the integration question. An analysis of European manifestos has given this model some empirical support (Hix 1999). A third model is the ‘regulation model’ (Steenbergen and Marks 2004, 7–8; Tsebelis and Garrett 2000), which argues that the European dimension is not independent of the left–right dimension. In this model, those on the left are supposed to be in favour of higher regulation and therefore greater European integration and those on the right of less regulation and so looser European integration. Finally, Hooghe and Marks (1999) argue that the two dimensions cannot be collapsed together but are not independent either. Political positions along these two dimensions are constrained by ‘the emergence of a cleavage ranging from center-left supranationalists who support regulated capitalism to rightist nationalists who support neoliberalism’ (76). Efforts to compare these models empirically have made similar findings, although their interpretations differ in some respects. Gabel and Hix (2004, 111) found that the best performing model was the traditional unidimensional left–right model in their analysis of European election manifestos. Gabel and Anderson (2004, 30) agree that European politics is effectively 7.2. MEASURING ATTITUDES TOWARDS THE EUROPEAN UNION 165 unidimensional in their study of citizen attitudes, although they appear to favour a HoogheMarks interpretation of that dimension. According to Hooghe, Marks and Wilson (2004, 139), European integration is structured by the traditional left–right dimension but the two dimensions are not identical because parties at the extreme left and right are less supportive of the EU than parties occupying the centre. Others argue that attitudes towards the EU are a reflection of not so much a person’s political views but their perceptions of their own government. Harteveld, van der Meer and De Vries (2013, 561) observed that trust in national institutions was an important predictor of trust in the EU in Eurobarometer survey data from 2009. This was seen as confirming their hypothesised ‘logic of extrapolation’, which proposed that ‘the legitimacy of the EU is actually derived indirectly, through the legitimacy of the individual member states’ (546–547). Even when a second, European dimension of political space has been recognised, its importance has not been undisputed. Van der Eijk and Franklin (2004, 32) have shown that this dimension has not had a large influence on European political behaviour, although this work took place well before the Great Recession. They argue that this is not because this dimension is unimportant to European voters but rather because the parties on offer at EU elections do not cover the entire political space, which means that voters are not currently free to select parties according to both their left–right preferences and their preferences towards the EU. For this reason, they describe this European preference dimension as a ‘sleeping giant’ that has the potential to awaken as a new motivator for vote choice if either new parties emerge to fill those empty parts of the political space or unforeseen events lead voters to prioritise their EU preferences over their left–right preferences (van der Eijk and Franklin 2004). One of the goals of this chapter is to determine whether either the Great Recession or the austerity period could be said to have constituted such an event. For the purposes of this chapter, it is assumed that there is an EU dimension to Europeans’ political views and that this can be measured through survey questions. It is not however assumed that this is completely independent of the left–right dimension and this is why the models introduced later in the chapter control for the individual’s left–right position. As will be seen, the results from those models suggest that, while there is a relationship between the two dimensions, this relationship is not overwhelmingly powerful nor is left–right position the dominant predictor of attitudes towards the EU. Precisely how to measure these attitudes is also not uncontested. Boomgaarden et al. (2011, 242) argue that discussion of attitudes towards the EU requires more precise terms 166 CHAPTER 7. ATTITUDES TOWARDS EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND INSTITUTIONS than ‘EU support’ or ‘Euroscepticism’. To this end, they conducted a survey in the Netherlands in 2008 asking various different questions about attitudes towards the EU (246). A factor analysis of their results found five factors, each consisting of five items. These factors were identified as negative affection, identity, performance, utilitarianism and strengthening (247– 251). Unfortunately, the EES survey data does not include items that would allow each of these dimensions to be measured in every year but it does include one question corresponding to the utilitarianism dimension and one corresponding to the strengthening dimension. These are the questions asking whether membership of the EU is a good thing and whether European integration has gone too far respectively. Since these two questions appear to be measuring somewhat different things, they are both analysed in this chapter. There are several questions in the EES surveys asking about attitudes towards the European Union. Often there are corresponding questions about the respondent’s national government, which would allow attitudes towards the EU and towards national governments to be compared directly. Unfortunately, the set of questions asked is different in each wave and some otherwise promising questions were not asked in each of the years under study. For example, questions about satisfaction with democracy in both the EU and the respondent’s country were asked in both 2004 and 2009 but not in 2014. Questions about trust in the national and European parliaments were missing from the 2009 survey and questions about whether the national and European parliaments respond to the concerns of citizens were not asked in the 2004 survey. Despite these difficulties, a set of survey questions was selected that does offer a useful comparison of attitudes towards the EU across the years of interest. The first of these questions asked voters to give an opinion as to whether further European unification is desirable. The precise wording of the question is: Some say European unification should be pushed further. Others say it already has gone too far. What is your opinion? Please indicate your views using a scale from 0 to 10, where 0 means unification ‘has already gone too far’ and 10 means ‘it should be pushed further’. What number on this scale best describes your position? This wording is almost identical in all three years, except that in 2004 a ten-point scale was used rather than an eleven-point scale. The use of ten-point scales was a consistent feature of the 2004 survey wave. In order to make these responses comparable to the responses in the later waves, the same correction was applied as was used for similar scales in previous chapters. See Chapter 2 for full details. 7.2. MEASURING ATTITUDES TOWARDS THE EUROPEAN UNION 167 The second question asks voters their opinion of their country’s EU membership. The wording is almost identical in all three years: Generally speaking, do you think that [country’s] membership of the European Union is a good thing, a bad thing, or neither good nor bad? Although this question is superficially similar to the first question, they are measuring different things. It is quite consistent to believe, for example, that European integration has gone too far while still holding that membership of the EU is a good thing. This interpretation is supported by the fact that the two variables are only weakly correlated (Spearman’s ρ = 0.38). If the two variables were in fact measuring the same thing, this correlation ought to be considerably stronger. The final two questions ask voters to attribute a degree of responsibility for their country’s economic conditions to their country’s government and to the EU respectively. The 2009 survey worded the questions as following: Now I would like to ask you some questions about how much responsibility the [country’s] government and the European Union have for some of the things going on in [country]. Of course you may think that neither is responsible. First, thinking about the economy, how responsible is the [country’s] government for economic conditions in [country]? Please indicate your views using any number on a scale from 0 to 10, where 0 means ‘no responsibility’ and 10 means ‘full responsibility’. And what about the European Union, how responsible is the EU for economic conditions in [country]?2 Unfortunately, these questions were only introduced in 2009, so they are not included in the 2004 survey. These questions are, however, so directly relevant to this thesis that they are worth using despite this omission. This means that it is not possible to gain as complete a picture of this variable as it is other variables, in that 2004 cannot serve as a baseline comparison year in this case. On the other hand, this pair of variables does make it possible to examine the relative responsibility assigned to governments compared to the EU in the key years of 2009 and 2014. 2 The wording used in the 2014 survey is: ‘Now I would like to ask you some questions about how much responsibility the different institutions have in the current economic situation in [country]. Please use a scale from 0 to 10, where 0 means that you think they have “no responsibility” and 10 means that they “full responsibility”.’ The country’s government and the European Union are the first two institutions read out. 168 7.3 CHAPTER 7. ATTITUDES TOWARDS EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND INSTITUTIONS Hypotheses The focus of this chapter is voter attitudes towards the European Union. The objective is to determine whether there was an observable shift in attitudes in the post-recession period. Such a shift could help to explain the results of the previous chapters, in which it was found that the most notable changes took place in the period following the recession rather than during the recession itself. Based on these findings, it was theorised that it was chiefly the austerity policies characterising the post-recession period that voters were reacting against. If this theory is accurate, then it would be expected that voters reacted against the EU in particular during this period, as the EU was strongly associated with these austerity policies. This chapter tests four specific hypotheses derived from these ideas. The first hypotheses concern support for the institutions of the EU. This chapter has introduced two relevant variables, namely the respondent’s opinion about the desirability of continued European integration and whether membership of the EU is a good thing for the respondent’s country. Although it has been argued that these variables are measuring different things, it is hypothesised that they have been affected similarly by the events of the Great Recession and its aftermath. One of the key ideas in previous chapters has been that the economic voting concept is generalisable beyond vote choice to related variables, such as turnout. Accordingly, it is expected that support for EU institutions is likewise influenced by a citizen’s prospective economic assessment. This leads to the chapter’s first hypothesis: Hypothesis 7.1 Support for both EU membership and further European integration is greater among voters who have an optimistic economic assessment. Previous work using Eurobarometer survey data has already shown that support for both of these is linked to an individual’s retrospective economic assessment (Gabel and Whitten 1997). It has also been shown, using the 2009 EES survey data, that a positive retrospective assessment is associated with greater satisfaction with democracy at the EU level (Hobolt 2012, 99). Although this thesis uses some of the same data, it is still useful to test this hypothesis for two reasons. Firstly, those studies tested a retrospective version of the hypothesis, whereas this thesis is focused on the effects of prospective economic assessment.3 The second reason is that this study includes the data from not only 2009 but also 2004 and 2014, which provides 3 The main reason for this is that the respondents in the 2009 EES survey were broadly in agreement that the economy had worsened over the past year, whereas there was considerably more variation in the responses to the prospective question. Chapter 1 discusses this issue in greater depth. 7.3. HYPOTHESES 169 an opportunity to examine how this relationship has evolved over the course of the recession and its aftermath. The main idea that this chapter seeks to test is that the post-crisis austerity policies are responsible for a voter backlash against the European Union. If this is indeed the case, then it would be expected that there would be an observable decline in support for the institutions of the EU in the period following the crisis. The second hypothesis is thus: Hypothesis 7.2 Support for both EU membership and further European integration fell between 2009 and 2014. Some existing studies have looked at related questions. For example, Armingeon and Ceka (2014, 83) observe that trust in the EU has fallen considerably over the course of the Great Recession, particularly in Greece. They argue that this can largely be explained by falling support for national governments (103). In a multilevel analysis of European Social Survey data from 2002, Kumlin (2009, 416) found a link between support for further European integration and both national public service dissatisfaction and national social spending. In particular, he found that both greater public service dissatisfaction and national social spending were associated with reduced integration support. He also found an interaction between these effects, so that the effect of public service dissatisfaction was even stronger in countries with high social spending. Mau (2005) looked at support for EU membership and for social policy-making at the European level. Most relevantly for this study, he found that support for EU membership was greater among those with higher socioeconomic status (79). Garry and Tilley (2014) argue that European citizens are more likely to favour European integration when they perceive that EU policies are preferable to those of the national government. For example, left-leaning citizens in countries where the prevailing consensus is right-leaning ought to be more supportive of the EU than right-leaning citizens. Their analysis of the 2009 EES survey data supports this theory. While none of these studies address this hypothesis directly, they do add weight to the idea that any decline in economic wellbeing ought to be linked to a reduction in support for the EU. Furthermore, it would be expected that this decline in support would be concentrated among those voters holding a pessimistic assessment of the economy. The reason for this is that optimistic voters presumably believe that the current economic policy is effective, whereas pessimistic voters would be more critical. Since this relationship has already been hypothesised to exist, it is expected that it would become stronger during the post-crisis period. The third hypothesis is thus: 170 CHAPTER 7. ATTITUDES TOWARDS EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND INSTITUTIONS Hypothesis 7.3 The effect of economic assessment on support for both EU membership and further European integration was strengthened between 2009 and 2014. The final hypothesis concerns the way citizens allocate responsibility for the economy between their national governments and the European Union. If voters did hold the EU to some degree responsible for the austerity policies that were put in place following the recession, then it would be expected that more responsibility for the economy was attributed to the EU during this period than beforehand. Another way of measuring the allocation of responsibility is to look at the difference between how responsible an individual holds the EU and how responsible that same individual holds the national government for the condition of the economy. This then gives an indication of where that individual believes the balance of responsibility between the two institutions lies. For the same reasons as before, it is expected that this balance would have shifted towards the EU during the post-recession period. The final hypothesis is therefore: Hypothesis 7.4 More economic responsibility was attributed to the EU, both in absolute terms and relative to that attributed to national governments, in 2014 than in 2009. Hobolt and Tilley (2014, 33–34) looked at the responsibility questions in the 2009 EES survey, including those for non-economic areas of responsibility and they also conducted an expert survey asking the same questions. They noted that citizens tended to attribute more responsibility for the economy to the EU than experts did (35). While both citizens and experts show some awareness of the various competencies of the EU and of national governments, the complexity of EU structures seems to make it difficult for people to make a definitive attribution of responsibility (44-45). This is concerning because it means that European voters’ perceptions of responsibility do not accord with the reality of which institutions hold the relevant powers and this discord is likely to damage long-term trust in those institutions (147). This hypothesis offers an opportunity to further this analysis with respect to responsibility for the economy by examining whether voters attributed responsibility differently following the implementation of austerity policies in so many countries. 7.4 Attitudes towards further European integration The first three hypotheses all concern attitudes towards continuing European integration as well as EU membership. This section focuses on integration, with the following section discussing membership. In order to test these hypotheses, a model was constructed to explain 7.4. ATTITUDES TOWARDS FURTHER EUROPEAN INTEGRATION 171 attitude towards European unification in terms of a number of relevant predictors. As in previous chapters, a multilevel model has been used so as to take into account the hierarchical structure of the data. In particular, it is believed that two individuals randomly selected from within a single country are more likely to have similar attitudes towards the EU than two individuals randomly selected from the entire EU. In order to take this into account, a two-level model has been built in which individuals are nested within countries. Model 7A describes a voter’s attitude towards European integration chiefly in terms of time, prospective economic assessment and left–right position. As has been the case throughout this thesis, time is modelled as a categorical variable so as not to assume anything about the pattern of change in the dependent variable across the years under study. This means that two dummy variables are included in the model to represent the 2009 and 2014 waves of the survey respectively, with the 2004 wave being the base case. Prospective economic assessment is included in the model in order to test the first hypothesis, namely that voters with a more positive assessment are likely to be more in favour of European unification. The voter’s left– right position is included as a predictor because it is likely that a voter’s assessment of the economy is influenced by their own political beliefs. In particular, austerity policies are likely to be more palatable to voters on the right than those on the left. Controlling for left–right position makes it possible to examine these effects separately and ensure that any relationship found between support for integration and prospective economic assessment is not merely an artefact of the voter’s ideology. Left–right position is modelled quadratically to account for the possibility of a curvilinear relationship, like those found between voter support for parties and the left–right position of those parties in Chapter 5. Indeed, it has been argued that Eurosceptic positions should be more common among the far left and the far right, simply because policies made at the European level will generally represent centrist preferences (Hix 2007, 136–137). The modelled quadratic relationship can account for this. This model additionally includes variables controlling for a number of demographic variables. As in previous chapters, these variables are age, gender, level of education, urban density and workforce status. This choice of controls has been informed by previous research showing that many of these factors are related to attitudes towards the EU. It is well-known, for example, that Euroscepticism is more prevalent among people with lower levels of education than among the highly educated (Hakhverdian et al. 2013, 523). Hakhverdian et al. (2013, 526–529) argue that this effect ought to have become stronger over time as a result of continuing market integration, the development of organised Eurosceptic political parties and 172 CHAPTER 7. ATTITUDES TOWARDS EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND INSTITUTIONS weakened national sovereignty. Using Eurobarometer data from 1973 to 2010, they show that there has indeed been an increasing educational gap in Euroscepticism since the signing of the Maastricht Treaty (531–535). Other political beliefs are also believed to be related. For example, C. J. Anderson (1998, 574–575) argues that people are not sufficiently well-informed about international politics, including EU politics, for direct questions about attitudes towards European integration to be independent of domestic attitudes. He proposes that models of public opinion regarding the integration process control for other relevant political factors (594). Similarly, Tillman (2013) argues that individuals holding authoritarian values are less likely to support European integration, supporting this argument with data from the 2008 wave of the European Values Survey. Domestic political beliefs are accounted for by the inclusion of the individual’s left–right position in the model. The model also includes interactions between time and each of the other variables. Without these interactions the model would assume a static relationship between the dependent and independent variables, which is unrealistic. The interaction between time and prospective economic assessment in particular is necessary in order to test the third hypothesis, which asserts that this relationship has strengthened between 2009 and 2014. As different subpopulations are likely to have been affected to different degrees by both the recession and the austerity policies that followed it, it also makes sense to allow for the possibility that the level of support for European integration has evolved in different ways among those different groups. Including interactions between time and each of the control variables achieves this goal. Finally, as this is a multilevel model, it was necessary to determine which, if any, random slopes should be included in addition to the random intercept for the country. Random slopes were included for the two time dummy variables, as it expected that there are country-specific circumstances that would cause the level of support for unification to evolve in different ways in different countries. Random slopes were also included for the economic assessment term and its interaction with the time dummy variables. Random slopes were not included for any of the controls. The reason for this was that the estimated variance of these random slopes was very small, which can lead to convergence problems and also means that they do not improve the model particularly. This model has been used to predict an individual’s attitude towards further European integration based on his or her prospective economic assessment.4 These predictions are displayed in Figure 7.1, which shows that support for unification progressively decayed across 4 Unless otherwise specified, all predictions are for a 40-year-old employed male having completed high school but not university and living in a mid-sized town. 7.4. ATTITUDES TOWARDS FURTHER EUROPEAN INTEGRATION 173 Figure 7.1: Support for European integration by prospective economic assessment support for integration 6.0 5.5 year 2004 5.0 2009 2014 4.5 4.0 3.5 -2 -1 0 1 prospective economic assessment 2 Predicted support for European integration in each survey year according to the individual’s prospective economic assessment, ranging from −2 for a highly pessimistic assessment to +2 for a highly optimistic assessment. These predictions are for an individual holding a left–right position in the centre of the spectrum. Source: EES the survey years irrespective of economic assessment. For a voter with a neutral economic assessment, this decay in support amounts to a 0.41 point (SE = 0.14, p < 0.01) drop between 2004 and 2009 with a further 0.70 point (SE = 0.14, p < 0.001) drop by 2014. From this plot, it is also apparent that a more optimistic economic assessment is associated with a greater support for further European unification, although the shallower slope of the 2009 line suggests that this effect may have been weaker then than in the other two years. The size of this effect in a given year can be summarised by the difference in the predicted support for further integration of an individual holding a strongly optimistic and one holding a strongly pessimistic economic assessment. This is the greatest change in support that can be attributed to variation in economic assessment. This amounts to 1.49 points (SE = 1.49, p < 0.001) in 2004, 0.91 points (SE = 0.17, p < 0.001) in 2009 and 1.89 points (SE = 0.24, p < 0.001) in 2014. As the plot suggests, the effect size in 2009 is significantly smaller than in both 2004 (∆ = 0.58 points, SE = 0.19, p < 0.01) and 2014 (∆ = 0.99 points, SE = 0.32, p < 0.01). The difference between 2004 and 2014 is not significant (∆ = 0.41 points, SE = 0.29, p = 0.16). Figure 7.2 shows the relationship between a voter’s left–right position and that voter’s predicted level of support for further European integration. Comparing to Figure 7.1 also shows 174 CHAPTER 7. ATTITUDES TOWARDS EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND INSTITUTIONS Figure 7.2: Support for European integration by left–right position 5.8 support for integration 5.6 5.4 5.2 year 2004 5.0 2009 2014 4.8 4.6 4.4 0 2 4 6 left–right position 8 10 Predicted support for European integration in each survey year according to the individual’s assessment of their own left–right position, ranging from 0 (left) to 10 (right). These predictions are for an individual holding a neutral prospective economic assessment. Source: EES that the effect of left–right position is very modest compared to that of prospective economic assessment. Once again, it is clear that the level of support has generally declined across the survey years. It also appears that support has decayed more among right-wing voters than leftwing voters. In 2004 and 2009, it appears that left-wing and right-wing voters are both more supportive of integration than those in the centre, with right-wing voters perhaps slightly more supportive than left-wing voters. By 2014, this pattern has changed, with left-wing voters the most supportive of further integration and right-wing voters the least supportive in an approximately linear relationship. In order to confirm the relationships suggested by this figure, it is helpful to derive numeric estimates of the quantities of interest as well as estimates of their statistical significance. In this case, there are two key quantities of interest. The first is the degree, if any, to which right-wing voters are more likely to support integration than left-wing voters.5 This directional tendency is positive if voters on the right are more supportive than voters on the left and negative if the opposite is the case. In 2004, the directional tendency was +0.44 (SE = 0.22, p = 0.05), 5 The measurement of both directional tendency and curvature is discussed in more detail in Chapter 5. In summary, directional tendency is the difference between the definite integrals of the two halves of the curve and curvature is the second derivative of the curve function, which in the case of a quadratic is a constant. 7.4. ATTITUDES TOWARDS FURTHER EUROPEAN INTEGRATION 175 indicating that support for integration was very slightly higher among right-wing than leftwing voters. The directional tendency in 2009 was not significant at +0.08 (SE = 0.20, p = 0.71). This means that it was unlikely that there was a difference in support between those on the left and the right in that year. In fact, the difference between the directional tendency of the two years is also not significant (∆ = 0.37, SE = 0.30, p = 0.22). In any case, the difference between left- and right-wing voters is either small or absent in both years. The directional tendency for 2014 on the other hand is −0.71 (SE = 0.21, p < 0.001), which is significantly different from the other years (∆ = 0.78, SE = 0.29, p < 0.01, compared to 2009). This is still a modest tendency but it does suggest that by 2014 European unification had become somewhat more popular on the left than on the right, albeit less popular among both groups than in previous years. The second quantity of interest is the curvature of the relationship in each year. This represents the degree to which voters near the extremes differ from those in the centre.6 A positive curvature indicates that support is greater towards the extremes and a negative curvature indicates that support is greatest at the centre. If the curvature is zero, then the curve is in fact a line. The estimated curvature is +0.008 (SE = 0.005, p = 0.11) in 2004, +0.016 (SE = 0.005, p < 0.001) in 2009 and −0.002 (SE = 0.005, p = 0.76). The only year in which this is significantly different from zero is 2009, in which there is a slight tendency for centrist voters to be less supportive of integration than those on the left and the right. The estimated curvature for 2009 is not significantly different from that of 2004 (∆ = 0.008, SE = 0.007, p = 0.27) but it is significantly different from that of 2014 (∆ = 0.018, SE = 0.007, p < 0.01). Taken together, the directional tendency and curvature findings provide evidence that there was a change in the relationship between left–right position and support for European integration between 2009 and 2014. There is only weak evidence of a change between 2004 and 2009. It must also be emphasised that this is a weak effect in any case. Many of the control variables included in the model were also found to be related to support for unification. As the effect sizes are small for these variables, the results will be summarised briefly. Older people appear to be very slightly less supportive of European integration than younger people, which each additional decade of age associated with a 0.060 point (SE = 0.015, p < 0.001) decrease in support in 2004. The size of this effect was not significantly different in the other years, being 0.012 points (SE = 0.021, p = 0.58) stronger 6 The ‘centre’ in this case is not necessarily the centre of the political spectrum but rather the vertex of the curve. If, however, the directional tendency is close to zero, which has been shown to be the case, then the vertex will be close to the point corresponding to the political centre. The location of the vertex can also be visually ascertained from the plot. 176 CHAPTER 7. ATTITUDES TOWARDS EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND INSTITUTIONS in 2009 and 0.016 points (SE = 0.021, p = 0.44) stronger in 2014 per decade of age than in 2004. Gender also played a very modest role, with women being 0.21 points (SE = 0.04, p < 0.001) less supportive of integration than men in 2004, 0.13 points (SE = 0.04, p < 0.01) less in 2009 and 0.14 points (SE = 0.04, p < 0.01) less in 2014, all other things being equal. Once again, the differences between the years were not significant. Education played a somewhat stronger role. There were three levels of education modelled, indicating the highest level of education attained. This is a university degree in the case of high education, a high school certificate in the case of medium education and neither of the above in the case of low education. There was a significant difference in support for European integration among these educational groups in each year, with higher education consistently associated with greater support. In 2004, an individual with medium education was predicted to be 0.36 points (SE = 0.06, p < 0.001) more supportive of unification than an individual with low education. An individual with high education was predicted to be a further 0.37 points (SE = 0.05, p < 0.001) more supportive. These relationships were not significantly different in the other years, except that the predictive difference between low and medium levels of education was 0.20 points (SE = 0.09, p = 0.02) smaller in 2009 and 2004. This particular result is likely to be statistical noise, given that the error is relatively high compared to the difference and that the other differences are not significant. Unlike education, the importance of urban density did appear to change over time. In 2004, voters living in urban areas were the most supportive of European integration. An urban voter was predicted to be 0.21 points (SE = 0.06, p < 0.001) more supportive than a voter living in a town and 0.31 points (SE = 0.05, p < 0.001) more supportive than a rural voter. By 2009, this gap had closed slightly, so that an urban voter was only 0.12 points SE = 0.05, p = 0.02 points more supportive than a rural voter, a 0.19 point (SE = 0.07, p = 0.01) difference. By 2014, the direction had changed, so that rural voters were now more 0.16 points (SE = 0.06, p < 0.01) more supportive of integration than urban voters, a 0.28 point (SE = 0.08, p < 0.001) change from 2004. Lastly, workforce status is a factor that would very much be expected to have some influence. In particular, it is expected that unemployed respondents would be harsher critics of European institutions than the employed or those not in the workforce. In fact, the estimated effect size of workforce status, all other things being equal, is very low and for the most part not significant. In 2004, unemployed voters are not significantly different from either employed voters (∆ = 0.087, SE = 0.095, p = 0.36) or those not in the workforce (∆ = 0.076, 7.5. POPULAR SUPPORT FOR EU MEMBERSHIP 177 SE = 0.102, p = 0.46). Employed people are predicted to be 0.16 points (SE = 0.05, p < 0.01) more supportive of further integration than those not in the workforce. Although these point estimates do differ slightly in the other years, none of the differences are significant. As this is a multilevel model, there are also estimates of the variances and covariances of the random effect terms. The random intercept accounts for 45 percent of the country-level variance and the random slopes for the time dummy variables account for a further 42 percent. That is, the bulk of the country-level variance was related to variation in the underlying level of support for European integration in each country and how that evolved over time. Only 13 percent of that variance was related to variation in the effect of prospective economic assessment in different countries. There is a moderate negative correlation (−0.50) between the random intercept and the slope for the time dummy variable indicating the year 2009. This indicates that countries that had high levels of support for unification in 2004 had typically lost some support by 2009 and those with low levels had gained some. Similarly, there is a weak negative correlation (−0.24) between the effective level of support in 2009 and the difference between 2009 and 2014, indicating a similar pattern between those two years. This is consistent with a regression to the mean over time. Combined, the country-level random effects account for 16 percent of the total residual variance in the model. This means that most of the variation is actually between individuals rather than between countries. In summary, support for further European integration was strongest in 2004, decaying between 2004 and 2009 and particularly between 2009 and 2014. Voters holding optimistic economic assessments were typically more supportive of integration than those holding pessimistic assessments, although the size of this effect was depressed in 2009 before recovering in 2014. A voter’s left–right position had only a small effect on his or her level of support but there was a slight tendency for right-wing voters to be more pro-integration than left-wing voters in 2004, a tendency which had reversed by 2014. These results are consistent with this chapter’s first three hypotheses, which predicted a positive relationship between economic assessment and support for integration, becoming stronger after 2009, as well as an overall decline in support for integration after 2009. 7.5 Popular support for EU membership Another potential indicator of satisfaction or dissatisfaction with the European Union is whether or not voters believe that EU membership is a good thing for their country. The same set of 178 CHAPTER 7. ATTITUDES TOWARDS EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND INSTITUTIONS hypotheses that applied to attitudes towards European integration also apply to attitudes towards EU membership. That is, it is expected that EU membership was seen less positively after 2009 and that there is a positive relationship between prospective economic assessment and attitude towards EU membership, which became stronger after 2009. Model 7B was constructed in order to test these hypotheses. This variable only has three levels of measurement, indicating a positive view, a negative view and a neutral view of EU membership. As a result, it is preferable to use a model that assumes an ordinal scale rather then the stronger assumption of an interval scale. To this end, a multilevel ordinal logit model has been used to model the likelihood of individuals believing that EU membership is a good thing or a bad thing for their country. The selection of predictors modelled is the same as for the integration model. This reflects the fact that both models seek to test the same hypotheses. Once again, the key predictors are time, prospective economic assessment and left–right position, which is modelled quadratically. Age, gender, education, urban density and workforce status are included as controls. Time is represented by two dummy variables, one for the year 2009 and one for 2014, with 2004 the base case. These dummy variables are interacted with each of the other variables so as to allow for variation in the strength of those effects over time. As before, this is a multilevel model, with individuals nested within countries. As well as the random intercept, this model includes random slopes for economic assessment, the time dummy variables and their interactions. This model was estimated and post-estimation simulation was used to predict the probabilities of an individual evaluating EU membership positively, negatively or neither in each survey year. Figure 7.3 shows these predicted probabilities for an individual with a neutral prospective economic assessment and who sits in the centre of the political spectrum. This figure shows that the majority of voters evaluated the EU positively in all three years, ranging from 55 percent [50%, 61%]7 in 2014 to 68 percent [61%, 74%] in 2009. Negative evaluations were comparatively rare, ranging from 7.6 percent [5.8%, 9.9%] in 2009 to 13 percent [10%, 15%] in 2014. As the figure shows, EU membership was seen more positively in 2009, during the initial crisis, than it was before or afterwards. Voters in 2009 were thirteen percent more likely (odds ratio 1.39, CI 1.04–1.86) than in 2004 and eight percent less likely (OR 0.59, CI 0.46–0.76) than in 2014 to see EU membership as good for their country. It appears from 7 Square brackets indicate 95% confidence intervals. 7.5. POPULAR SUPPORT FOR EU MEMBERSHIP 179 Figure 7.3: Evaluation of EU membership over time 0.7 predicted probability 0.6 0.5 evaluation good 0.4 neither bad 0.3 0.2 0.1 2004 2009 year 2014 Predicted probabilities of an individual holding a particular evaluation of EU membership in each year. These possible evaluations are that EU membership is good for that individual’s country, bad for the country, or neither good nor bad. These predictions are for an individual holding a neutral economic assessment and a left–right position in the centre of the spectrum. Source: EES the figure as though assessments of EU membership were less positive in 2014 than in 2004 but this difference is not significant (OR 0.92, CI 0.79–1.04).8 Figure 7.4 shows the relationship between an individual’s prospective economic assessment and that individual’s probability of evaluating EU membership positively, assuming a neutral assessment of the economy. From this point onwards, focus will be limited to the predicted probability of a ‘good’ response. This is because the relationships between the probabilities of the various responses have been modelled as independent of the predictors,9 so examining the other responses separately would not affect the inferences that could be drawn. As the figure shows, there is a strong relationship between prospective economic assessment and the likelihood of a positive evaluation of EU membership. An individual who was highly optimistic about the economy was more than twice as likely (OR 5.82, CI 3.76–8.95) to evaluate EU membership positively in 2004 than one who was highly pessimistic about the economy. 8 As in the previous chapter, the percentage differences reported in the text are relative probabilities, with odds ratios and confidence intervals given alongside in brackets. 9 In particular, the likelihood of the ‘bad’ response is given by odds(bad) = k/ odds(good) where k = 0.172 [0.168, 0.177] was estimated from the data. As the three possible responses are mutually exclusive, this gives enough information to infer the likelihood of the ‘neither’ response: P(neither) = 1 − P(good) − P(bad). 180 CHAPTER 7. ATTITUDES TOWARDS EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND INSTITUTIONS Figure 7.4: Positive evaluation of EU membership by prospective economic assessment 0.8 predicted probability 0.7 year 0.6 2004 2009 0.5 2014 0.4 0.3 -2 -1 0 1 prospective economic assessment 2 Predicted probability of an individual evaluating EU membership as good for his or her country. Probabilities are shown according to the survey year and the individual’s prospective economic assessment, ranging from −2 for a highly pessimistic assessment to +2 for a highly optimistic assessment. These predictions are for an individual holding a left–right position in the centre of the spectrum. Source: EES This effect became significantly weaker (OR 0.60, CI 0.43–0.86) in 2009, when optimists were only one and a half times as likely (OR 3.52, CI 2.67–4.61) as pessimists to see EU membership positively. By 2014, this effect had strengthened once again (OR 3.09, CI 1.81–5.26), becoming a three-fold difference (OR 10.9, CI 7.51–15.6) between optimists and pessimists. The difference between the 2004 and 2014 effect sizes is not quite significant (OR 1.87, CI 0.95– 3.66). This figure also shows that most of the divergence over time occurred among pessimistic voters, with optimistic voters remaining quite consistent. Figure 7.5 shows how the predicted probability of a positive evaluation of EU membership varies according to the individual’s reported left–right position. It is clear from this figure that those on the right typically see EU membership more positively than those on the left. Another thing that this figure shows is that the size of this effect is greatest in 2009. Comparing this figure with Figure 7.4 also shows that left–right position has a smaller impact on this evaluation than economic assessment does. As this relationship is modelled quadratically, it will be summarised using the same measures of directional tendency and curvature as previously, although the underlying units in this case are on the logit scale. The directional 7.5. POPULAR SUPPORT FOR EU MEMBERSHIP 181 Figure 7.5: Positive evaluation of EU membership by left–right position predicted probability 0.70 0.65 year 2004 0.60 2009 2014 0.55 0.50 0 2 4 6 left–right position 8 10 Predicted probability of an individual evaluating EU membership as good for his or her country. Probabilities are shown according to the survey year and the individual’s assessment of their own left–right position, ranging from 0 (left) to 10 (right). These predictions are for an individual holding a neutral prospective economic assessment. Source: EES tendency was +0.72 (SE = 0.16, p < 0.001) in 2004, +1.26 (SE = 0.15, p < 0.001) in 2009 and +0.68 (SE = 0.15, p < 0.001) in 2014. This confirms that the probability of a positive evaluation was greater among right-wing voters than left-wing voters in all years. The pattern over time was that this imbalance increased (∆ = 0.54, SE = 0.22, p = 0.01) from 2004 to 2009 before decreasing again (∆ = 0.58, SE = 0.22, p < 0.01) by 2014 to very close to its original level (∆ = 0.04, SE = 0.22, p = 0.86). As for curvature, there was a small negative curvature (−0.010, SE = 0.004, p < 0.01) in 2009, indicating a slight tendency for those in the centre to see EU membership more positively than those at the extremes. This was very close to zero in both 2004 (+0.004, SE = 0.004, p = 0.25) and 2014 (−0.004, SE = 0.004, p = 0.32), indicating that the relationship in those years was approximately linear. Some of the control variables are much stronger predictors of an individual’s assessment of EU membership than others. The effect of age, for example, on the probability of a positive assessment is not significantly different from zero (OR 1.00, CI 0.98–1.03) in 2004, nor is the effect significantly stronger in either of the other years. Men were approximately ten percent more likely (OR 1.24, CI 1.17–1.32) than women to assess EU membership positively in 2004. 182 CHAPTER 7. ATTITUDES TOWARDS EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND INSTITUTIONS This effect was not significantly different in 2009 but by 2014 it had weakened (OR 0.87, CI 0.80–0.95) to a four percent increase in probability (OR 1.08, CI 1.02–1.15). In general, higher levels of education were associated with a more positive assessment of EU membership. In 2004, voters with a university education were 35 percent more likely (OR 2.16, CI 1.98– 2.37) to see EU membership positively than voters who had not completed high school. This difference grew (OR 1.27, CI 1.12–1.44) between 2004 and 2009, to a 37 percent increase in probability (OR 2.75, CI 2.52–3.00).10 There was no significant difference between 2009 and 2014 (OR 0.97, CI 0.86–1.11). Similarly, voters interviewed in areas of higher population density are more likely to assess EU membership positively. In 2004, voters in cities were eleven percent more likely (OR 1.29, CI 1.20–1.40) to do so than voters living in rural areas. This effect was about the same in 2009 but by 2014 had weakened (OR 0.78, CI 0.69–0.87) such that there was no longer a statistically significant difference between rural areas and cities (OR 1.01, CI 0.93–1.09). There was also a small workforce status effect. In 2004, voters who were unemployed were seven percent less likely (OR 0.83, CI 0.73–0.95) and voters who were neither employed nor unemployed—frequently retirees—were four percent more likely (OR 1.11, CI 1.03–1.19) to evaluate EU membership positively than those who were employed. These effects were remarkably consistent over time, with no significant differences between any pair of years. As this is a multilevel model, some things can also be said about the variances and covariances of the random effects terms. There is once again a moderate negative correlation (−0.41) between the random intercept and the random slope for the 2009 time dummy variable, which indicates that in those countries where assessments of EU memberships were highly positive or highly negative in 2004 tended to be have more moderate assessments in 2009. Similarly, there is a strong negative correlation (−0.66) between the 2014 time dummy variable and the effective 2009 level for each country. As this is consistent with a regression to the mean effect, it suggests that the measured country-specific levels of support owe much to chance. The remaining random slopes explain only sixteen percent of the total country-level variance. Unfortunately, with an ordered logit model such as this, the concept of residual variance is not well-defined, so it is difficult to talk about the total proportion of the variance explained by the random effects. In summary, EU membership is seen by most citizens as good, or at least neutral, for their respective countries. Support for the idea that EU membership is a good thing peaked in 2009, 10 The reason that the considerably higher odds ratio only corresponds to a small increase in relative probability is that the base probability is higher in 2009 than in 2004. 7.6. ATTRIBUTION OF RESPONSIBILITY FOR THE ECONOMY 183 during the initial phase of the Great Recession, before returning to roughly its 2004 levels by 2014. An optimistic economic assessment was a strong predictor of a positive evaluation of EU membership in all years. Those holding a pessimistic economic assessment were most critical of the EU in 2014 and least critical in 2009. Left–right position also had a modest influence, with those on right generally being more positive in their assessment than those on the left, especially in 2009. These results are consistent with the three hypotheses this model was constructed to test, which were that support for EU membership fell between 2009 and 2014, that support for EU membership was positively linked to economic assessment, and that the strength of that relationship grew between 2009 and 2014. 7.6 Attribution of responsibility for the economy The final hypothesis concerns the attribution of responsibility for the economy between the European Union and the appropriate national government. This hypothesis states that the EU was held more responsible in 2014 than it was in 2009, both in absolute terms and relative to national governments. A model was constructed in order to test this hypothesis. The dependent variable in Model 7C is the level of responsibility a particular individual attributes to a particular institution on an eleven-point scale and a dummy predictor variable indicates whether the institution is the EU or the national government. In other respects this model is similar to the earlier model measuring support for European integration. Like that model, this one includes as predictors the individual’s prospective economic assessment, left–right position, age, gender and level of education. It also includes a time dummy variable, which is interacted with each of those other variables. Unlike the other model, this one only includes a single time variable because there is no data available from 2004. The base year in this model is 2009 and the time dummy variable indicates the year 2014. Furthermore, each other variable, including the interactions, is interacted with the institutional dummy variable. This was done so as not to assume that any of those variables affect the amount of responsibility accorded to the different institutions in precisely the same way. Finally, like the other models in this chapter, this is a multilevel model with individuals nested within countries. Random slopes have been included for, as previously, time and prospective economic assessment and, additionally, their interactions with the institution dummy variable. According to this model, a typical centrist voter with a neutral prospective economic assessment would have held the government more responsible than the EU for the economy in 184 CHAPTER 7. ATTITUDES TOWARDS EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND INSTITUTIONS Figure 7.6: Attribution of economic responsibility by prospective economic assessment 2009 2014 predicted responsibility 7.5 7.0 6.5 6.0 5.5 -2 -1 0 1 2 -2 -1 0 prospective economic assessment institution national government 1 2 European Union Predicted level of responsibility attributed to the national government and to the European Union in 2009 and 2014 according to the individual’s prospective economic assessment, which ranges from −2 for a highly pessimistic assessment to +2 for a highly optimistic assessment. These predictions are for an individual holding a left–right position in the centre of the spectrum. Source: EES both years. The predicted responsibility scores that this voter would have assigned the government were 7.15 (SE = 0.13, p < 0.001) in 2009 and 7.41 (SE = 0.12, p < 0.001) in 2014. The difference between the two years is not significant (∆ = 0.25, SE = 0.17, p = 0.13). The predicted scores assigned to the EU were 5.58 (SE = 0.10, p < 0.001) in 2009 and 6.37 (SE = 0.13, p < 0.001) in 2014. This means that the responsibility attributed to the EU increased by 0.79 points (SE = 0.10, p < 0.001) between the two years. In relative terms, the responsibility attributed to the EU in 2009 was 1.58 points (SE = 0.16, p < 0.001) less than that attributed to the national government, whereas by 2014 this difference was only 1.04 points (SE = 0.12, p < 0.001; ∆ = 0.53, SE = 0.17, p < 0.01). In other words, this class of voter generally considered national governments to be more responsible for the economy than the EU but this gap has closed somewhat over time as voters have started to attribute a greater amount of responsibility to the EU. 7.6. ATTRIBUTION OF RESPONSIBILITY FOR THE ECONOMY 185 Figure 7.7: Attribution of economic responsibility by left–right position 2009 2014 predicted responsibility 7.5 7.0 6.5 6.0 5.5 0 2 4 institution 6 8 10 0 2 left–right position national government 4 6 8 10 European Union Predicted level of responsibility attributed to the national government and to the European Union in 2009 and 2014 according to the individual’s assessment of their own left–right position, ranging from 0 (left) to 10 (right). These predictions are for an individual holding a neutral prospective economic assessment. Source: EES Figure 7.6 shows how these predicted responsibility scores vary for voters with differing economic assessments. The first thing that stands out in this figure is that voters in 2014 were generally more likely to hold the EU responsible for economic conditions than voters in 2004. It is also clear that in 2009, individuals who were highly optimistic about the economy typically assigned national governments less responsibility for the economy than those who were highly pessimistic. This effect accounts for 0.63 points (SE = 0.24, p < 0.01) of difference. It appears from the plot that there was a similar, albeit weaker, effect for the responsibility attributed to the EU but this effect was not statistically significant (0.12 points, SE = 0.15, p = 0.43), nor was there a significant effect in 2014 (0.14 points, SE = 0.25, p = 0.59). This effect had also weakened (∆ = 0.79, SE = 0.31, p < 0.01) for governments so that it was no longer significant (−0.16 points, SE = 0.32, p = 0.61) by 2014. Figure 7.7 shows the relationship between a voter’s left–right position and that individual’s predicted responsibility scores under this model, assuming in this case a neutral economic 186 CHAPTER 7. ATTITUDES TOWARDS EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND INSTITUTIONS assessment. One thing that stands out in this figure, as in the last, is that all groups of voters held the European Union more responsible for the economy than they did in 2009. It also appears that right-wing voters in 2009 were more likely to hold governments accountable for the condition of the economy and that otherwise voters on both the left and the right are more inclined to assign higher responsibility scores than voters in the centre. The directional tendency for government responsibility was +1.03 (SE = 0.17, p < 0.001) in 2009 but had fallen (∆ = 0.90, SE = 0.25, p < 0.001) to almost zero (+0.13, SE = 0.18, p = 0.47) in 2014. This confirms the impression that right-wing voters tended to hold governments more responsible for the economy than left-wing voters but only in 2009. The directional tendency for EU responsibility was positive but not quite significant at +0.32 (SE = 0.17, p = 0.06) in 2009 and not significant in 2014 (+0.15, SE = 0.24, p < 0.01). The curvature was positive in all cases, as the figure suggests. Specifically, for government responsibility, this was +0.009 (SE = 0.004, p = 0.03) in 2009 and +0.010 (SE = 0.004, p = 0.01) in 2014 and for EU responsibility, +0.018 (SE = 0.004, p < 0.001) in 2009 and +0.020 (SE = 0.004, p < 0.001) in 2014. These figures confirm that centrist voters were somewhat less inclined to assign high responsibility scores than voters on the left and right. This may simply be a result of higher political interest among those voters who identify as being further from the centre. As the control variables are of less substantive interest, their analysis will be limited to their effect on the relative responsibility attributed to national governments over the EU. In general, older people are more likely to attribute economy responsibility to their national governments than the EU, although the effect is very small, amounting to an extra 0.04 points (SE = 0.02, p = 0.01) of difference in 2009 and a similar amount in 2014. Gender had a stronger effect, with men’s relative responsibility scores 0.23 points (SE = 0.05, p < 0.001) greater than women’s in 2009. By 2014 however, this effect had declined in magnitude (∆ = 0.15, SE = 0.07, p = 0.03) so that it was no longer significant. In 2009, higher levels of education were associated with more responsibility assigned to the government over the EU, there being a 0.36 point (SE = 0.07, p < 0.001) difference between university educated voters and those who did not complete high school. By 2014, there was no longer a significant difference between these groups (∆ = −0.29, SE = 0.11, p < 0.01). Urban density did not have a significant effect in 2009 but by 2014 a pattern had emerged in which those living in urban areas attributed more responsibility to the EU relative to the national government than those in rural areas. This amounted to a 0.18 point (SE = 0.07, p < 0.01) difference between cities and rural areas. Lastly, there was also a mild workforce status effect in 2009, when 7.7. CONCLUSION 187 employed voters attributed more responsibility to the government relative to the EU than both unemployed voters (∆ = 0.28, SE = 0.11, p < 0.01) and those not in the workforce (∆ = 0.14, SE = 0.06, p = 0.02). These effects were not significant in 2014 but the differences between the years were also not significant. The random effects account for 26 percent of the total variance in this model, which is considerably more than in the European integration model. This suggests that country-level differences are more important influences on beliefs about who is responsible for the economy than on attitudes towards continuing integration. There is a strong negative correlation (−0.77) between the random intercept and the random slope for the institution dummy variable. This indicates that, in 2009, countries where the government was seen as highly responsible for the economy tended to see the EU as less responsible and vice versa. There is also a strong negative correlation (−0.68) between the time random slope and the random intercept and a similar correlation (−0.73) between the time random slope and the random slope for the time–institution interaction. These are both consistent with regression to the mean. The institution and time dummy variables along with their interactions account for 87 percent of the country-level variance. These results support the fourth hypothesis, which states that the level of responsibility for the economy attributed to the EU increased between 2009 and 2014 and that additionally the balance between the responsibility assigned to the EU and to national governments shifted towards the EU over the same time period. The post-estimation predictions from this model show that these patterns are indeed observable. It was somewhat surprising to see that prospective economic assessment played only a minor role in the attribution of responsibility, really only being relevant for the EU and in 2009 and even then on a relatively modest scale. The reason this is surprising is that this variable has been shown to be an important predictor in the other models not just in this chapter but throughout this thesis, predicting party preference and turnout likelihood as well as attitudes towards European unification EU membership. Based on this model it appears that voters’ attribution of responsibility between the institutions of government and the EU is, unlike their voting behaviour, relatively robust to their assessment of the economy. 7.7 Conclusion A recurring pattern has emerged in the preceding chapters, which is that voters’ initial response to the Great Recession was muted, with the strongest effects taking place well after 188 CHAPTER 7. ATTITUDES TOWARDS EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND INSTITUTIONS the initial shock. This pattern suggests that European voters may be responding more to the political reaction to the crisis—the austerity programmes implemented in its wake—than to the recession itself. If this were indeed the case, then there ought to be evidence of a change in voters’ attitudes towards the EU in the years since the recession, since it played a direct role in introducing austerity into four countries and in indirect role in the remaining countries, owing to the Stability Growth Pact, as discussed earlier in the chapter. By testing four hypotheses, this chapter has shown that there was such a change in attitudes. The first of these was that voters who have an optimistic view of the economy are more likely to see both EU membership and further European unification positively. This was supported by the data, with both the membership and integration models showing a positive relationship with prospective economic assessment in all years. This is confirmation of the idea that voters’ attitudes towards the EU are linked to their evaluation of economic conditions. This resembles the economic voting effect, except that it is not the only individual political parties that are being held accountable but the European institutions themselves. The second hypothesis was that this support for the EU fell between 2009 and 2014 and the third hypothesis was that the effect of an optimistic economic assessment became stronger over the same period. Both of these hypotheses were supported by both the membership and integration models. Support for further integration fell between 2009 and 2014, having previously fallen less severely between 2004 and 2009. Support for EU membership actually rose by 2009 before falling again by 2014. The strength of the economic assessment effect in both models fell from 2004 to 2009 before rising again by 2014. The changes between 2009 and 2014 are very different from those between 2004 and 2009. This implies that the changes that took place in the later time period were not merely a continuation of those taking place in the earlier period. This pattern supports the argument that the recession itself cannot entirely explain recent European voter attitudes and behaviour. On the other hand, the economic link in 2014 is even stronger than before and any explanation has to take account of this. These trends are consistent with the idea that the austerity politics of the post-recession period has had a strong impact on voters. The final hypothesis was that the level of responsibility for the economy that voters attributed to the EU was greater in 2014 than in 2009. This was measured in two ways—both in absolute terms and relative to that responsibility attributed to the national government. The data supported the hypothesis under both measures. Although governments were held more responsible than the EU in both years, this gap closed between the two years, owing to 7.7. CONCLUSION 189 an increase in the level of responsibility attributed to the EU in 2014. Unfortunately no data for the relevant questions was available from 2004 so it is not possible to compare with that year as in the other cases. It is interesting to note that prospective economic assessment had little if any impact on the attribution of responsibility in 2014. That is, by that year, optimistic and pessimistic voters were nearly in agreement on the question. Once again, these findings support the argument that there was a shift in attitudes about the economy that took place too late to be attributed purely to the recession. This finding also supports Hobolt and Tilley’s (2014) argument that voters increasingly tend to blame the EU for problems it may not be directly responsible for. This chapter’s findings offer support to the argument that the austerity policies implemented in the immediate aftermath of the Great Recession played a larger role in affecting voters’ political behaviour and attitudes than the mere fact of the recession itself, which is one of the central arguments of the thesis. The following and final chapter summarises the findings of the entire thesis and discusses their implications in general and for economic voting theory in particular. Chapter 8 Conclusion: revising theories of economic voting This thesis has been motivated by two key questions. First, what were voters’ electoral intentions in the wake of the Great Recession and how did these differ from their intentions at other times? Secondly, how much of this response can be attributed to the austerity programmes implemented in the wake of the recession, rather than the economic hardships themselves? In summary, it was found that the economic voting response was depressed during the Great Recession and still had not fully recovered by 2014. Voters’ economic dissatisfaction was also expressed in other observable changes in attitudes and intentions but the most striking of these did not take place until after 2009. By this point, the economies in most of the surveyed countries had recovered from the initial crisis but many of them had also implemented unpopular austerity measures, suggesting that it was the political reaction to the crisis, rather than the economic events themselves, that produced the strongest reaction from voters. These questions were researched by using European Election Studies survey data to construct several models assessing the influence of prospective economic assessment on a voter’s intended electoral behaviour. By contrasting responses from the 2004, 2009 and 2014 survey waves, the thesis was able to compare these relationships at a time before the crisis, a time when the initial recession was at its peak and a time well after the initial recession but when many countries were still struggling with the economic consequences of the situation. In doing so, it was possible to make an argument about how these relationships evolved over the course of the crisis. This thesis models the economic vote by using individuals’ prospective sociotropic assessments of the economy to predict their support for the parties in their country. This means that a voter’s prospective economic perceptions are expected to influence his or her level of support for each party—positively for for government parties and negatively for opposition parties—and it is these levels of support which ultimately determine that individual’s vote choice. Party support is thus used as the dependent variable for the empirical economic voting models discussed in this thesis. 191 192 CHAPTER 8. CONCLUSION A measurable economic vote was observed in all three years. This means that an optimistic economic assessment consistently improved a voter’s support for government parties and reduced a voter’s support for opposition parties, while a pessimistic assessment had the opposite effect. The only clarity of responsibility effect involved the ideological cohesion of the government, that is, the proportion of the government’s members of parliament who are on the same side of the political spectrum as the prime minister. The economic vote tended to be stronger in countries where the government was more ideologically cohesive. Other clarity effects were tested for but not found, nor was there any evidence that the government’s time in office affected the strength of the economic vote. The economy was also found to have an influence on election turnout. This was a withdrawal effect, meaning that those who were pessimistic about the economy were less likely to vote compared to those holding more optimistic views. Finally, support for both EU membership and further European integration was higher among optimistic voters than pessimistic voters in all three years. In summary, people who are optimistic about the economy are more likely to vote and more likely to support the incumbent government as well as the European project, whereas pessimists are less likely to vote, more likely to support opposition parties and more sceptical of the European project. Several changes were observed between 2004 and 2009, during which period the Great Recession began and, in most countries as well as the EU overall, peaked. During this period of economic turmoil, the economic vote actually became weaker, not stronger. The mediating effect of ideological cohesion was suppressed during this time, as was the withdrawal effect on turnout. Support for EU membership and European integration also fell and the link between prospective economic assessment and support for these also weakened. Voters started to prefer parties further from the centre than they previously had. In economic terms, pessimistic voters had tended to prefer left-leaning parties and optimistic voters right-leaning parties but this difference had become much smaller by 2009. In other words, every key link identified between economic perceptions and voter attitudes or intentions became weaker during the Great Recession. The only stronger effect that was identified was the increase in support for parties further from the centre. The most striking changes were found between 2009 and 2014. This period followed the Great Recession, although some countries did experience subsequent periods of recession, and is largely characterised by the European debt crisis. During this time, austerity programmes were implemented in many EU member states. In some countries, these were imposed by the 193 European Troika1 in return for access to bailout funds. Over this period, the economic vote started to recover, although not to its pre-crisis levels. The clarity effect of ideological cohesion was also partly restored. As for turnout, the withdrawal effect became even stronger than it had been in 2004. On the other hand, support for the European project became much weaker and the link between economic perceptions and this support also became stronger than it had been before the crisis. Support increased for parties even further away from the centre than previously and, on the social dimension, there was also an increase in support for traditionalist/authoritarian parties, especially among pessimistic voters. Whereas in previous years all voters had preferred pro-integration parties, by 2014 there was a shift towards anti-integration parties, particularly among pessimistic voters once again. Finally, between 2009 and 2014, voters had become much more likely to regard the EU as responsible for economic issues than they had previously, although still not to the same degree as their national governments. These findings suggest that it was the political response to the crisis, in the form of austerity programmes, rather than the recession itself, that produced the greatest change in voters’ attitudes and intentions. Other explanations were also considered but these do not fit the findings so well. For example, one possibility is that voters wanted to see how the crisis would play out before reacting strongly. There are two problems with this explanation, however. First, this would imply that the twelve months that the EU had been in recession by the time of the 2009 survey wave were not sufficient to produce a full economic voting response, in spite of the evidence that a twelve month window is a good choice for economic voting studies (Hellwig and Marinova 2015). Second, this idea cannot explain the increase in Euroscepticism or the increasing popularity of the view that the EU is responsible for the economy. Similarly, it is unlikely that voters were simply responding more forcefully after 2009 because there were additional waves of recession. This alone could not explain the change in attitudes towards the EU. Yet another possibility is that the increase in Euroscepticism is a coincidence, that is it has an unrelated cause. There must be some link between this Euroscepticism and economic issues, however, since it was predominantly pessimistic voters who became more Eurosceptic after 2009 and 2014 was the first year in which optimistic and pessimistic voters had different attitudes towards Eurosceptic parties. It is difficult to give an account of events that would explain all of these findings and yet allow no role for the politics of austerity. It must be conceded that some key findings of this thesis were foreshadowed elsewhere. In the introduction to their edited volume on politics during the Great Recession, Bermeo and 1 The European Commission, European Central Bank and International Monetary Fund. The role of these institutions in introducing austerity measures was discussed in Section 7.1. 194 CHAPTER 8. CONCLUSION Bartels (2014) commented that: Voters did punish incumbents as predicted; but contrary to expectations, the combustible potential of the Great Recession was realized in only a few of the countries we studied. This observation constitutes the first of our volume’s two major themes: in most countries, popular reactions to the Great Recession were surprisingly muted and moderate. (3, emphasis in original) They went on to state that: Our analysis of these exceptional cases yields the second theme of our project: dramatic political reactions to the Great Recession were associated less with the direct economic repercussions of the crisis than with government initiatives to cope with those repercussions. Radical reactions were less likely to be triggered directly by declining growth or escalating unemployment than by the austerity and bailout programs that policy makers adopted in response to crisis trends. (4, emphasis in original) In other words, the authors also found that the economic voting response to the Great Recession was surprisingly weak and that the strongest reactions appear to have been in response to the austerity programmes implemented after the recession began. Despite not being the first to make these observations, this thesis still makes an important contribution to this literature. Bermeo and Bartels’s comments were based on very different evidence from that here. The individual studies in their book were based on aggregate data and they did not use the EES surveys but various other datasets. This thesis thus corroborates their evidence by showing that similar conclusions can be reached using completely different data and methods. This thesis further contributes to the economic voting literature in several other ways. First, it provides a much-needed multinational account of individual-level behaviour during the Great Recession. Although a number of studies of economic voting behaviour during this period have emerged, they either study a single country or they use only aggregate data. Both of these approaches have their place but they are also limited. Single country studies, while useful for gaining a deep understanding of the situation in those countries, cannot necessarily be generalised to other countries which might have different peculiar circumstances. For example, studies in Sweden (Lindvall, Martinsson and Oscarsson 2013; Martinsson 2013) found a strengthened economic vote during the Great Recession, while studies in Portugal (Freire 195 and Santana-Pereira 2012) and Turkey (Çarkoğlu 2012) found a weakened economic vote. By studying multiple countries together, this thesis has been able to show that it is the latter result which predominates, at least in the EU. Similarly, aggregate studies are useful because aggregate data is often readily available and they offer a means to compare countries but not all changes in individual attitudes are necessarily manifested at the aggregate level. This thesis fills this gap with an analysis that is both multinational and individual-level. Second, this thesis also demonstrates that the novel method for measuring the economic vote proposed by van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin (2007) can be replicated using newer data. Whereas most economic voting studies use logistic regression models to predict the effect of changing economic conditions on party choice, they argued that that economic voting could be more accurately and more reliably measured using party support as a dependent variable. According to them, this has several advantages, such as being more sensitive to shifts in support that might not necessarily be expressed in a change in vote likelihood, a characteristic which makes this method particularly appropriate for multiparty systems such as those prevalent throughout Europe. This thesis has adopted this method, with some key differences, notably the use of multilevel modelling rather than regression with robust standard errors. By showing that this method can be applied to different data yielding similar results, this thesis has contributed further evidence in support of their argument that party support models can correct the instability problems that have plagued party choice models. Third, this thesis has implications for the clarity of responsibility literature. Powell and Whitten (1993) were trying to solve the same problem with their clarity of responsibility theory as van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin (2007) were with their party support model of economic voting, namely the instability problem of economic voting results. Of the many clarity components tested in this thesis, only the ideological cohesion of the government was shown to have any effect on the strength of the economic vote. Since these models are based on the party support theory of economic voting, this supports van der Brug, van der Eijk and Franklin’s argument that model misspecification may account for much of the instability of economic voting results. It also suggests that clarity of responsibility effect may be at least in part an artefact of this misspecification. Given the large extant literature on clarity of responsibility, these results are hardly definitive but it suggests an interesting area for further research. A study could be designed to test whether the existence of an apparent clarity effect depends on whether the economic vote is measured in terms of vote choice or party support. 196 CHAPTER 8. CONCLUSION The current study has also contributed to the turnout literature, particularly that part of the literature examining the idea that, much like the economic voting effect, an individual’s inclination to vote is affected in some way by his or her assessment of the economy. One of the two competing theories is that, in the face of economic misfortune, people are mobilised to vote so that they can show their dissatisfaction. An alternative theory is that people are not mobilised but in fact too concerned with the increasingly difficult task of meeting their daily needs to focus on more abstract concerns like politics and will as a result withdraw from political involvement (Rosenstone 1982, 25–26). One argument for this hypothesis is that mobilisation occurs when the economy is performing especially well or especially poorly, owing to the increased salience of economic issues, and withdrawal occurs otherwise (Martins and Veige 2013). The findings of the current research support the withdrawal argument, although as the withdrawal effect was weakened during the recession, it also offers partial support to the theory that withdrawal is the norm but that mobilisation also occurs during extreme economic conditions. These results also have broader implications for European politics. The finding that voters were relatively cautious about condemning their governments for an international recession originating beyond their borders is presumably good news for politicians, as it suggests that at least some voters will allow them scope to react to events outside of their immediate control. On the other hand, the strong reaction against the austerity programmes introduced after the crisis also suggests that there are limits to the policy measures that their citizens are willing to tolerate, even in response to such a crisis. That voters would object to pension and pay cuts, tax hikes and the loss of government services is not on the face of it surprising but this idea also appears to stand in contrast to traditional accounts of the economic vote, which argue that voters are not concerned with policy instruments, only with outcomes (Fiorina 1981, 8– 9). This is only the case, however, if voters see austerity purely as a policy instrument. It is very likely that an individual facing a cut to his or her own pension sees this as an undesirable policy outcome, rather than a mere instrument. This would explain why economic voting and anti-austerity sentiment can exist side by side. The change in attitudes towards the EU and European integration should be of concern to European politicians, as well as the increased support for Eurosceptic parties. These results show that the consensus in favour of the existing European institutions is under threat. The recent decision by British voters to leave the EU is a visible indicator of this but these results do not suggest that this shift in attitudes is confined to the UK. Furthermore, the large increase in 197 the degree to which voters consider the EU to be responsible for the condition of the economy does not correspond to a new centralisation of economic power at the European level. As Hobolt and Tilley (2014) have observed, the disconnect between the powers of the European institutions and what voters hold them responsible for is creating an accountability deficit. Unless this is addressed, there is no reason to expect support for the status quo to return to its previous levels. There are several limitations in the thesis. One obvious limitation is that the findings are not necessarily generalisable beyond the countries of Europe. These countries are predominantly industrialised parliamentary democracies, so many of the findings are likely to be valid for similar countries like Canada or New Zealand; the situation in countries using a presidential system, like the United States and most of South America, or in less industrialised countries, may be different. It would be interesting to investigate the situation in these other countries but this is made difficult by the lack of comparable survey data collected at the same time. It was the convenient timing of the EES survey data that led to the choice to study Europe in this thesis. Nonetheless, it may be possible to use surveys such as the Comparative Study of Electoral Systems to perform similar comparative research across a different selection of countries. Two limitations arise from the constraints of the surveys used. First, as in any surveybased research, the sample is not perfectly random, the response rates are not as high as would be preferred and there are missing responses. Second, the questions are not always worded identically in each year and sometimes a particular question is not included at all in a particular year’s survey. Even with a single year, there are sometimes variations among the specific national surveys. This is another reason why it would be useful to replicate this study using a different comparative survey project. Although these constraints are to some degree unavoidable, it would increase the confidence in these findings if they were repeated using different data. Finally, an important priority for further research would be to look at voters’ attitudes towards austerity. As has already been discussed, the results of this thesis are highly suggestive that it was the austerity measures rather than the Great Recession itself that produced the greatest change in voters’ attitudes and intentions. However, this was not an a priori hypothesis but rather one that has emerged from the data, being suggested by the pattern in the findings of Chapters 3–6. Indirect evidence was used to test this hypothesis in Chapter 7 and the evidence found supports it but the surveys used in this thesis do not include the questions that would be 198 CHAPTER 8. CONCLUSION needed to test it directly. As a result, it would be valuable to study attitudes towards austerity directly, including the different individual policy measures that are collectively described as austerity measures. Appendix A Countries and parties This appendix lists all of the countries and parties involved in the analysis presented in this thesis. The countries are listed in alphabetical order and under each country heading, the parties for each year are listed in the order that survey respondents were asked about them in the relevant European Election Study (EES) survey. For each party, it is noted whether it has been treated as the prime minister’s party or as another cabinet party at that time. All other parties have been treated as opposition parties. 199 200 APPENDIX A. COUNTRIES AND PARTIES Austria Belgium 2004 2004 Status PM cabinet Party Social Democratic Party of Austria Austrian People’s Party Freedom Party of Austria The Greens—The Green Alternative Communist Party of Austria 2009 Status Party PM cabinet Social Democratic Party of Austria Austrian People’s Party Freedom Party of Austria Alliance for the Future of Austria The Greens—The Green Alternative Hans-Peter Martin’s List Junge Liberale Communist Party of Austria 2014 No party support questions were included in this year’s survey. 2009 Status Party PM cabinet Christian Democratic and Flemish Open Flemish Liberals and Democrats Socialist Party Different Flemish Interest Green New Flemish Alliance List Dedecker Social Liberal Party Workers’ Party of Belgium Humanist Democratic Centre Reformist Movement Socialist Party National Front Environmentalists cabinet cabinet cabinet 2014 Status Party cabinet PM Austrian People’s Party Social Democratic Party of Austria NEOS—The New Austria and Liberal Forum The Greens—The Green Alternative Freedom Party of Austria Alliance for the Future of Austria Status cabinet cabinet cabinet cabinet PM cabinet Party Workers’ Party of Belgium Christian Democratic and Flemish Socialist Party Different Open Flemish Liberals and Democrats New Flemish Alliance Green Flemish Interest Humanist Democratic Centre Socialist Party Reformist Movement Environmentalists People’s Party Workers’ Party of Belgium (Wallonia) 201 Cyprus Czech Republic 2004 2004 Status Party Status Party cabinet Progressive Party of Working People Democratic Rally Democratic Party Movement for Social Democracy PM cabinet Czech Social Democratic Party Christian and Democratic Union— Czechoslovak People’s Party Communist Party of Bohemia and Moravia Civic Democratic Party Green Party PM cabinet 2009 Status Party PM Progressive Party of Working People Democratic Rally Democratic Party Movement for Social Democracy European Party Ecological and Environmental Movement cabinet cabinet 2009 Status cabinet PM cabinet Party Czech Social Democratic Party Christian and Democratic Union— Czechoslovak People’s Party Communist Party of Bohemia and Moravia Civic Democratic Party Green Party 2014 2014 Status Party PM Democratic Rally Democratic Party Movement for Social Democracy Progressive Party of Working People Ecological and Environmental Movement Citizens’ Alliance Status Party cabinet Christian and Democratic Union— Czechoslovak People’s Party Tradition Responsibility Prosperity (TOP 09) Czech Social Democratic Party Civic Democratic Party Communist Party of Bohemia and Moravia National Socialists—21st Century Left ANO 2011 Party of Free Citizens PM cabinet 202 APPENDIX A. COUNTRIES AND PARTIES Denmark Estonia 2004 2004 Status cabinet PM Party Social Democrats Danish Social Liberal Party Conservative People’s Party Socialist People’s Party Danish People’s Party Venstre Status PM cabinet cabinet 2009 Status cabinet PM Party Estonian Centre Party Res Publica Party Estonian Reform Party People’s Union of Estonia Pro Patria Union Social Democratic Party Estonian United People’s Party Estonian Christian Union Estonian Social Democratic Labour Party Party Social Democrats Danish Social Liberal Party Conservative People’s Party Socialist People’s Party Danish People’s Party Venstre Liberal Alliance June Movement People’s Movement against the EU 2009 Status Party PM Estonian Reform Party Estonian Centre Party Pro Patria and Res Publica Union Social Democratic Party Estonian Greens People’s Union of Estonia cabinet 2014 2014 Status Party PM Social Democrats Venstre Socialist People’s Party Danish People’s Party Danish Social Liberal Party Liberal Alliance Conservative People’s Party People’s Movement against the EU cabinet Status cabinet PM Party Pro Patria and Res Publica Union Social Democratic Party Estonian Reform Party Estonian Centre Party Estonian Greens 203 Finland France 2004 2004 Status Party cabinet PM Social Democratic Party of Finland Centre Party National Coalition Party Left Alliance Green League Swedish People’s Party of Finland Christian Democrats True Finns cabinet Status cabinet PM Party Far left (Workers’ Struggle / New Anticapitalist Party) French Communist Party Socialist Party The Greens Union for French Democracy / other right parties Union for a Popular Movement National Front / Gathering for France 2009 Status PM cabinet cabinet cabinet Party Social Democratic Party of Finland Centre Party National Coalition Party Left Alliance Green League Swedish People’s Party of Finland Christian Democrats True Finns 2009 Status PM 2014 Status Party PM cabinet cabinet National Coalition Party Christian Democrats Social Democratic Party of Finland Centre Party Swedish People’s Party of Finland Green League Left Alliance True Finns cabinet cabinet Party Far left (Workers’ Struggle / New Anticapitalist Party) French Communist Party Socialist Party The Greens Democratic Movement Union for a Popular Movement National Front Left Party 2014 Status PM Party Union for a Popular Movement Socialist Party National Front The Greens Left Front Union of Democrats and Independents / Democratic Movement France Arise New Anticapitalist Party 204 APPENDIX A. COUNTRIES AND PARTIES Germany Greece 2004 2004 Status PM cabinet Party Status Party Christian Democratic Union / Christian Social Union Social Democratic Party Alliance 90 / The Greens Party of Democratic Socialism Free Democratic Party The Republicans PM New Democracy Panhellenic Socialist Movement Communist Party of Greece Coalition of Left Popular Orthodox Rally Democratic Social Movement 2009 2009 Status Party PM Christian Democratic Union / Christian Social Union Social Democratic Party Alliance 90 / The Greens The Left Free Democratic Party cabinet Status Party PM New Democracy Panhellenic Socialist Movement Communist Party of Greece Coalition of the Radical Left Popular Orthodox Rally Ecologist Greens 2014 2014 Status Party PM Christian Democratic Union / Christian Social Union Social Democratic Party Free Democratic Party Alliance 90 / The Greens The Left Alternative for Germany Pirate Party cabinet Status Party PM New Democracy Coalition of the Radical Left Panhellenic Socialist Movement Independent Greeks Golden Dawn Democratic Left Communist Party of Greece The River cabinet 205 Hungary Ireland 2004 2004 Status PM cabinet Party Status Party Fidesz—Hungarian Civic Alliance Hungarian Democratic Forum Hungarian Justice and Life Party Hungarian Socialist Party Hungarian Workers’ Party Alliance of Free Democrats PM Fianna Fail Fine Gael Green Party Labour Party Progressive Democrats Sinn Fein 2009 Status PM cabinet 2009 Party Status Party Fidesz—Hungarian Civic Alliance Jobbik Hungarian Communist Workers’ Party Hungarian Democratic Forum Hungarian Socialist Party Alliance of Free Democrats Christian Democratic People’s Party PM Fianna Fail Fine Gael Green Party Labour Party Sinn Fein Libertas cabinet 2014 2014 Status PM Party Jobbik Politics Can Be Different Fidesz / Christian Democratic People’s Party Hungarian Socialist Party Together 2014 / Dialogue for Hungary Democratic Coalition Status Party PM cabinet Fine Gael Labour Party Fianna Fail Green Party Sinn Fein Socialist Party 206 APPENDIX A. COUNTRIES AND PARTIES Italy Latvia 2004 2004 Status PM cabinet cabinet cabinet Party Communist Refoundation Party Democrats of the Left Democracy is Freedom—The Daisy Party of Italian Communists Federation of the Greens Italian Democratic Socialists Union of Democrats for Europe Italy of Values Forza Italia National Alliance Union of the Centre North League New Italian Socialist Party Italian Radicals / Pannella-Bonino List 2009 Status Party PM cabinet The People of Freedom North League Democratic Party Italy of Values Union of the Centre Communist Refoundation Party / Party of Italian Communists Left and Freedom The Right 2014 Status Party PM Democratic Party Forza Italia North League Five Star Movement Union of the Centre The Other Europe New Centre-Right Brothers of Italy cabinet cabinet Status cabinet PM cabinet Party New Era Party For Human Rights in a United Latvia People’s Party Union of Greens and Farmers Latvia’s First party For Fatherland and Freedom Latvian Way 2009 Status Party cabinet cabinet PM People’s Party Union of Greens and Farmers New Era Party Harmony Centre Latvia’s First Party / Latvian Way For Fatherland and Freedom For Human Rights in a United Latvia Civic Union Society for Other Politics cabinet cabinet 2014 Status Party PM Unity Harmony National Alliance Union of Greens and Farmers Reform Party Latvian Russian Union cabinet cabinet cabinet 207 Lithuania Luxembourg 2004 2004 No party support questions were included in No party support questions were included in this year’s survey. this year’s survey. 2009 2009 Status Party PM Homeland Union—Lithuanian Christian Democrats Social Democratic Party of Lithuania National Resurrection Party Order and Justice Liberal Movement Labour Party Liberal and Centre Union Election Action of Poles in Lithuania Lithuanian Popular Peasants’ Union New Union (Social Liberals) cabinet cabinet cabinet Status cabinet PM 2014 cabinet PM cabinet cabinet cabinet Party Homeland Union—Lithuanian Christian Democrats Social Democratic Party of Lithuania Liberal Movement Labour Party Order and Justice Election Action of Poles in Lithuania Lithuanian Popular Peasants’ Union The Greens Luxembourg Socialist Workers’ Party Democratic Party Christian Social People’s Party Alternative Democratic Reform Party The Left Communist Party of Luxembourg Citizens’ List 2014 Status Status Party PM cabinet Party Christian Social People’s Party Luxembourg Socialist Workers’ Party Democratic Party The Greens The Left Alternative Democratic Reform Party 208 APPENDIX A. COUNTRIES AND PARTIES Malta The Netherlands 2004 2004 No party support questions were included in Status this year’s survey. PM cabinet 2009 cabinet Status Party PM Nationalist Party Labour Party Democratic Alternative National Action Party Labour Party Christian Democratic Appeal People’s Party for Freedom and Democracy Democrats 66 GreenLeft Pim Fortuyn List ChristianUnion Reformed Political Party Socialist Party 2009 2014 Status Party PM Labour Party Nationalist Party Democratic Alternative Status Party cabinet PM Labour Party Christian Democratic Appeal People’s Party for Freedom and Democracy Democrats 66 GreenLeft Party for the Animals ChristianUnion Reformed Political Party Socialist Party Party for Freedom Proud of the Netherlands cabinet 2014 Status Party PM People’s Party for Freedom and Democracy Labour Party Party for Freedom Socialist Party Christian Democratic Appeal Democrats 66 ChristianUnion GreenLeft cabinet 209 Poland Portugal 2004 2004 Status cabinet cabinet PM cabinet Party League of Polish Families Polish People’s Party Law and Justice Civic Platform Self-Defence of the Republic of Poland Social Democracy of Poland Democratic Left Alliance Labour United Freedom Union cabinet PM Status Party cabinet Polish People’s Party Libertas Poland Coalition Agreement for the Future Democratic Left Alliance Civic Platform Law and Justice 2014 Status Party PM cabinet Civic Platform Polish People’s Party Democratic Left Alliance Law and Justice Your Movement Congress of the New Right United Poland Party Left Bloc Democratic and Social Centre— People’s Party Democratic Unitarian Coalition New Democracy Party Socialist Party Social Democratic Party 2009 Status 2009 PM Status PM Party Left Bloc Democratic and Social Centre— People’s Party Democratic Unitarian Coalition Socialist Party Social Democratic Party 2014 Status Party PM cabinet Social Democratic Party Democratic and Social Centre— People’s Party Socialist Party Democratic Unitarian Coalition Left Bloc Earth Party 210 APPENDIX A. COUNTRIES AND PARTIES Slovakia Slovenia 2004 2004 Status PM cabinet cabinet cabinet Party Status Party People’s Party—Movement for a Democratic Slovakia Direction—Social Democracy Communist Party of Slovakia Slovak Democratic and Christian Union Party of the Hungarian Coalition Christian Democratic Movement Alliance of the New Citizen Slovak National Party cabinet Democratic Party of Pensioners of Slovenia Liberal Democracy of Slovenia New Slovenia—Christian People’s Party Slovenian People’s Party Youth Party of Slovenia Slovenian National Party Slovenian Democratic Party United List of Social Democrats Slovenia is Ours PM cabinet 2009 2009 Status Party cabinet People’s Party—Movement for a Democratic Slovakia Direction—Social Democracy Slovak Democratic and Christian Union—Democratic Party Party of the Hungarian Coalition Christian Democratic Movement Slovak National Party Communist Party of Slovakia Free Forum PM cabinet Status Party cabinet Democratic Party of Pensioners of Slovenia Liberal Democracy of Slovenia Slovenian People’s Party Slovenian National Party Slovenian Democratic Party Social Democrats Zares—New Politics New Slovenia—Christian People’s Party Youth Party of Slovenia cabinet PM cabinet 2014 Status Party PM Christian Democratic Movement Slovak Democratic and Christian Union—Democratic Party Party of the Hungarian Coalition Direction—Social Democracy New Majority Freedom and Solidarity Ordinary People Most-Híd 2014 Status Party PM Positive Slovenia Slovenian Democratic Party Social Democrats Civic List Democratic Party of Pensioners of Slovenia New Slovenia—Christian People’s Party Liberal Democracy of Slovenia Slovenian People’s Party cabinet cabinet cabinet 211 Spain Sweden 2004 2004 Status Party PM People’s Party / Navarrese People’s Union Spanish Socialist Workers’ Party United Left / Initiative for Catalonia Greens Status PM 2009 Status PM Party People’s Party Spanish Socialist Workers’ Party United Left / Initiative for Catalonia Greens Union Convergence and Union Republican Left of Catalonia Basque National Party Galician Nationalist Bloc Canarian Coalition / Canarian Nationalist Party Yes to Navarre Basque Solidarity Navarrese People’s Union Party Left Party Swedish Social Democratic Party Centre Party Liberal People’s Party Moderate Party Christian Democrats Green Party June List 2009 Status cabinet cabinet PM cabinet Party Left Party Swedish Social Democratic Party Centre Party Liberal People’s Party Moderate Party Christian Democrats Green Party Swedish Democrats Pirate Party 2014 2014 Status Status Party PM People’s Party Spanish Socialist Workers’ Party United Left / Initiative for Catalonia Greens Union Coalition for Europe Republican Left of Catalonia Citizens—Party of the Citizenry Podemos PM cabinet cabinet cabinet Party Swedish Social Democratic Party Moderate Party Green Party Liberal People’s Party Centre Party Swedish Democrats Christian Democrats Left Party 212 APPENDIX A. COUNTRIES AND PARTIES United Kingdom 2004 Status Party PM Labour Conservatives Liberal Democrats UK Independence Party Scottish National Party Plaid Cymru 2009 Status Party PM Labour Conservatives Liberal Democrats Scottish National Party Plaid Cymru UK Independence Party British National Party Green Party 2014 Status Party PM Conservatives Labour Liberal Democrats Green Party UK Independence Party Scottish National Party Plaid Cymru cabinet Appendix B Coefficient tables Model 3A. Economic voting for PMs’ parties Fixed effect Coeff. Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Left–right distance Left–right distance2 Party ID Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Distance × party ID Age × party ID Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 0.067 0.490 0.159 −0.428 0.023 4.706 0.323 0.054 −0.007 0.084 0.028 −0.018 0.065 −0.083 0.052 0.280 0.179 −0.051 −0.038 Country random effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Left–right distance Party ID Prospective assessment Distance × party ID Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 SE p (0.095) (0.183) (0.130) (0.019) (0.001) (0.129) (0.053) (0.021) (0.008) (0.025) (0.031) (0.026) (0.027) (0.043) (0.025) (0.029) (0.015) (0.048) (0.065) Var. 0.184 0.773 0.359 0.008 0.375 0.055 0.015 0.036 0.076 0.492 0.014 0.235 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.011 0.353 0.001 0.357 0.495 0.016 0.055 0.038 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.310 0.565 SD (0.429) (0.879) (0.599) (0.091) (0.612) (0.235) (0.123) (0.189) (0.275) Dependent variable is support for the prime minister’s party. Sample size is 51962 individuals within 25 countries. Pseudo R2 is 0.541. 213 214 APPENDIX B. COEFFICIENT TABLES Model 3B. Economic voting for all parties, no incumbency status Fixed effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Left–right distance Left–right distance2 Party ID Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Distance × party ID Age × party ID Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 Coeff. −0.195 0.137 0.160 −0.345 0.021 5.192 −0.034 0.021 −0.003 0.009 0.013 0.017 0.020 0.002 0.000 0.212 0.131 0.015 0.002 Party random effect Intercept Left–right distance Party ID Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Distance × party ID SE p (0.052) (0.063) (0.064) (0.006) (0.000) (0.051) (0.023) (0.011) (0.005) (0.015) (0.016) (0.014) (0.014) (0.018) (0.011) (0.013) (0.008) (0.030) (0.031) Var. 0.555 0.018 0.936 0.065 0.034 0.010 0.065 0.052 0.043 0.044 0.035 0.020 0.037 < 0.001 0.030 0.013 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.135 0.059 0.586 0.555 0.413 0.207 0.146 0.890 0.989 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.615 0.953 SD (0.745) (0.135) (0.968) (0.255) (0.185) (0.100) (0.255) (0.228) (0.208) (0.210) (0.187) (0.142) (0.192) Dependent variable is individual’s support for party. Sample size is 352050 measurements within 497 parties. Pseudo R2 is 0.508. 215 Model 3C. Economic voting for all parties, 2-way incumbency status Fixed effect Coeff. Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Cabinet party Left–right distance Left–right distance2 Party ID Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Distance × party ID Age × party ID Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 Cabinet × year 2009 Cabinet × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × cabinet Prosp. assess. × cabinet × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × cabinet × year 2014 Party random effect Intercept Left–right distance Party ID Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Distance × party ID Country random effect Intercept Prosp. assess. × cabinet SE −0.209 0.129 0.153 0.043 −0.345 0.021 5.186 −0.036 0.021 −0.003 0.009 0.014 0.017 0.020 0.002 0.000 0.213 0.130 0.031 0.007 0.167 0.052 0.431 −0.136 −0.125 (0.065) (0.062) (0.063) (0.094) (0.006) (0.000) (0.051) (0.017) (0.011) (0.005) (0.015) (0.016) (0.014) (0.014) (0.018) (0.011) (0.013) (0.008) (0.023) (0.024) (0.125) (0.127) (0.050) (0.049) (0.051) Var. 0.560 0.018 0.920 0.033 0.034 0.010 0.065 0.053 0.043 0.044 0.035 0.020 0.037 0.002 0.038 0.015 0.646 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.038 0.061 0.591 0.538 0.372 0.209 0.144 0.909 0.984 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.173 0.775 0.185 0.685 < 0.001 0.006 0.014 SD (0.749) (0.135) (0.959) (0.183) (0.185) (0.101) (0.256) (0.230) (0.208) (0.210) (0.187) (0.142) (0.192) Var. 0.037 0.028 p SD (0.193) (0.167) Dependent variable is individual’s support for party. Sample size is 352050 measurements within 497 parties within 25 countries. Pseudo R2 is 0.508. 216 APPENDIX B. COEFFICIENT TABLES Model 3D. Economic voting for all parties, 3-way incumbency status Fixed effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Cabinet party Prime minister’s party Left–right distance Left–right distance2 Party ID Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Distance × party ID Age × party ID Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 Cabinet × year 2009 Cabinet × year 2014 PM × year 2009 PM × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × cabinet Prosp. assess. × PM Prosp. assess. × cabinet × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × cabinet × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × PM × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × PM × year 2014 Coeff. −0.207 0.125 0.151 0.116 −0.164 −0.345 0.021 5.187 −0.034 0.021 −0.003 0.009 0.014 0.017 0.020 0.002 0.000 0.214 0.130 0.027 0.004 −0.036 −0.042 0.433 0.201 0.384 0.108 −0.161 −0.157 0.044 0.065 SE (0.066) (0.062) (0.063) (0.116) (0.148) (0.006) (0.000) (0.051) (0.017) (0.011) (0.005) (0.015) (0.016) (0.014) (0.014) (0.018) (0.011) (0.013) (0.008) (0.022) (0.023) (0.156) (0.158) (0.200) (0.202) (0.054) (0.058) (0.059) (0.061) (0.078) (0.080) p 0.003 0.044 0.016 0.320 0.269 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.044 0.062 0.591 0.535 0.372 0.207 0.144 0.911 0.982 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.223 0.872 0.816 0.789 0.031 0.321 < 0.001 0.061 0.007 0.010 0.569 0.416 217 Party random effect Intercept Left–right distance Party ID Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Distance × party ID Var. 0.560 0.018 0.921 0.032 0.034 0.010 0.065 0.053 0.043 0.044 0.035 0.020 0.037 Country random effect Intercept Prosp. assess. × cabinet Prosp. assess. × PM Var. 0.038 0.022 0.000 SD (0.748) (0.135) (0.959) (0.180) (0.184) (0.101) (0.256) (0.229) (0.208) (0.210) (0.187) (0.142) (0.192) SD (0.195) (0.150) (0.009) Dependent variable is individual’s support for party. Note that as prime ministers’ parties are also cabinet parties, the prime minister’s party term should be interpreted relative to other cabinet parties rather than opposition parties. Sample size is 352050 measurements within 497 parties within 25 countries. Pseudo R2 is 0.508. 218 APPENDIX B. COEFFICIENT TABLES Model 3E. Mean party preference Fixed effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 Coeff. 3.594 −0.346 −0.434 0.129 0.096 −0.089 0.035 0.003 −0.016 0.006 −0.042 0.028 −0.052 0.070 Country random effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Prospective assessment Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 SE p (0.110) (0.146) (0.121) (0.025) (0.013) (0.004) (0.015) (0.018) (0.016) (0.016) (0.025) (0.015) (0.022) (0.034) Var. 0.262 0.482 0.316 0.011 0.004 0.020 < 0.001 0.029 0.003 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.021 0.875 0.323 0.694 0.095 0.063 0.027 0.050 SD (0.511) (0.694) (0.562) (0.103) (0.066) (0.140) Dependent variable is the individual’s mean party preference. Sample size is 63286 individuals within 25 countries. Pseudo R2 is 0.116. 219 Model 4A. Clarity of responsibility (PMs’ parties) Fixed effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Left–right distance Left–right distance2 Party ID Prospective assessment Time in office (PM) Government clarity Institutional clarity Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Distance × party ID Age × party ID Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × time in office Prosp. assess. × govt clarity Prosp. assess. × inst. clarity Coeff. 0.543 0.329 0.039 −0.438 0.023 4.680 0.131 0.024 −0.893 0.054 0.047 −0.005 0.087 0.035 −0.018 0.068 −0.077 0.056 0.266 0.178 −0.083 −0.066 0.005 0.186 0.144 Country random effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Party ID Prospective assessment Var. 0.195 0.631 0.353 0.313 0.025 SE (0.244) (0.173) (0.133) (0.005) (0.001) (0.118) (0.091) (0.016) (0.290) (0.261) (0.021) (0.008) (0.025) (0.031) (0.026) (0.027) (0.044) (0.025) (0.015) (0.016) (0.029) (0.031) (0.004) (0.089) (0.121) p 0.033 0.071 0.773 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.161 0.130 0.004 0.837 0.027 0.525 0.001 0.260 0.503 0.012 0.079 0.028 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.004 0.033 0.168 0.037 0.245 SD (0.442) (0.795) (0.594) (0.559) (0.159) Dependent variable is support for the prime minister’s party. Sample size is 51962 individuals within 25 countries. Pseudo R2 is 0.534. 220 APPENDIX B. COEFFICIENT TABLES Model 4B. Components of government clarity (PMs’ parties) Fixed effect Coeff. Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Left–right distance Left–right distance2 Party ID Prospective assessment Time in office (PM) Single-party government Absence of cohabitation Ideological cohesion Dominance of main party Institutional clarity Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Distance × party ID Age × party ID Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × time in office Prosp. assess. × single party Prosp. assess. × no cohabitation Prosp. assess. × cohesion Prosp. assess. × dominance Prosp. assess. × inst. clarity 1.917 0.311 −0.056 −0.437 0.023 4.674 −0.131 0.006 0.213 −0.267 −1.580 −0.142 −0.146 0.047 −0.005 0.086 0.034 −0.018 0.067 −0.078 0.056 0.266 0.178 −0.071 −0.037 0.007 −0.053 −0.026 0.388 0.035 0.190 Country random effect Var. Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Party ID Prospective assessment 0.175 0.750 0.387 0.312 0.024 SE (0.414) (0.186) (0.140) (0.005) (0.001) (0.118) (0.137) (0.015) (0.193) (0.213) (0.323) (0.336) (0.257) (0.021) (0.008) (0.025) (0.031) (0.026) (0.027) (0.044) (0.025) (0.015) (0.016) (0.030) (0.032) (0.004) (0.061) (0.068) (0.086) (0.113) (0.117) p < 0.001 0.110 0.696 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.343 0.690 0.283 0.237 < 0.001 0.675 0.576 0.028 0.502 0.001 0.267 0.501 0.013 0.073 0.027 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.016 0.250 0.069 0.381 0.696 < 0.001 0.757 0.120 SD (0.418) (0.866) (0.622) (0.558) (0.155) Dependent variable is support for the prime minister’s party. Sample size is 51962 individuals within 25 countries. Pseudo R2 is 0.534. 221 Model 4C. Ideological cohesion (PMs’ parties) Fixed effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Left–right distance Left–right distance2 Party ID Prospective assessment Time in office (PM) Ideological cohesion Institutional clarity Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Distance × party ID Age × party ID Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × time in office Prosp. assess. × cohesion Prosp. assess. × inst. clarity Coeff. 1.395 0.339 −0.061 −0.437 0.023 4.676 −0.109 0.008 −1.391 −0.080 0.047 −0.005 0.087 0.036 −0.018 0.067 −0.077 0.056 0.266 0.178 −0.071 −0.034 0.007 0.375 0.152 Country random effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Party ID Prospective assessment Var. 0.160 0.674 0.354 0.311 0.023 SE (0.315) (0.175) (0.135) (0.005) (0.001) (0.118) (0.103) (0.014) (0.297) (0.235) (0.021) (0.008) (0.025) (0.031) (0.026) (0.027) (0.044) (0.025) (0.015) (0.016) (0.028) (0.032) (0.004) (0.082) (0.114) p < 0.001 0.065 0.654 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.295 0.559 < 0.001 0.738 0.028 0.498 0.001 0.245 0.504 0.013 0.076 0.027 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.012 0.284 0.069 < 0.001 0.195 SD (0.400) (0.821) (0.595) (0.558) (0.152) Dependent variable is support for the prime minister’s party. Sample size is 51962 individuals within 25 countries. Pseudo R2 is 0.534. 222 APPENDIX B. COEFFICIENT TABLES Model 4D. Ideological cohesion over time (PMs’ parties) Fixed effect Coeff. Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Left–right distance Left–right distance2 Party ID Prospective assessment Time in office (PM) Ideological cohesion Institutional clarity Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Distance × party ID Age × party ID Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 Time in office × year 2009 Time in office × year 2014 Cohesion × year 2009 Cohesion × year 2014 Inst. clarity × year 2009 Inst. clarity × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × time in office Prosp. assess. × cohesion Prosp. assess. × inst. clarity Prosp. assess. × time in office × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × time in office × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × cohesion × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × cohesion × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × inst. clarity × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × inst. clarity × year 2014 Country random effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Party ID Prospective assessment 1.702 0.367 −0.777 −0.437 0.023 4.674 −0.447 −0.034 −1.288 −0.531 0.046 −0.005 0.087 0.036 −0.018 0.066 −0.079 0.055 0.266 0.178 0.502 −0.136 0.041 0.078 −0.685 −0.033 0.704 0.825 0.019 0.824 −0.061 −0.016 0.030 −0.681 −0.340 0.189 0.568 Var. 0.161 0.745 0.396 0.314 0.028 SE (0.637) (0.871) (0.764) (0.005) (0.001) (0.119) (0.220) (0.031) (0.613) (0.401) (0.021) (0.008) (0.025) (0.031) (0.026) (0.027) (0.044) (0.025) (0.015) (0.016) (0.225) (0.228) (0.040) (0.048) (0.875) (0.716) (0.825) (0.557) (0.010) (0.205) (0.154) (0.011) (0.015) (0.238) (0.220) (0.142) (0.136) p 0.016 0.676 0.318 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.043 0.293 0.053 0.201 0.031 0.485 0.001 0.244 0.488 0.015 0.071 0.030 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.026 0.549 0.309 0.112 0.440 0.964 0.402 0.154 0.059 < 0.001 0.695 0.132 0.036 0.004 0.123 0.183 < 0.001 SD (0.402) (0.863) (0.630) (0.560) (0.166) Dependent variable is support for the prime minister’s party. Sample size is 51962 individuals within 25 countries. Pseudo R2 is 0.534. 223 Model 4E. Ideological cohesion over time (all parties) Fixed effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Cabinet party Prime minister’s party Left–right distance Left–right distance2 Party ID Prospective assessment Time in office (cabinet) Ideological cohesion Institutional clarity Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Distance × party ID Age × party ID Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 Cabinet × year 2009 Cabinet × year 2014 Time in office × year 2009 Time in office × year 2014 Cohesion × year 2009 Cohesion × year 2014 Inst. clarity × year 2009 Inst. clarity × year 2014 Cohesion × cabinet Inst. clarity × cabinet Prosp. assess. × cabinet Prosp. assess. × PM Prosp. assess. × time in office Prosp. assess. × cohesion Prosp. assess. × inst. clarity Prosp. assess. × cabinet × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × cabinet × year 2014 Cohesion × cabinet × year 2009 Cohesion × cabinet × year 2014 Inst. clarity × cabinet × year 2009 Inst. clarity × cabinet × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × cohesion × cabinet Prosp. assess. × inst. clarity × cabinet Prosp. assess. × time in office × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × time in office × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × cohesion × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × cohesion × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × inst. clarity × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × inst. clarity × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × cohesion × cabinet × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × cohesion × cabinet × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × inst. clarity × cabinet × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × inst. clarity × cabinet × year 2014 Coeff. 1.062 −1.336 −0.751 −0.178 0.098 −0.345 0.021 5.188 −0.083 −0.018 −1.077 −0.398 0.021 −0.003 0.009 0.014 0.017 0.021 0.001 0.000 0.214 0.130 0.071 −0.001 0.963 1.022 0.012 −0.001 1.294 0.844 0.430 0.119 0.207 0.061 −0.369 0.154 −0.003 0.021 0.058 0.430 0.096 −1.176 −0.890 0.357 −0.411 1.031 −0.358 0.000 0.012 −0.014 0.036 −0.059 −0.068 −0.924 −0.555 0.488 0.544 SE (0.436) (0.474) (0.463) (0.771) (0.083) (0.006) (0.000) (0.051) (0.145) (0.017) (0.424) (0.265) (0.011) (0.005) (0.015) (0.016) (0.013) (0.014) (0.018) (0.011) (0.013) (0.008) (0.162) (0.164) (0.863) (0.860) (0.020) (0.020) (0.500) (0.459) (0.286) (0.281) (0.752) (0.419) (0.302) (0.033) (0.007) (0.143) (0.078) (0.339) (0.340) (0.889) (0.852) (0.563) (0.555) (0.296) (0.161) (0.008) (0.008) (0.167) (0.163) (0.103) (0.107) (0.351) (0.338) (0.219) (0.220) p 0.016 0.005 0.106 0.817 0.242 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.569 0.293 0.011 0.140 0.062 0.588 0.540 0.375 0.204 0.139 0.940 0.975 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.662 0.996 0.265 0.235 0.534 0.947 0.010 0.067 0.133 0.672 0.783 0.884 0.223 < 0.001 0.623 0.886 0.453 0.205 0.778 0.186 0.297 0.526 0.459 0.001 0.027 0.950 0.132 0.934 0.824 0.568 0.523 0.009 0.102 0.026 0.014 224 APPENDIX B. COEFFICIENT TABLES Party random effect Intercept Left–right distance Party ID Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Distance × party ID Var. 0.556 0.018 0.926 0.035 0.034 0.010 0.065 0.053 0.043 0.044 0.035 0.020 0.037 Country random effect Intercept Var. 0.034 SD (0.746) (0.135) (0.962) (0.187) (0.185) (0.101) (0.256) (0.230) (0.207) (0.210) (0.188) (0.142) (0.191) SD (0.185) Dependent variable is individual’s support for party. Sample size is 352050 individuals within 497 parties within 25 countries. Pseudo R2 is 0.508. 225 Model 5A. Party’s European integration position Fixed effect Coeff. Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Cabinet party Prime minister’s party Party European integration position Left–right distance Left–right distance2 Party ID Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Distance × party ID Age × party ID Props. assess. × year 2009 Props. assess. × year 2014 Cabinet × year 2009 Cabinet × year 2014 Integration pos. × year 2009 Integration pos. × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × cabinet Prosp. assess. × PM Prosp. assess. × integration pos. Prosp. assess. × cabinet × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × cabinet × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × integration pos. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × integration pos. × year 2014 Party random effect Intercept Left–right distance Party ID Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Country random effect Party European integration position −0.100 0.107 0.101 −0.172 0.040 0.183 −0.354 0.022 5.222 −0.026 0.026 −0.003 0.021 0.009 0.010 0.013 −0.004 0.001 0.287 0.132 0.009 −0.014 0.244 0.266 −0.058 −0.161 0.381 0.136 0.017 −0.191 −0.217 −0.002 0.045 Var. 0.391 0.020 1.066 0.036 0.037 0.011 0.065 0.054 0.043 0.047 0.035 0.020 Var. 0.005 SE (0.050) (0.064) (0.064) (0.112) (0.090) (0.034) (0.007) (0.001) (0.056) (0.018) (0.012) (0.006) (0.016) (0.017) (0.014) (0.015) (0.019) (0.012) (0.008) (0.008) (0.025) (0.026) (0.145) (0.147) (0.043) (0.041) (0.044) (0.036) (0.012) (0.057) (0.058) (0.016) (0.016) p 0.046 0.094 0.117 0.125 0.658 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.155 0.036 0.614 0.184 0.581 0.475 0.376 0.832 0.910 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.708 0.576 0.093 0.072 0.174 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.140 0.001 < 0.001 0.918 0.006 SD (0.626) (0.141) (1.033) (0.189) (0.193) (0.103) (0.255) (0.233) (0.208) (0.217) (0.187) (0.143) SD (0.067) Dependent variable is individual’s support for party. Sample size is 314782 individuals within 428 parties within 22 countries. Pseudo R2 is 0.504. 226 APPENDIX B. COEFFICIENT TABLES Model 5B. Party’s left–right position Fixed effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Cabinet party Prime minister’s party Party left–right position Party left–right position2 Left–right distance Left–right distance2 Party ID Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Distance × party ID Age × party ID Props. assess. × year 2009 Props. assess. × year 2014 Cabinet × year 2009 Cabinet × year 2014 Left–right pos. × year 2009 Left–right pos. × year 2014 Left–right pos.2 × year 2009 Left–right pos.2 × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × cabinet Prosp. assess. × PM Prosp. assess. × left–right position Prosp. assess. × left–right position2 Prosp. assess. × cabinet × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × cabinet × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × left–right pos. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × left–right pos. × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × left–right pos.2 × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × left–right pos.2 × year 2014 Coeff. 0.094 0.106 −0.091 −0.056 0.026 −0.021 −0.037 −0.354 0.022 5.228 0.005 0.026 −0.003 0.021 0.009 0.010 0.014 −0.004 0.002 0.287 0.131 −0.007 0.008 0.192 0.200 −0.012 0.010 0.003 0.039 0.346 0.142 0.032 −0.006 −0.155 −0.129 −0.031 −0.030 0.004 −0.003 SE (0.070) (0.093) (0.095) (0.114) (0.092) (0.022) (0.009) (0.007) (0.001) (0.056) (0.026) (0.012) (0.006) (0.016) (0.017) (0.014) (0.015) (0.019) (0.012) (0.008) (0.008) (0.036) (0.037) (0.147) (0.147) (0.029) (0.029) (0.012) (0.012) (0.044) (0.036) (0.008) (0.004) (0.057) (0.058) (0.011) (0.011) (0.005) (0.005) p 0.180 0.256 0.337 0.627 0.774 0.335 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.847 0.035 0.608 0.187 0.590 0.471 0.371 0.825 0.899 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.837 0.839 0.192 0.175 0.683 0.739 0.793 0.002 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.069 0.007 0.026 0.005 0.007 0.400 0.509 227 Party random effect Intercept Left–right distance Party ID Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Var. 0.423 0.020 1.057 0.036 0.037 0.011 0.065 0.054 0.043 0.047 0.035 0.020 SD (0.650) (0.141) (1.028) (0.191) (0.192) (0.103) (0.256) (0.233) (0.208) (0.217) (0.187) (0.143) Dependent variable is individual’s support for party. Sample size is 314782 individuals within 428 parties. Pseudo R2 is 0.504. 228 APPENDIX B. COEFFICIENT TABLES Model 5C. Party’s social and economic positions Fixed effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Cabinet party Prime minister’s party Party economic position Party economic position2 Party social position Party social position2 Left–right distance Left–right distance2 Party ID Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Distance × party ID Age × party ID Props. assess. × year 2009 Props. assess. × year 2014 Cabinet × year 2009 Cabinet × year 2014 Economic pos. × year 2009 Economic pos. × year 2014 Economic pos.2 × year 2009 Economic pos.2 × year 2014 Social pos. × year 2009 Social pos. × year 2014 Social pos.2 × year 2009 Social pos.2 × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × cabinet Prosp. assess. × PM Prosp. assess. × economic position Prosp. assess. × economic position2 Prosp. assess. × social position Prosp. assess. × social position2 Prosp. assess. × cabinet × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × cabinet × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × economic pos. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × economic pos. × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × economic pos.2 × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × economic pos.2 × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × social pos. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × social pos. × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × social pos.2 × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × social pos.2 × year 2014 Coeff. 0.139 0.073 −0.093 −0.031 0.027 0.008 −0.024 −0.042 −0.019 −0.354 0.022 5.227 −0.067 0.026 −0.003 0.021 0.009 0.010 0.014 −0.004 0.001 0.287 0.132 0.042 0.055 0.193 0.176 −0.018 −0.033 −0.008 0.027 −0.007 0.048 0.011 0.012 0.312 0.161 0.060 0.002 −0.016 0.005 −0.133 −0.100 −0.029 −0.033 0.000 −0.007 −0.007 −0.012 −0.005 −0.007 SE (0.090) (0.120) (0.124) (0.119) (0.094) (0.025) (0.010) (0.021) (0.009) (0.007) (0.001) (0.056) (0.032) (0.012) (0.006) (0.016) (0.017) (0.014) (0.015) (0.019) (0.012) (0.008) (0.008) (0.043) (0.046) (0.153) (0.151) (0.034) (0.033) (0.014) (0.013) (0.029) (0.029) (0.011) (0.012) (0.043) (0.035) (0.009) (0.004) (0.008) (0.003) (0.055) (0.056) (0.012) (0.012) (0.005) (0.005) (0.010) (0.010) (0.004) (0.004) p 0.125 0.543 0.454 0.796 0.774 0.744 0.020 0.050 0.031 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.038 0.035 0.603 0.184 0.590 0.470 0.371 0.833 0.909 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.331 0.235 0.207 0.244 0.597 0.324 0.573 0.046 0.797 0.093 0.325 0.316 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.681 0.032 0.073 0.016 0.074 0.019 0.008 0.998 0.185 0.533 0.244 0.210 0.099 229 Party random effect Intercept Left–right distance Party ID Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Var. 0.420 0.020 1.059 0.032 0.037 0.011 0.065 0.054 0.043 0.047 0.035 0.020 SD (0.648) (0.141) (1.029) (0.179) (0.192) (0.103) (0.255) (0.233) (0.207) (0.217) (0.187) (0.143) Dependent variable is individual’s support for party. Sample size is 314782 individuals within 428 parties. Pseudo R2 is 0.504. 230 APPENDIX B. COEFFICIENT TABLES Model 6A. Turnout intention Fixed effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Government identifier Opposition identifier Prospective assessment Voted last time Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Government ID × year 2009 Government ID × year 2014 Opposition ID × year 2009 Opposition ID × year 2014 Age × government ID Age × opposition ID Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 Voted last time × year 2009 Voted last time × year 2014 Coeff. 0.314 −0.094 −0.063 0.245 0.287 0.015 0.358 −0.017 −0.020 0.003 0.014 0.003 −0.002 0.003 0.028 0.071 0.046 0.068 0.030 0.010 0.006 −0.007 0.010 −0.007 0.041 Country random effect Var. Intercept Government identifier Opposition identifier 0.006 0.006 0.005 SE (0.017) (0.008) (0.007) (0.017) (0.016) (0.003) (0.006) (0.003) (0.001) (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.006) (0.004) (0.010) (0.010) (0.009) (0.009) (0.002) (0.002) (0.004) (0.004) (0.009) (0.009) p < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.451 0.001 0.362 0.581 0.659 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.001 < 0.001 0.002 0.053 0.012 0.435 < 0.001 SD (0.076) (0.074) (0.070) This is a multilevel logistic regression model. The dependent variable is one for individuals who indicated an intention to vote and zero for individuals who indicated they would not vote as well as individuals who refused to answer the question. Sample size is 63483 individuals within 22 countries. Pseudo R2 is 0.361. 231 Model 7A. Desirability of continued European unification Fixed effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Left–right position Left–right position2 Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 Left–right pos. × year 2009 Left–right pos. × year 2014 Left–right pos.2 × year 2009 Left–right pos.2 × year 2014 Age × year 2009 Age × year 2014 Female × year 2009 Female × year 2014 Low education × year 2009 Low education × year 2014 High education × year 2009 High education × year 2014 Rural area × year 2009 Rural area × year 2014 Urban area × year 2009 Urban area × year 2014 Unemployed × year 2009 Unemployed × year 2014 Not in workforce × year 2009 Not in workforce × year 2014 Coeff. 5.506 −0.381 −1.082 0.372 −0.206 −0.060 0.369 −0.355 0.206 −0.106 0.088 0.162 0.020 0.004 −0.145 0.101 −0.013 −0.048 0.004 −0.005 −0.011 −0.016 0.079 0.069 0.199 0.145 0.071 0.053 0.002 0.305 −0.188 −0.168 −0.170 −0.182 −0.022 −0.137 Country random effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Prospective assessment Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 SE p (0.173) (0.126) (0.131) (0.056) (0.044) (0.016) (0.052) (0.062) (0.054) (0.053) (0.096) (0.053) (0.009) (0.003) (0.047) (0.072) (0.012) (0.012) (0.004) (0.004) (0.021) (0.021) (0.061) (0.061) (0.087) (0.090) (0.073) (0.071) (0.076) (0.077) (0.075) (0.075) (0.131) (0.124) (0.072) (0.073) Var. 0.688 0.306 0.336 0.061 0.028 0.094 < 0.001 0.006 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.046 0.362 0.002 0.025 0.107 0.007 0.179 0.281 < 0.001 0.272 0.169 0.586 0.437 0.191 0.256 0.022 0.107 0.325 0.460 0.980 < 0.001 0.013 0.025 0.194 0.144 0.759 0.061 SD (0.830) (0.553) (0.579) (0.248) (0.167) (0.307) Dependent variable is individual’s support for further European integration. Sample size is 54806 individuals within 25 countries. Pseudo R2 is 0.107. 232 APPENDIX B. COEFFICIENT TABLES Model 7B. Evaluation of EU membership Fixed effect Intercept (‘bad’ response) Intercept (‘bad’ or ‘neutral’ response) Year 2009 Year 2014 Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Left–right position Left–right position2 Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 Left–right pos. × year 2009 Left–right pos. × year 2014 Left–right pos.2 × year 2009 Left–right pos.2 × year 2014 Age × year 2009 Age × year 2014 Female × year 2009 Female × year 2014 Low education × year 2009 Low education × year 2014 High education × year 2009 High education × year 2014 Rural area × year 2009 Rural area × year 2014 Urban area × year 2009 Urban area × year 2014 Unemployed × year 2009 Unemployed × year 2014 Not in workforce × year 2009 Not in workforce × year 2014 Coeff. −2.152 −0.392 0.440 −0.119 0.440 −0.219 0.005 0.440 −0.331 0.150 −0.108 −0.182 0.101 0.030 0.002 −0.126 0.157 0.018 −0.004 −0.007 −0.004 0.022 0.005 0.018 0.139 −0.093 −0.080 0.148 0.136 0.108 0.124 0.047 −0.130 −0.057 −0.084 −0.018 −0.014 SE (0.150) (0.149) (0.137) (0.149) (0.056) (0.031) (0.011) (0.038) (0.043) (0.039) (0.037) (0.066) (0.038) (0.006) (0.002) (0.044) (0.086) (0.009) (0.009) (0.003) (0.003) (0.015) (0.015) (0.045) (0.043) (0.062) (0.062) (0.055) (0.052) (0.055) (0.054) (0.056) (0.054) (0.092) (0.085) (0.053) (0.052) p < 0.001 0.009 0.001 0.423 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.662 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.004 0.006 0.008 < 0.001 0.251 0.005 0.070 0.045 0.671 0.005 0.129 0.153 0.757 0.693 0.001 0.133 0.192 0.007 0.009 0.051 0.023 0.403 0.016 0.531 0.322 0.741 0.787 233 Country random effect Intercept Year 2009 Year 2014 Prospective assessment Prosp. assess. × year 2009 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 Var. 0.458 0.349 0.424 0.057 0.023 0.155 SD (0.677) (0.591) (0.651) (0.238) (0.153) (0.394) This is a multilevel ordered logit model. The dependent variable is the individual’s evaluation of EU membership as good, bad or neutral. Sample size is 56803 individuals within 25 countries. No Pseudo R2 has been computed as the residual variance is unknown. The p-values given here are based on Wald tests, as the software used to estimate this model does not produce Satterthwaite estimates of the degrees of freedom as for the other models. 234 APPENDIX B. COEFFICIENT TABLES Model 7C. Allocation of responsibility for the economy Fixed effect Intercept Institution is EU Year 2014 Prospective assessment Female Age (decades) High education Low education Urban area Rural area Unemployed Not in workforce Left–right position Left–right position2 Prosp. assess. × year 2014 Left–right pos. × year 2014 Left–right pos.2 × year 2014 Age × year 2014 Female × year 2014 Low education × year 2014 High education × year 2014 Rural area × year 2014 Urban area × year 2014 Unemployed × year 2014 Not in workforce × year 2014 EU × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × EU Left–right pos. × EU Left–right pos.2 × EU Age × EU Female × EU Low education × EU High education × EU Rural area × EU Urban area × EU Unemployed × EU Not in workforce × EU Prosp. assess. × EU × year 2014 Left–right pos. × EU × year 2014 Left–right pos.2 × EU × year 2014 Age × EU × year 2014 Female × EU × year 2014 Low education × EU × year 2014 High education × EU × year 2014 Rural area × EU × year 2014 Urban area × EU × year 2014 Unemployed × EU × year 2014 Not in workforce × EU × year 2014 Coeff. 0.319 −1.478 0.430 −0.159 0.185 −0.050 −0.010 −0.095 0.038 0.099 −0.058 −0.186 0.043 0.004 0.200 −0.036 0.001 0.051 −0.112 0.139 0.289 0.021 −0.037 0.081 0.170 0.419 0.129 −0.026 0.004 −0.042 0.229 0.169 −0.188 −0.021 −0.069 0.282 0.141 −0.204 0.030 0.000 0.003 −0.155 −0.250 0.033 −0.023 0.208 −0.204 −0.129 SE (0.118) (0.147) (0.158) (0.059) (0.036) (0.012) (0.043) (0.051) (0.045) (0.047) (0.075) (0.042) (0.007) (0.002) (0.077) (0.010) (0.003) (0.017) (0.050) (0.075) (0.060) (0.066) (0.063) (0.100) (0.060) (0.143) (0.041) (0.010) (0.003) (0.017) (0.051) (0.073) (0.061) (0.066) (0.064) (0.107) (0.059) (0.058) (0.014) (0.004) (0.024) (0.072) (0.106) (0.084) (0.094) (0.089) (0.142) (0.085) p 0.013 < 0.001 0.012 0.014 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.811 0.062 0.394 0.034 0.443 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.029 0.016 < 0.001 0.772 0.003 0.027 0.065 < 0.001 0.748 0.559 0.417 0.004 0.007 0.004 0.007 0.124 0.016 < 0.001 0.020 0.002 0.750 0.281 0.008 0.017 0.002 0.034 0.908 0.913 0.031 0.019 0.693 0.805 0.019 0.151 0.128 235 Country random effect Intercept Institution is EU Year 2014 Prospective assessment Prosp. assess. × year 2014 EU × year 2014 Prosp. assess. × EU Prosp. assess. × EU × year 2014 Var. 0.321 0.490 0.568 0.077 0.125 0.436 0.027 0.046 SD (0.567) (0.700) (0.754) (0.278) (0.353) (0.660) (0.163) (0.214) Dependent variable is the degree to which the individual holds the institution responsble for the condition of the economy. Sample size is 76658 individuals within 24 countries. Pseudo R2 is 0.135. References Aidt, Toke S. 2000. ‘Economic voting and information’. Electoral Studies 19 (2–3): 349–362. Alesina, Alberto, and Howard Rosenthal. 1995. Partisan Politics, Divided Government, and the Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Allen, Trevor J. 2015. ‘Extreme right support and mainstream party failure after the Eurozone Crisis’. Conference paper, APSA Annual Meeting, 5 September. Accessed 23 September 2015. http://convention2.allacademic.com/one/apsa/apsa15/ online_program.php. Alwin, Duane F. 1997. ‘Feeling Thermometers Versus 7-Point Scales: Which are Better?’ Sociological Methods and Research 25 (3): 318–340. Alwin, Duane F., and Jon A. Krosnick. 1991. ‘The Reliability of Survey Attitude Measurement: The Influence of Question and Respondent Attitudes’. Sociological Methods and Research 20 (1): 139–181. Anderson, Cameron D. 2006. ‘Economic Voting and Multilevel Governance: A Comparative Individiual-Level Analysis’. American Journal of Political Science 50 (2): 449–463. Anderson, Christopher J. 1998. ‘When in Doubt, Use Proxies: Attitudes Toward Domestic Politics and Support for European Integration’. Comparative Poliitcal Studies 31 (5): 569–601. . 2000. ‘Economic voting and political context: A comparative perspective’. Electoral Studies 19 (2): 151–170. Anderson, Christopher J., and Jason D. Hecht. 2012. ‘Voting when the economy goes bad, everyone is in charge, and no one is to blame: The case of the 2009 German election’. Electoral Studies 31 (1): 5–19. 237 238 REFERENCES . 2014. ‘Crisis of Confidence? The Dynamics of Economic Opinions During the Great Recession’. In Mass Politics in Tough Times: Opinions, Votes, and Protest in the Great Recession, edited by Nancy Bermeo and Larry M. Bartels, 40–71. New York: Oxford University Press. Arcelus, Francisco, and Allan H. Meltzer. 1975. ‘The Effect of Aggregate Economic Variables on Congressional Elections’. American Political Science Review 69 (4): 1232–1239. Arceneaux, Kevin. 2003. ‘The Conditional Impact of Blame Attribution on the Relationship Between Economic Adversity and Turnout’. Political Research Quarterly 56 (1): 67–75. . 2006. ‘The Federal Face of Voting: Are Elected Officials Held Accountable for the Functions Relevant to Their Office?’ Political Psychology 27 (5): 731–754. Arceneaux, Kevin, and David W. Nickerson. 2009. ‘Modeling Certainty with Clustered Data: A Comparison of Methods’. Political Analysis 17 (2): 177–190. Armingeon, Klaus, and Besir Ceka. 2014. ‘The loss of trust in the European Union during the great recession since 2007: The role of heuristics from the national political system’. European Union Politics 15 (1): 82–107. Ashworth, Scott. 2005. ‘Reputational Dynamics and Political Careers’. Journal of Law, Economics & Organization 21 (2): 441–466. Ashworth, Scott, and Ethan Bueno de Mesquita. 2008. ‘Electoral Selection, Strategic Challenger Entry, and the Incumbency Advantage’. Journal of Politics 70 (4): 1006–1025. Aslanidis, Paris, and Cristóbal Rovira Kaltwasser. 2016. ‘Dealing with populists in government: The SYRIZA–ANEL coalition in Greece’. Democratization 23 (6): 1077–1091. Barro, Robert J. 1973. ‘The Control of Politicians: An Economic Model’. Public Choice 14 (1): 19–42. Bartels, Larry M. 2012. ‘Elections in hard times’. Public Policy Research 19 (1): 44–50. . 2013. ‘Political Effects of the Great Recession’. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 650 (1): 47–75. . 2014. ‘Ideology and Retrospection in the Electoral Responses to the Great Recession’. In Mass Politics in Tough Times: Opinions, Votes, and Protest in the Great Recession, edited by Nancy Bermeo and Larry M. Bartels, 185–223. New York: Oxford University Press. REFERENCES 239 Bates, Douglas, Martin Mächler, Ben Bolker and Steve Walker. 2015. ‘Fitting Linear MixedEffects Models Using lme4’. Journal of Statistical Software 67 (1): 1–48. BBC News. 2009. ‘Huge protest over Irish economy’. Accessed 4 August 2016. http : / / news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/europe/7903518.stm. . 2015. ‘Election 2015: Results’. Accessed 5 August 2016. http://www.bbc.com/ news/election/2015/results. . 2016a. ‘EU Referendum Results’. Accessed 30 July 2016. http : / / www . bbc . com/news/politics/eu_referendum/results. . 2016b. ‘Scottish Parliament election 2016 results’. Accessed 15 July 2016. http: //www.bbc.com/news/election/2016/scotland/results. Bell, Robert M., and Michael L. Cohen. 2007. ‘Comment: Struggles with Survey Weighting and Regression Modeling’. Statistical Science 22 (2): 165–167. Bellucci, Paolo. 2012. ‘Government accountability and voting choice in Italy, 1990–2008’. Electoral Studies 31 (3): 491–497. Berglund, Frode, Sören Holmberg, Hermann Schmitt and Jacques Thomassen. 2005. ‘Party Identification and Party Choice’. In The European Voter: A Comparative Study of Modern Democracies, edited by Jacques Thomassen, 106–124. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Bermeo, Nancy, and Larry M. Bartels. 2014. ‘Mass Politics in Tough Times’. In Mass Politics in Tough Times: Opinions, Votes, and Protest in the Great Recession, edited by Nancy Bermeo and Larry M. Bartels, 1–39. New York: Oxford University Press. Birch, Sarah. 2008. Full participation: A comparative study of compulsory voting. Manchester: Manchester University Press. Blais, André. 2000. To Vote or Not to Vote?: The Merits and Limits of Rational Choice Theory. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press. . 2007. ‘Turnout in Elections’. In The Oxford Handbook of Poltical Behavior, edited by Russell J. Dalton and Hans-Dieter Klingemann, 621–635. Oxford: Oxford University Press. . 2013. ‘The Source of Turnout Decline: New Values or New Contexts?’ Comparative Political Studies 46 (1): 95–117. 240 REFERENCES Blais, André, and R. K. Carty. 1990. ‘Does proportional representation foster voter turnout?’ European Journal of Political Research 18 (2): 167–181. Bloom, Howard S., and H. Douglas Price. 1975. ‘Voter Response to Short-Run Economic Conditions: The Asymmetric Effect of Prosperity and Recession’. American Political Science Review 69 (4): 1240–1254. Boomgaarden, Hajo G., Andreas R. T. Schuck, Matthijs Elenbaas and Claes H. de Vreese. 2011. ‘Mapping EU attitudes: Conceptual and empirical dimensions of Euroscepticism and EU support’. European Union Politics 12 (2): 241–266. Borges, Walt, Harold D. Clarke, Marianne C. Stewart, David Sanders and Paul Whiteley. 2013. ‘The emerging political economy of austerity in Britain’. Electoral Studies 32 (3): 396–403. Borre, Ole. 1997. ‘Economic Voting in Danish Electoral Surveys 1987–94’. Scandinavian Political Studies 20 (4): 347–365. Bouvet, Florence, and Sharmila King. 2016. ‘Income inequality and election outcomes in OECD countries: New evidence following the Great Recession of 2008–2009’. Electoral Studies 41 (1): 70–79. Brack, Nathalie, and Nicholas Startin. 2015. ‘Introduction: Euroscepticism, from the margins to the mainstream’. International Political Science Review 36 (3): 239–249. Brody, Richard A., and Paul M. Sniderman. 1977. ‘From Life Space to Polling Place: The Releveance of Personal Concerns for Voting Behavior’. British Journal of Political Science 7 (3): 337–360. Busch, Kathrin Barbara. 2016. ‘Estimating parties’ left–right positions: Determinants of voters’ perceptions’ proximity to party ideology’. Electoral Studies 41 (1): 159–178. Campbell, Angus, Philip E. Converse, Warren E. Miller and Donald E. Stokes. 1960. The American Voter. New York: John Wiley & Sons. Çarkoğlu, Ali. 2012. ‘Economic valuations vs. ideology: Diagnosing the sources of electoral change in Turkey, 2002–2011’. Electoral Studies 31 (3): 313–521. Carlsen, Fredrik. 2000. ‘Unemployment, inflation and government popularity—are there partisan effects?’ Electoral Studies 19 (2–3): 141–150. REFERENCES 241 Chappell Jr., Henry W., and Linda Gonçalves Veiga. 2000. ‘Economics and elections in Western Europe: 1960–1997’. Electoral Studies 19 (2): 183–197. Christensen, Rune Haubo Bojesen. 2015. ordinal: Regression Models for Ordinal Data. R package version 2015.6-28. http://www.cran.r-project.org/package=ordinal/. Clarke, Harold D., and Guy D. Whitten. 2013. ‘Hard choices in hard times: Valence voting in Germany’. Electoral Studies 32 (3): 445–451. Connor, Gregery, Thomas Flavin and Brian O’Kelly. 2012. ‘The U.S. and Irish credit crises: Their distinctive differences and common features’. Journal of International Money and Finance 31 (1): 60–79. Conover, Pamela Johnston, Stanley Feldman and Kathleen Knight. 1987. ‘The Personal and Political Underpinnings of Economic Forecasts’. American Journal of Political Science 31 (3): 559–583. Converse, Philip E. 1976. The Dynamics of Party Support: Cohort-Analyzing Party Identification. Beverly Hills, California: Sage Publications. Coppock, Alexander, and Donald P. Green. 2015. ‘Is Voting Habit Forming? New Evidence from Experiments and Regression Discontinuities’. American Journal of Political Science. doi:10.1111/ajps.12210. Crewe, Ivor. 1981. ‘Electoral Participation’. In Democracy at the Polls: A Comparative Study of Competitive National Elections, edited by David Butler, Howard R. Penniman and Austin Ranney, 216–263. Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute. Cutler, Fred. 2004. ‘Government Responsibility and Electoral Accountability in Federations’. Journal of Federalism 34 (2): 19–38. . 2008. ‘Whodunnit? Voters and Responsibility in Canadian Federalism’. Canadian Journal of Political Science 41 (3): 627–654. Dalton, Russell J. 2016. ‘Stability and chance in party issue positions: The 2009 and 2014 European elections’. Electoral Studies. doi:10.1016/j.electstud.2016.06. 008. Dalton, Russell J., David M. Farrell and Ian McAllister. 2011. Political Parties and Democratic Linkage: How Parties Organize Democracy. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 242 REFERENCES Dalton, Russell J., and Ian McAllister. 2015. ‘Random Walk or Planned Excursion? Continuity and Change in the Left–Right Positions of Political Parties’. Comparative Political Studies 48 (6): 759–787. Davis, Otto A., Melvin J. Hinich and Peter C. Ordeshook. 1970. ‘An Expository Development of a Mathematical Model of the Electoral Process’. American Political Science Review 54 (2): 426–448. Debus, Marc, Mary Stegmaier and Jale Tosun. 2014. ‘Economic Voting under Coalition Governments: Evidence from Germany’. Political Science Research and Methods 2 (1): 49–67. Döring, Holger, and Philip Manow. 2015. Parliament and government composition database (ParlGov): An infrastructure for empirical information on parties, elections and governments in modern democracies. Version 14/10. Accessed 27 June. www.parlgov.org. Dorussen, Han. 2002. ‘Conclusions’. In Economic Voting, edited by Han Dorussen and Michaell Taylor, 303–310. ECPR Studies in European Political Science 27. London: Routledge. Dorussen, Han, and Harvey D. Palmer. 2002. ‘The context of economic voting: An introduction’. In Economic Voting, edited by Han Dorussen and Michaell Taylor, 1–14. ECPR Studies in European Political Science 27. London: Routledge. Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row. Duch, Raymond M. 2001. ‘A Developmental Model of Heterogeneous Economic Voting in New Democracies’. American Political Science Review 95 (4): 895–910. . 2007. ‘Comparative Studies of the Economy and the Vote’. In The Oxford Handbook of Comparative Politics, edited by Charles Boix and Susan C. Stokes, 805–844. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Duch, Raymond M., and Iñaki Sagarzazu. 2014. ‘Crisis Perceptions and Economic Voting Among the Rich and the Poor: The United Kingdom and Germany’. In Mass Politics in Tough Times: Opinions, Votes, and Protest in the Great Recession, edited by Nancy Bermeo and Larry M. Bartels, 224–265. New York: Oxford University Press. Duch, Raymond M., and Randolph T. Stevenson. 2008. The Economic Vote: How Political and Economic Institutions Condition Election Results. New York: Cambridge University Press. Dumont, Patrick, Raphaël Kies and Philippe Poirier. 2010. ‘Luxembourg’. European Journal of Political Research 49 (7–8): 1076–1088. REFERENCES 243 Dumont, Patrick, and Philippe Poirier. 2005. ‘Luxembourg’. European Journal of Political Research 44 (7–8): 1102–1118. DuMouchel, William H., and Greg J. Duncan. 1983. ‘Using Sample Survey Weights in Multiple Regression Analyses of Stratified Samples’. Journal of the American Statistical Association 78 (383): 535–543. Durant, Henry. 1965. ‘Indirect influences on voting behaviour’. Polls 1:3–11. Durr, Robert H. 1993. ‘What Moves Policy Sentiment?’ American Political Science Review 87 (1): 158–170. Duverger, Maurice. 1959. Political Parties: Their Organization and Activity in the Modern State. 2nd ed. Translated by Barbara North and Robert North. University Paperbacks. London: Methuen & Co. EES. 2004. European Election Study 2004. Voter study. Version 2. http://eeshomepage. net/ees-2004-study/voter-study. . 2009. European Parliament Election Study 2009. Voter study. Advance release, 7 April 2010. http://www.piredeu.eu. . 2014. European Election Study 2014. Voter study. Advance release, 1 January 2015. http://eeshomepage.net/voter-study-2014. EJPR. 2003–2015. ‘Political Data Yearbook’. Country entries not cited individually, European Journal of Political Research 42–54. . 2016. Political Data Yearbook: Interactive. European Journal of Political Research. Accessed 22 January 2016. http://www.politicaldatayearbook.com/. Elgie, Robert. 1999. ‘The Politics of Semi-Presidentialism’. In Semi-Presidentialism in Europe, edited by Robert Elgie, 1–21. Oxford: Oxford University Press. . 2012. ‘The President of Ireland in Comparative Perspective’. Irish Political Studies 27 (4): 502–521. Erikson, Robert S., Michael B. MacKuen and James A. Stimson. 2000. ‘Bankers or peasants revisited’. Electoral Studies 19 (2–3): 295–312. . 2002. The Macro Polity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 244 REFERENCES European Commission. 2009. Economic Crisis in Europe: Causes, Consequences and Responses. European Economy 7. Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs. Accessed 4 August 2016. http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/ publication15887_en.pdf. . 2010. The Economic Adjustment Programme for Greece. Occasional Papers 61. DirectorateGeneral for Economic and Financial Affairs. Accessed 29 July 2016. http : / / ec . europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/occasional_paper/ 2010/pdf/ocp61_en.pdf. . 2011a. The Economic Adjustment Programme for Ireland. Occasional Papers 76. DirectorateGeneral for Economic and Financial Affairs. Accessed 29 July 2016. http : / / ec . europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/occasional_paper/ 2011/pdf/ocp76_en.pdf. . 2011b. The Economic Adjustment Programme for Portugal. Occasional Papers 79. DirectorateGeneral for Economic and Financial Affairs. Accessed 29 July 2016. http : / / ec . europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/occasional_paper/ 2011/pdf/ocp79_en.pdf. . 2012. The Second Economic Adjustment Programme for Greece. Occasional Papers 94. Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs. Accessed 29 July 2016. http: //ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/occasional_ paper/2012/pdf/ocp94_en.pdf. . 2013. The Economic Adjustment Programme for Cyprus. Occasional Papers 149. DirectorateGeneral for Economic and Financial Affairs. Accessed 29 July 2016. http : / / ec . europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/occasional_paper/ 2013/pdf/ocp149_en.pdf. Evans, Geoffrey, and Robert Andersen. 2006. ‘The Political Conditioning of Economic Perceptions’. Journal of Politics 68 (1): 194–207. Evans, Geoffrey, and Mark Pickup. 2010. ‘Reversing the Causal Arrow: The Political Conditioning of Economic Perceptions in the 2000–2004 U.S. Presidential Election Cycle’. Southern Political Science Association 72 (4): 1236–1251. Fair, Ray C. 1978. ‘The Effect of Economic Events on Votes for President’. Review of Economics and Statistics 60 (2): 159–173. REFERENCES 245 Fearon, James D. 1999. ‘Electoral Accountability and the Control of Politicians: Selecting Good Types versus Sanctioning Poor Performance’. In Democracy, Accountability, and Representation, edited by Adam Przeworski, Susan C. Stokes and Bernard Manin, 55–97. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Feld, Lars P., and Gebhard Kirchgässner. 2000. ‘Official and hidden unemployment and the popularity of the government: an econometric analysis for the Kohl government’. Electoral Studies 19 (2–3): 333–347. Ferejohn, John. 1986. ‘Incumbent performance and electoral control’. Public Choice 50 (1–3): 5–25. Fiorina, Morris P. 1978. ‘Economic Retrospective Voting in American National Elections: A Micro-Analysis’. Midwest Political Science Association 22 (2): 426–443. . 1981. Retrospective Voting in American National Elections. New Haven: Yale University Press. Fisher, Stephen D., and Sara B. Hobolt. 2010. ‘Coalition government and electoral accountability’. Electoral Studies 29 (3): 358–369. Flassbeck, Heiner, and Costas Lapavitsas. 2015. ‘Confronting the failure of the European Monetary Union’. In Asymmetric Crisis in Europe and Possible Futures: Critical political economy and post-Keynesian perspectives, edited by Johannes Jäger and Elisabeth Springler, 131– 148. New York: Routledge. Ford, Robert, and Matthew J. Goodwin. 2010. ‘Angry White Men: Individual and Contextual Predictors of Support for the British National Party’. Political Studies 58 (1): 1–25. Fraile, Marta, and Michael S. Lewis-Beck. 2012. ‘Economic and elections in Spain (1982– 2008): Cross-measures, cross-time’. Electoral Studies 31 (3). . 2013. ‘Multi-dimensional economic voting in Spain: The 2008 election’. Electoral Studies 32 (3): 465–469. Franklin, Mark N. 1996. ‘Electoral Participation’. In Comparing Democracies: Elections and Voting in Global Perspective, edited by Lawrence LeDuc, Richard G. Nieme and Pippa Norris, 216–235. Thousand Oaks, California: SAGE. . 2004. Voter Turnout and the Dynamics of Electoral Competition in Established Democracies since 1945. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 246 REFERENCES Freire, André, and José Santana-Pereira. 2012. ‘Economic voting in Portugal, 2002–2009’. Electoral Studies 31 (3): 506–512. Gabel, Matthew J., and Christopher J. Anderson. 2004. ‘The structure of citizen attitudes and the European political space’. In European Integration and Political Conflict, edited by Gary Marks and Marco R. Steenbergen, 13–31. New York: Cambridge University Press. Gabel, Matthew J., and Simon Hix. 2004. ‘Defining the EU political space: an empirical study of the European election manifestos, 1979–1999’. In European Integration and Political Conflict, edited by Gary Marks and Marco R. Steenbergen, 93–119. New York: Cambridge University Press. Gabel, Matthew, and Guy D. Whitten. 1997. ‘Economic conditions, economic perceptions, and public support for European integration’. Political Behavior 19 (1): 81–96. Garry, John. 2014. ‘Holding parties responsible at election time: Multi-level, multi-party government and electoral accountability’. Electoral Studies 34 (1): 78–88. Garry, John, and James Tilley. 2014. ‘Inequality, state ownership and the European Union: How economic context and economic ideology shape support for the Europeana Union’. European Union Politics 16 (1): 139–154. Gelman, Andrew. 2007a. ‘Rejoinder: Struggles with Survey Weighting and Regression Modeling’. Statistical Science 22 (2): 184–188. . 2007b. ‘Struggles with Survey Weighting and Regression Modeling’. Statistical Science 22 (2): 153–164. Gelman, Andrew, and Jennifer Hill. 2007. Data Analysis Using Regression and Multilevel/Hierarchical Models. New York: Cambridge University Press. Gelman, Andrew, and Yu-Sung Su. 2015. arm: Data Analysis Using Regression and Multilevel/ Hierarchical Models. R package version 1.8-6. https://CRAN.R-project.org/ package=arm. Geys, Benny. 2006. ‘Explaining voter turnout: A review of aggregate-level research’. Electoral Studies 25 (4): 637–663. Gosnell, Harold F., and William G. Colman. 1940. ‘Political Trends in Industrial America: Pennsylvania an Example’. Public Opinion Quarterly 4 (3): 473–486. REFERENCES 247 Gowrisankaran, Gautam, Matthew F. Mitchell and Andrea Moro. 2008. ‘Electoral design and voter welfare from the US Senate: Evidence from a dynamic selection model’. Review of Economic Dynamics 11 (1): 1–17. Gray, Mark, and Miki Caul. 2000. ‘Declining Voter Turnout in Advanced Industrial Democracies, 1950 to 1997: The Effects of Declining Group Mobilization’. Comparative Political Studies 33 (9): 1091–1122. Green, Donald P., and Ron Shacar. 2000. ‘Habit Formation and Political Behaviour: Evidence of Consuetude in Voter Turnout’. British Journal of Political Science 30 (4): 561–573. Green, Donald, Bradley Palmquist and Eric Schickler. 2002. Partisan Hearts and Minds. New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press. Grittersova, Jana, Indridi H. Indridason, Christina C. Gregory and Ricardo Crespo. 2015. ‘Austerity and Political Extremism: The Electoral Consequences of Fiscal Reforms’. Conference paper, APSA Annual Meeting, 5 September. Accessed 23 September 2015. http: / / convention2 . allacademic . com / one / apsa / apsa15 / online _ program.php. Hakhverdian, Armen, Erika van Elsas, Wouter van der Brug and Theresa Kuhn. 2013. ‘Euroscepticism and education: A longitudinal study of 12 EU member states, 1973–2010’. European Union Politics 14 (4): 522–541. Hansford, Thomas G., and Brad T. Gomez. 2015. ‘Reevaluating the sociotropic economic voting hypothesis’. Electoral Studies 39 (1): 15–25. Harteveld, Eelco, Tom van der Meer and Catherine E. De Vries. 2013. ‘In Europe we trust? Exploring three logics of trust in the European Union’. European Union Politics 14 (4): 542–565. Heipertz, Martin, and Amy Verdun. 2010. Ruling Europe: The Politics of the Stability and Growth Pact. New York: Cambridge University Press. Hellwig, Timothy, and Eva Coffey. 2011. ‘Public opinion, party messages, and responsibility for the financial crisis in Britain’. Electoral Studies 30 (3): 417–426. Hellwig, Timothy, and Dani M. Marinova. 2015. ‘More Misinformed than Myopic: Economic Retrospections and the Voter’s Time Horizon’. Political Behaviour 37 (4): 865–887. 248 REFERENCES Hellwig, Timothy, and David Samuels. 2008. ‘Electoral Accountability and the Variety of Democractic Regimes’. British Journal of Political Science 38 (1): 65–90. Hernández, Enrique, and Hanspeter Kriesi. 2015. ‘The electoral consequences of the financial and economic crisis in Europe’. European Journal of Political Research. doi:10.1111/ 1475-6765.12122. Hibbs, Douglas. 1993. Solidarity or Egoism? The Economics of Sociotropic and Egocentric Influences on Political Behavior: Denmark in International and Theoretical Perspective. Aarhus, Denmark: Aarhus University Press. Hix, Simon. 1999. ‘Dimensions and alignments in European Union politics: Cognitive constraints and partisan responses’. European Journal of Political Research 35 (1): 69–106. . 2007. ‘Euroscepticism as Anti-Centralization: A Rational Choice Institutionalist Perspective’. European Union Politics 8 (1): 131–150. Hix, Simon, and Christopher Lord. 1997. Political Parties in the European Union. Basingstoke, Hampshire: Macmillan Press. Hobolt, Sara B. 2012. ‘Citizen Satisfaction with Democracy in the European Union’. Journal of Common Market Studies 50 (Supplement 1): 88–105. Hobolt, Sara B., and Patrick Leblond. 2014. ‘Economic Insecurity and Public Support for the Euro: Before and During the Financial Crisis’. In Mass Politics in Tough Times: Opinions, Votes, and Protest in the Great Recession, edited by Nancy Bermeo and Larry M. Bartels, 128–147. New York: Oxford University Press. Hobolt, Sara B., and James Tilley. 2014. Blaming Europe? Responsibility Without Accountability in the European Union. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hobolt, Sara, James Tilley and Susan Banducci. 2013. ‘Clarity of responsibility: How government cohesion conditions preformance voting’. European Journal of Political Research 52 (2): 164–187. Hooghe, Liesbet, and Gary Marks. 1999. ‘The Making of a Polity: The Struggle over European Integration’. In Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism, edited by Herbert Kitschelt, Peter Lange, Gary Marks and John D. Stephens, 70–97. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. REFERENCES 249 Hooghe, Liesbet, Gary Marks and Carole J. Wilson. 2004. ‘Does left/right structure party positions on European integration?’ In European Integration and Political Conflict, edited by Gary Marks and Marco R. Steenbergen, 120–140. New York: Cambridge University Press. Hotelling, Harold. 1929. ‘Stability in Competition’. The Economic Journal 39 (153): 41–57. Huber, Gregory A., Seth J. Hill and Gabriel S. Lenz. 2012. ‘Sources of Bias in Retrospective Decision Making: Experimental Evidence on Voters’ Limitations in Controlling Incumbents’. American Political Science Review 106 (4): 720–741. Irish Times. 2016. ‘Election 2016: Results Hub’. Accessed 4 August 2016. http://www. irishtimes.com/election-2016/results-hub. Jackman, Robert W. 1987. ‘Political Institutions and Voter Turnout in the Industrial Democracies’. American Political Science Review 81 (2): 405–424. Jackman, Robert W., and Ross A. Miller. 1995. ‘Voter Turnout in the Industrial Democracies during the 1980s’. Comparative Political Studies 27 (4): 467–492. Johns, Robert, James Mitchell and Christopher J. Carman. 2013. ‘Constitution or Competence? the SNP’s Re-Election in 2011’. Political Studies 61 (1): 158–178. Katz, Richard S., and Peter Mair. 1995. ‘Changing Models of Party Organization and Party Democracy: The Emergence of the Cartel Party’. Party Politics 1 (1): 5–28. . 2009. ‘The Cartel Party Thesis: A Restatement’. Perspectives on Politics 7 (4): 753–766. Kenworthy, Lane, and Lindsay A. Owens. 2011. ‘The Surprisingly Weak Effect of Recessions on Public Opinion’. In The Great Recession, edited by David B. Grusky, Bruce Western and Christopher Wimer, 196–219. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Kernell, Samuel. 1977. ‘Presidential Popularity and Negative Voting: An Alternative Explanation of the Midterm Congressional Decline of the President’s Party’. American Political Science Review 71 (1): 44–66. Kerr, W. A. 1944. ‘A Quantitative Study of Political Behavior, 1840–1940’. Journal of Social Psychology 19 (2): 273–281. Key Jr, V. O. 1961. Public Opinion and American Democracy. New York: Alfred A. Knopf. . 1964. Politics, Parties, & Pressure Groups. 5th ed. New York: Thomas Y. Crowell Company. 250 REFERENCES . 1966. The Responsible Electorate: Rationality in Presidential Voting 1936–1960. Cambridge, Massachussets: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. Kinder, Donald R., and D. Roderick Kiewiet. 1979. ‘Economic Discontent and Political Behavior: The Role of Personal Grievances and Collective Economic Judgments in Congressional Voting’. American Journal of Political Science 23 (3): 495–527. . 1981. ‘Sociotropic Politics: The American Case’. British Journal of Political Science 11 (2): 129–161. King, Gary, James Honaker, Anne Joseph and Kenneth Scheve. 2001. ‘Analyzing Incomplete Political Science Data: An Alternative Algorithm for Multiple Imputation’. American Political Science Review 95 (1): 49–69. Kirchheimer, Otto. 1966. ‘The Transformation of the Western European Party Systems’. In Political Parties and Political Development, edited by Joseph LaPalombara and Myron Weiner, 177–200. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Koole, Ruud. 1996. ‘Cadre, Catch-all or Cartel? A Comment on the Notion of the Cartel Party’. Party Politics 2 (4): 507–523. Kramer, Gerald H. 1971. ‘Short-Term Fluctuations in U.S. Voting Behavior, 1896–1964’. American Political Science Review 65 (1): 131–143. . 1983. ‘The Ecological Fallacy Revisited: Aggregate- versus Individual-level Findings on Economics and Elections, and Sociotropic Voting’. American Political Science Review 77 (1): 92–111. Kriesi, Hanspeter. 2012. ‘The Political Consequences of the Financial and Economic Crisis in Europe: Electoral Punishment and Popular Protest’. Swiss Poliitcal Science Review 18 (4): 518–522. . 2014. ‘The Political Consequences of the Economic Crisis in Europe: Electoral Punishment and Popular Protest’. In Mass Politics in Tough Times: Opinions, Votes, and Protest in the Great Recession, edited by Nancy Bermeo and Larry M. Bartels, 297–333. New York: Oxford University Press. Kroh, Martin. 2009. ‘The Ease of Ideological Voting: Voter Sophistication and Party System Complexity’. In The Comparative Study of Electoral Systems, edited by Hans-Dieter Klingemann, 220–236. Oxford: Oxford University Press. REFERENCES 251 Krouwel, André. 2012. Party Transformations in European Democracies. Albany, New York: State University of New York Press. Kuklinski, James H., and Darrell M. West. 1981. ‘Economic Expectations and Voting Behavior in United States House and Senate Elections’. American Political Science Review 75 (2): 436–447. Kumlin, Staffan. 2009. ‘Blaming Europe? Exploring the variable impact of national public service dissatisfaction on EU trust’. Journal of European Social Policy 19 (5): 408–420. Kuznetsova, Alexandra, Per Bruun Brockhoff and Rune Haubo Bojesen Christensen. 2016. lmerTest: Tests in Linear Mixed Effects Models. R package version 2.0-32. https : / / CRAN.R-project.org/package=lmerTest. Lacy, Dean, and Barry C. Burden. 1999. ‘The Vote-Stealing and Turnout Effects of Ross Perot in the 1992 U.S. Presidential Election’. American Journal of Political Science 43 (1): 233–255. Lane, Robert E. 1959. Political Life: Why People Get Involved in Politics. New York: Free Press. LeDuc, Lawrence, and Jon H. Pammett. 2013. ‘The fate of governing parties in times of economic crisis’. Electoral Studies 32 (3): 494–499. Leighley, Jan E., and Jonathon Nagler. 2014. Who Votes Now? Demographics, Issues, Inequality, and Turnout in the United States. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Lester, J. C. 1994. ‘The Evolution of the Political Compass (And Why Libertarianism Is Not Right-Wing)’. Journal of Social and Evolutionary Systems 17 (3): 231–241. Lewis-Beck, Michael S. 1986. ‘Comparative Economic Voting: Britain, France, Germany, Italy’. American Journal of Political Science 30 (2): 315–346. Lewis-Beck, Michael S., William G. Jacoby, Helmut Norpoth and Herbert F. Weisberg. 2008. The American Voter Revisited. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Lewis-Beck, Michael S., Richard Nadeau and Angelo Elias. 2008. ‘Economics, Party, and the Vote: Causality Issues and Panel Data’. American Journal of Political Science 52 (1): 84–95. Lewis-Beck, Michael S., and Martin Paldam. 2000. ‘Economic voting: an introduction’. Electoral Studies 19 (2–3): 113–121. Lewis-Beck, Michael S., Rune Stubager and Richard Nadeau. 2013. ‘The Kramer problem: Micro-macro resolution with a Danish pool’. Electoral Studies 32 (3): 500–505. 252 REFERENCES Lindvall, Johannes. 2012. ‘The Political Consequences of the Great Depression and the Great Recession: Remarkably Similar’. Swiss Political Science Review 18 (4): 514–517. . 2013. ‘Economic crises as political opportunities’. In Before and Beyond the Global Economic Crisis: Economics, Politics and Settlement, edited by Mats Benner, 132–150. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. . 2014. ‘The electoral consequences of two great crises’. European Journal of Political Research 53 (4): 747–765. Lindvall, Johannes, Johan Martinsson and Henrik Oscarsson. 2013. ‘Party choice in hard times: Group-specific responses to economic downturns in Sweden’. Electoral Studies 32 (3). Linek, Lukáš, and Tomáš Lacina. 2010. ‘Czech Republic’. European Journal of Political Research 49 (7–8): 939–946. Lipset, Seymour Martin. 1981. Political Man: The Social Bases of Politics. Expanded Edition. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press. Lyons, William, and Robert Alexander. 2000. ‘A Tale of Two Electorates: Generational Replacement and the Decline of Voting in Presidential Elections’. Journal of Politics 62 (4): 1014– 1034. MacKuen, Michael B., Robert S. Erikson and James A. Stimson. 1992. ‘Peasants or Bankers? The American Electorate and the U.S. Economy’. American Political Science Review 86 (3): 597–611. Mair, Peter. 2007. ‘Left–Right Orientations’. In The Oxford Handbook of Poltical Behavior, edited by Russell J. Dalton and Hans-Dieter Klingemann, 206–222. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Marsh, Michael, and Slava Mikhaylov. 2012. ‘Economic voting in a crisis: The Irish election of 2011’. Electoral Studies 31 (3): 478–484. Martins, Rodrigo, and Francisco José Veige. 2013. ‘Economic performance and turnout at national and local elections’. Public Choice 157: 429–448. Martinsson, Johan. 2013. ‘Economic voting in Sweden 1985–2010’. Electoral Studies 32 (3): 470–475. REFERENCES 253 Matakos, Konstantinos, and Dimitrios Xefteris. 2016. ‘Election note: The September 20, 2015 parliamentary election in Greece’. Electoral Studies. doi:10.1016/j.electstud. 2016.04.004. Mau, Steffen. 2005. ‘Democratic demand for a social Europe? Preferences of the European citizenry’. International Journal of Social Welfare 14 (2): 76–85. Mavrogordatos, George Th., and Nikos Marantzidis. 2010. ‘Greece’. European Journal of Political Research 49 (7–8): 991–1000. Mayer, Nonna. 2014. ‘The Electoral Impact of the Crisis on the French Working Class: More to the right?’ In Mass Politics in Tough Times: Opinions, Votes, and Protest in the Great Recession, edited by Nancy Bermeo and Larry M. Bartels, 266–296. New York: Oxford University Press. McBride, Stephen. 2015. ‘The economics of austerity’. In Social Policy in Times of Austerity: Global economic crisis and the new politics of welfare, edited by Kevin Farnsworth and Zoë Irving, 67–86. Bristol: Policy Press. McDonnell, Duncan, and James L. Newell. 2011. ‘Outsider parties in government in Western Europe’. Party Politics 17 (4): 443–452. Meehl, Paul E. 1977. ‘The Selfish Voter Paradox and the Thrown-Away Vote Argument’. American Political Science Review 71 (1): 11–30. Meyer, Thomas M., and Daniel Strobl. 2016. ‘Voter perceptions of coalition policy positions in multiparty systems’. Electoral Studies 41 (1): 80–91. Michelitch, Kristin, Marco Morales, Andrew Owen and Joshua A. Tucker. 2012. ‘Looking to the future: Prospective economic voting in 2008 Presidential Elections’. Electoral Studies 31 (4): 838–851. Mylonas, Harris. 2013. ‘Greece’. European Journal of Political Research: Political Data Yearbook 52 (1): 87–95. Nadeau, Richard, and Michael S. Lewis-Beck. 2001. ‘National Economic Voting in U.S. Presidential Elections’. Journal of Politics 63 (1): 159–181. Nadeau, Richard, Richard G. Niemi and Antoine Yoshinaka. 2002. ‘A cross-national analysis of economic voting: taking account of the political context across time and nations’. Electoral Studies 21 (3): 403–423. 254 REFERENCES Nannestad, Peter, and Martin Paldam. 1994. ‘The VP-function: A survey of the literature on vote and popularity functions after 25 years’. Public Choice 79 (3): 213–245. . 1995. ‘It’s the government’s fault! A cross-section study of economic voting in Denmark, 1990/93’. European Journal of Political Research 28 (1): 33–62. . 1997a. ‘From the Pocketbook of the Welfare Man: A Pooled Cross-Section Study of Economic Voting in Denmark, 1986–92’. British Journal of Political Science 27 (1): 119– 136. . 1997b. ‘The grievance asymmetry revisited: A micro study of economic voting in Denmark, 1986–92’. European Journal of Political Economy 13 (1): 81–99. Nezi, Roula. 2012. ‘Economic voting under the economic crisis: Evidence from Greece’. Electoral Studies 31 (3): 498–505. Norpoth, Helmut. 2001. ‘Divided Government and Economic Voting’. Journal of Politics 63 (2): 414–435. Nousiainen, Jaakko. 2001. ‘From Semi-presidentialism to Parliamentary Government: Political and Constitutional Developments in Finland’. Scandinavian Political Studies 24 (2): 95– 109. Ogburn, William F., and Lolagene C. Coombs. 1940. ‘American Government and Politics: The Economic Factor in the Roosevelt Elections’. American Political Science Review 34 (4): 719– 727. O’Malley, Eoin. 2012. ‘Ireland’. European Journal of Political Research: Political Data Yearbook 51 (1): 141–152. Orriols, Lluis, and Álvaro Martínez. 2014. ‘The role of the political context in voting indecision’. Electoral Studies 25 (1): 12–23. Paldam, Martin. 1991. ‘How Robust is the Vote Function? A Study of Seventeen Nations over Four Decades: The Calculus of Support’. In Economics and Politics, edited by Helmut Norpoth, Michael S. Lewis-Beck and Jean-Dominique Lafay, 9–32. Manchester: Manchester University Press. Paldam, Martin, and Peter Nannestad. 2000. ‘What do voters know about the economy? A study of Danish data, 1990–1993’. Electoral Studies 19 (2–3): 363–391. REFERENCES 255 Palmer, Harvey D., and Guy D. Whitten. 2011. ‘Through thick and thin? The dynamics of government support across income groups during economic crises’. Electoral Studies 30 (3): 427–437. Palmer, Harvey D., Guy D. Whitten and Laron K. Williams. 2013. ‘Who sould be chef? The dynamics of valence evalations across income groups during economic crises’. Electoral Studies 32 (3): 425–431. Panebianco, Angelo. 1988. Political parties: organization and power. Translated by Marc Silver. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Passarelli, Gianluca, and Dario Tuorto. 2014. ‘Not with my vote: Turnout and the economic crisis in Italy’. Contemporary Italian Politics 6 (2): 147–158. Pearson, F. A., and W. I. Myers. 1948. ‘Prices and Presidents’. Farm Economics (Ithaca, New York), no. 163 (September): 4210–4218. Plutzer, Eric. 2002. ‘Becoming a Habitual Voter: Inertia, Resources, and Growth in Young Adulthood’. American Political Science Review 96 (1): 41–56. Popa, Sebastian Adrian, Hermann Schmitt, Sara B. Hobolt and Eftichia Teperoglou. 2015. EES 2014 Voter Study Advance Release Notes. Mannheim: MZES, University of Mannheim. Powell Jr., G. Bingham. 1980. ‘Voting Turnout in Thirty Democracies: Partisan, Legal, and Socio-Economic Influences’. In Electoral Participation: A Comparative Analysis, edited by Richard Rose, 5–34. London: SAGE. . 1982. Contemporary Democracies: Participation, Stability, and Violence. Cambridge, Massachussets: Harvard University Press. . 1986. ‘American Voter Turnout in Comparative Perspective’. American Political Science Review 80 (1): 17–43. Powell Jr., G. Bingham, and Guy D. Whitten. 1993. ‘A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of the Political Context’. American Journal of Political Science 37 (2): 391–414. R Core Team. 2016. R: A Language and Environment for Statistical Computing. Vienna, Austria: R Foundation for Statistical Computing. https://www.R-project.org/. 256 REFERENCES Radcliff, Benjamin. 1992. ‘The Welfare State, Turnout, and the Economy: A Comparative Analysis’. American Political Science Review 86 (2): 444–454. . 1994. ‘Reward Without Punishment: Economic Conditions and the Vote’. Political Research Quarterly 47 (3): 721–731. Rees, Albert, Herbert Kaufman, Samuel J. Eldersveld and Frank Freidel. 1962. ‘The Effect of Economic Conditions on Congressional Elections 1946–1958’. Review of Economics and Statistics 44 (4): 458–465. Reinhart, Carmen M., and Kenneth S. Rogoff. 2009. This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Rihoux, Benoît, Audrey Vandeleene, Lieven de Winter, Pierre Baudewyns and Serge Deruette. 2015. ‘Belgium’. European Journal of Political Research: Political Data Yearbook 54 (1): 33–43. Rogers, Jonathan. 2014. ‘A communotropic theory of economic voting’. Electoral Studies 36 (1): 107–116. Rori, Lamprini. 2016. ‘The 2015 Greek parliamentary elections: from great expectations to no expectations’. West European Politics. doi:10.1080/01402382.2016.1171577. Rosenstone, Steven J. 1982. ‘Economic Adversity and Voter Turnout’. American Journal of Political Science 26 (1): 25–46. Royed, Terry J., Kevin M. Leyden and Stephen A. Borrelli. 2000. ‘Is “Clarity of Responsibility” Important for Economic Voting? Revisiting Powell and Whitten’s Hypothesis’. British Journal of Political Science 30 (4): 669–698. Rubin, Donald B. 1978. ‘Multiple Imputations in Sample Surveys: A Phenomenonological Bayesian Approach to Nonresponse’. Proceedings of the Survey Research Methods Section of the American Statistical Association: 20–34. Rüdig, Wolfgang, and Georgios Karyotis. 2014. ‘Who Protests in Greece? Mass Opposition to Austerity’. British Journal of Political Sicence 44 (4): 487–513. Samuels, David. 2004. ‘Presidentialism and Accountability for the Economy in Comparative Perspective’. American Political Science Review 98 (3): 425–436. REFERENCES 257 Sanders, David. 2000. ‘The real economy and the perceived economy in popularity functions: how much do voters need to know? A study of British data, 1974–97’. Electoral Studies 19 (2–3): 275–294. Scharpf, Fritz W. 2013. ‘Monetary Union, Fiscal Crisis and the Disabling of Democratic Accountability’. In Politics in the Age of Austerity, edited by Armin Schäfer and Wolfgang Streeck, 108–142. Cambridge: Polity Press. Schlozman, Kay Lehman, and Sidney Verba. 1979. Injury to Insult: Unemployment, Class, and Political Response. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press. Schmitt, Hermann. 2009. ‘Multiple Party Identifications’. In The Comparative Study of Electoral Systems, edited by Hans-Dieter Klingemann, 137–157. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Schmitt, Hermann, Matthew Loveless, Sascha Adam and Daniela Braun. 2009. European Election Study 2004: Design, Data Description and Documentation. 2nd ed. Mannheim: MZES, University of Mannheim. Singer, Matthew M. 2011a. ‘When do voters actually think “It’s the Economy”? Evidence from the 2008 presidential campaign’. Electoral Studies 30 (4): 621–632. . 2011b. ‘Who Says “It’s the Economy”? Cross-National and Cross-Individual Variance in the Salience of Economic Performance’. Comparative Political Studies 44 (3): 284–312. . 2013. ‘The global economic crisis and domestic political agendas’. Electoral Studies 32 (3): 404–410. Soroka, Stuart N. 2006. ‘Good News and Bad News: Asymmetric Responses to Economic Information’. Journal of Politics 68 (2): 372–385. Soroka, Stuart, and Christopher Wlezien. 2014. ‘Economic Crisis and Support for Redistribution in the United Kingdom’. In Mass Politics in Tough Times: Opinions, Votes, and Protest in the Great Recession, edited by Nancy Bermeo and Larry M. Bartels, 105–127. New York: Oxford University Press. Stanig, Piero. 2013. ‘Political polarization in retrospective economic evalations during recessions and recoveries’. Electoral Studies 32 (4): 729–745. Stavrakakis, Yannis, and Giorgos Katsambekis. 2014. ‘Left-wing populism in the European periphery: the case of SYRIZA’. Journal of Political Ideologies 19 (2): 119–142. 258 REFERENCES Steenbergen, Marco R., and Gary Marks. 2004. ‘Introduction: Models of political conflict in the European Union’. In European Integration and Political Conflict, edited by Gary Marks and Marco R. Steenbergen, 1–10. New York: Cambridge University Press. Stegmaier, Mary, and Michael S. Lewis-Beck. 2011. ‘Shocks and oscillations: The political economy of Hungary’. Electoral Studies 30 (3): 462–467. Stevens, Daniel. 2007. ‘Mobilization, Demobilization and the Economy in American Elections’. British Journal of Political Science 37 (1): 165–186. Stevenson, Randolph T. 2001. ‘The Economy and Policy Mood: A Fundamental Dynamic of Democratic Politics?’ American Journal of Political Science 45 (3): 620–633. . 2002. ‘The economy as context: indirect links between the economy and voters’. In Economic Voting, edited by Han Dorussen and Michaell Taylor, 45–65. ECPR Studies in European Political Science 27. London: Routledge. Stevenson, Randolph T., and Raymond Duch. 2013. ‘The meaning and use of subjective perceptions in studies of economic voting’. Electoral Studies 32 (2): 305–320. Stigler, George J. 1973. ‘General Economic Conditions and National Elections’. American Economic Review 63 (2): 160–167. Stubager, Rune, Niels W. Botterill, Michael S. Lewis-Beck and Richard Nadeau. 2014. ‘Scope conditions of economic voting: The Danish exception?’ Electoral Studies 34 (1): 16–26. Swedlow, Brendon. 2008. ‘Beyond liberal and conservative: Two-dimensional conceptions of ideology and the structure of political attitudes and values’. Journal of Political Ideologies 13 (2): 157–180. Taniguchi, Masaki. 2016. ‘The multi-store model for economic voting: Rome wasn’t built in a day’. Electoral Studies 41 (1): 179–189. The Economist. 2009. ‘The European elections: Swing low, swing right’. 11 June. Accessed 21 September 2015. http://www.economist.com/node/13832286. Tibbitts, Clark. 1931. ‘Majority Votes and the Business Cycle’. American Journal of Sociology 36 (4): 596–606. Tillman, Erik R. 2008. ‘Economic Judgments, Party Choice, and Voter Abstention in CrossNational Perspective’. Comparative Political Studies 41 (9): 1290–1309. REFERENCES 259 . 2013. ‘Authoritarianism and citizen attitudes towards European integration’. European Union Politics 14 (4): 566–589. To Vima: English. 2014. ‘Alexis Tsipras: “We do not support any sort of Euroscepticism” ’. 7 May. Accessed 1 October 2015. http://www.tovima.gr/en/article/?aid= 593303. Traugott, Michael W., and John P. Katosh. 1979. ‘Response Validity in Surveys of Voting Behavior’. Public Opinion Quarterly 43 (3): 359–377. Tsebelis, George, and Geoffrey Garrett. 2000. ‘Legislative Politics in the European Union’. European Union Politics 1 (1): 9–36. Tufte, Edward R. 1975. ‘Determinants of the Outcomes of Midterm Congressional Elections’. American Political Science Review 69 (3): 812–826. . 1978. Political Control of the Economy. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Van der Brug, Wouter, Cees van der Eijk and Mark Franklin. 2007. The Economy and the Vote: Economic Conditions and Elections in Fifteen Countries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Van der Eijk, Cees, and Mark N. Franklin. 2004. ‘Potential for contestation on European matters at natioanl elections in Europe’. In European Integration and Political Conflict, edited by Gary Marks and Marco R. Steenbergen, 32–50. New York: Cambridge University Press. Van der Eijk, Cees, Hermann Schmitt and Tanja Binder. 2005. ‘Left–Right Orientations and Party Choice’. In The European Voter: A Comparative Study of Modern Democracies, edited by Jacques Thomassen, 167–191. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Van Egmond, Marcel H., Eliyahu V. Sapir, Wouter van der Brug, Sara B. Hobolt and Mark N. Franklin. 2010. EES 2009 Voter Study Advance Release Notes. Amsterdam: University of Amsterdam. Várnagy, Réka. 2010. ‘Hungary’. European Journal of Political Research 49 (7–8): 1001–1008. Verney, Susannah. 2015. ‘Waking the ‘sleeping giant’ or expressing domestic dissent? Mainstreaming Euroscepticism in crisis-stricken Greece’. International Political Science Review 36 (3): 279–295. 260 REFERENCES Weschle, Simon. 2014. ‘Two types of economic voting: How economic conditions jointly affect vote choice and turnout’. Electoral Studies 34 (1): 39–53. Whitaker, Richard. 2011. ‘United Kingdom’. European Journal of Political Research 50 (7–8): 1164–1174. Whiteley, Paul. 2016. ‘What explains electoral responses to the ‘Great Recession’ in Europe?’ Asian Journal of Comparative Politics 1 (1): 62–76. Whitten, Guy D., and Harvey D. Palmer. 1999. ‘Cross-national analyses of economic voting’. Electoral Studies 18 (1): 49–67. Wickham, Hadley. 2009. ggplot2: Elegant Graphics for Data Analysis. New York: SpringerVerlag. http://ggplot2.org. Wickham, Hadley, and Romain Francois. 2015. dplyr: A Grammar of Data Manipulation. R package version 0.4.3. https://CRAN.R-project.org/package=dplyr. Wickham, Hadley, David A. James and Seth Falcon. 2014. RSQLite: SQLite Interface for R. R package version 1.0.0. https://CRAN.R-project.org/package=RSQLite. Wilcox, Clyde, Lee Sigelman and Elizabeth Cook. 1989. ‘Some Like It Hot: Individual Differences in Responses to Group Feeling Thermometers’. Public Opinion Quarterly 53 (2): 246–257. Wilkinson, Thomas, and Hornell Hart. 1950. ‘Prosperity and Political Victory’. Public Opinion Quarterly 14 (2): 331–335. Wlezien, Christopher. 2015. ‘The myopic voter? The economy and US presidental elections’. Electoral Studies 39 (1): 195–204. Wlezien, Christopher, Mark Franklin and Daniel Twiggs. 1997. ‘Economic Perceptions and Vote Choice: Disentangling the Endogeneity’. Political Behavior 19 (1): 7–17. Wolfinger, Raymond E., and Steven J. Rosenstone. 1980. Who Votes? New Haven: Yale University Press. Woon, Jonathon. 2012. ‘Democratic Accountability and Retrospective Voting: A Laboratory Experiment’. American Journal of Political Science 56 (4): 913–930. Xu, Ronghui. 2003. ‘Measuring explained variation in linear mixed effects models’. Statistics in Medicine 22 (22): 3527–3541. REFERENCES 261 Zeglovits, Eva, and Sylvia Kritzinger. 2014. ‘New Attempts to Reduce Overreporting of Voter Turnouts and Their Effects’. International Journal of Public Opinion Research 26 (2): 224– 234.