* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download report - Standard Chartered Bank
Present value wikipedia , lookup
Financialization wikipedia , lookup
History of the Federal Reserve System wikipedia , lookup
Interbank lending market wikipedia , lookup
Monetary policy wikipedia , lookup
International monetary systems wikipedia , lookup
Interest rate wikipedia , lookup
l Global Research l Special Report – Economics Money supply – The forgotten indicator Highlights Theory and historical evidence suggest that broad money and GDP growth should be closely linked. But the link has weakened in the face of financial innovation. We examine an alternative measure of money, Divisia, and believe it can resurrect money as an indicator. Standard money supply data simply sums the components included. Divisia money weights components by their usefulness in transactions. We find support for studies that show Divisia money growth to be a good indicator of the stance of monetary policy and a useful predictor of GDP growth. Our Divisia measures are also based on broad measures of money which has a bigger impact on economic activity. We provide our own in-house estimates of Divisia money for China, the euro area, India and Japan. For China we produce our own estimates of broad money supply, M3 and M4. Our global index also includes the US and UK. We plan to provide regular updates on all six major economies. Enam Ahmed +44 20 7885 7735 [email protected] Senior Economist, Thematic Research Standard Chartered Bank Samantha Amerasinghe +44 20 7885 6625 [email protected] Economist, Thematic Research Standard Chartered Bank Chidu Narayanan +65 6596 7004 [email protected] Economist, Asia Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Acknowledgements We would like to acknowledge the contribution of John Calverley, Chief Economist, Calverley Economic Advisors Ltd. Divisia money growth is higher than two to three years ago, except in the UK; but it remains slower than pre-2008, except in Japan, suggesting that monetary conditions are still not buoyant. We believe this supports our view that the global upswing will continue but stay disappointing and that further stimulus will be necessary. Important disclosures can be found in the Disclosures Appendix All rights reserved. Standard Chartered Bank 2016 https://research.sc.com Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Contents Infographic 3 Executive summary 5 Why look at Divisia money? 5 What Divisia money growth says 5 Conclusion – Add Divisia money to your dashboard 6 Why money supply is important 8 Theory and history 8 Money supply and quantitative easing 9 How Divisia money is calculated 10 Why Divisia money is superior 12 Country studies 14 Global – Picking up but still lacklustre 14 China – Fastest rate in three years 15 Euro area – A strong bounce in 2015 16 India – Running slowly since 2012 17 Japan – Up with Abenomics 18 UK – Slower recently 19 US – Stuck in low gear 20 Why don’t central banks use Divisia? 22 Conclusion – Add Divisia to your dashboard 22 Appendix 1: The quantity theory of money 25 Appendix 2: Calculating Divisia money 27 Practical problems in calculating Divisia money Global Research Team 10 March 2016 30 32 2 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Infograph ic DIVISIA MONEY TRENDS Latest rates, % Japan Change in last 2 years Change since 2007 3.5 US 4.0 UK 6.8 Euro area 7.2 India 11.8 China 15.4 0 4 8 12 16 -4 -2 0 2 4 -12 -8 -4 0 4 OUR TAKE Japan Slow but higher than pre -crisis US Slow but up since 2013; supports our below -consensus growth forecast UK Moderate, but down since 2013 Euro area Strong, but much higher since 2013; growth surprise? India Moderate, well down on pre - crisis China Moderate, up since 2013; supports our above -consensus growth forecast Source: Standard Chartered Research 10 March 2016 3 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator CALCULATING DIVISIA MONEY Cash Checking accounts Time deposits M2 30 10 10 10 Adjusted for usefulness in transactions*, then… Cash Checking accounts Time deposits ½ Divisia M2 10 10 25 5 *Based on a benchmark rate of 4% and a time deposit rate of 2% WHY DIVISIA IS BETTER It captures the relative ‘moneyness’ of each component It can better accommodate new instruments It is a theoretically consistent approach It provides a more reliable signal of GDP trends Source: Standard Chartered Research 10 March 2016 4 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Executive summary Why look at Divisia money? Divisia money uses a sophisticated weighting mechanism Economic theory suggests that growth in broad money supply is a good gauge of monetary policy stance and likely GDP trends. In practice, financial innovation has made ‘simple sum’ (SSM) measures of money unreliable as an indicator in recent years. Divisia (named after French economist Francois Divisia, 1889-1964) money uses a sophisticated weighting mechanism to adjust for the relative ‘moneyness’ of different components, so it can take account of substitution between them, and the emergence of new instruments. This makes it a more trustworthy money indicator than official series. We find it performs much better as an indicator, and did so especially during the 2008-09 global financial crisis (GFC). We present data unavailable elsewhere In this report we present Divisia money growth estimates for six major countries. Currently neither the US nor China publish a money indicator broader than M2, but it is important to look at broad measures to gauge liquidity properly. Our data covers M4 for China, India, the UK and the US, and M3 for the euro area and Japan (though definitions vary). We use the official Divisia series for the UK, the only country to publish regular estimates, while US data is calculated by the Center for Financial Stability. The estimates for China, the euro area, India and Japan are our own. What Divisia money growth says Money growth has been weak since 2008 Divisia money has been weak despite QE Our measure of the global Divisia broad money supply (aggregating the six major countries using GDP weights) illustrates the weakness of money growth since the GFC, despite large-scale quantitative easing (QE). While central banks have been adding money by purchasing securities, private-sector deleveraging has subtracted money. Moreover, not all central bank purchases impact the broad money supply; purchases from banks may only lead to higher central bank reserves. Money is picking up, but is still lack-lustre Divisia money growth picked up in 2015, led by acceleration in the euro area and China. But the global measure, as well as the country measures (except Japan), are still growing more slowly than pre-2008 (Figures 1-2). This supports our view that the global upswing will continue but remain disappointing and more stimulus is needed. Figure 1: Global Divisia money has been weak since 2008 Divisia and simple sum money, % y/y 10 Figure 2: Divisia money is turning up except in Japan and the euro area, % y/y 30 25 8 SSM 20 CN 15 6 DM 4 IN 10 EA UK 5 JP 0 2 -5 0 2007 2008 2009 2010 Source: Standard Chartered Research 10 March 2016 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 -10 2007 US 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 Source: Standard Chartered Research 5 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator China – The fastest rate in three years Divisia is not a crystal ball, but an indicator worth watching Our measure of Divisia M4 has picked up over the last year to its fastest rate in three years (Figure 3, page 7). We believe this pick-up reflects monetary easing, including cuts in interest rates and reserve requirements as well as easing in macro-prudential measures (see Special Report, 23 November, 2015, ‘Asian housing: Ride the cycle’). This momentum supports our view that an imminent hard landing is unlikely and our above-consensus forecast of 6.8% GDP growth for 2016. Euro area – A strong bounce in 2015 Since late 2014 Divisia M3 growth has accelerated markedly, reaching 7.2% y/y (Figure 4). This surge puts money growth only slightly below the 2003-07 average and likely reflects both active QE and the recent rise in lending to the private sector. But GDP growth has been lacklustre and most indicators suggest it will remain modest: Our 2016 GDP forecast of 1.4% is close to consensus. In contrast, strong Divisia money growth could be pointing to a growth surprise. India – Running slowly since 2012 Trends in Divisia M4 fit well with the growth slowdown and the fall in the inflation rate since 2012 (Figure 5). Divisia M4 has firmed slightly over the last year, suggesting economic growth could pick up or at least continue at recent moderate rates. Japan – Up with Abenomics Growth in Divisia M3 has picked up since QE was expanded in 2013 as part of ‘Abenomics’ (Figure 6). But money growth is still only modest, suggesting QE is struggling to boost broad money. That said, our analysis finds the relationship between money and GDP in Japan is not as reliable as in other countries. UK – Slower recently In the UK, Divisia growth is a good match with GDP trends, much better than the simple-sum M4 measure. Currently Divisia M4 is growing at 6.8%, below the 7-10% growth rate seen pre-2008 and also down from the level in 2013 (Figure 7). GDP growth has indeed slowed since 2013 from 3% to about 2%. This is consistent with the Bank of England (BoE) remaining on hold, in our view. US – Stuck in low gear Our analysis finds that Divisia money fits better than official M2 with trends in GDP. US Divisia M4 is expanding at 4% currently, well below the 6-7% rate prevailing before the GFC and helping to explain why GDP growth remains disappointing (Figure 8). Slow Divisia money growth supports our below-consensus 2016 GDP forecast of only 1%, with GDP growth held down also by demand leaking abroad due to the strong US dollar. Conclusion – Add Divisia money to your dashboard Our analysis, as well as academic studies, finds that Divisia money is a good measure of monetary policy stance and a useful indicator for GDP trend. Divisia money is not a magic crystal ball, but we believe analysts should add it to their dashboard. It usually performs better than simple-sum measures. Divisia measures will likely become more important in emerging countries as financial systems deepen, widening the gap with simple sum measures. We plan to provide regular updates. 10 March 2016 6 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Figure 3: China DM4 and real GDP Figure 4: Euro-area Divisia M3 and real GDP % y/y % y/y 30 16 China DM4 14 25 12 10 12 20 10 15 8 10 6 China real GDP (RHS) 2 0 0 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2 6 0 4 -2 Euro-area DM3 2 -6 2006 2008 2010 Source: ChinaBond, Standard Chartered Research Source: Bruegel, Eurostat, Standard Chartered Research Figure 5: India Divisia M4 and real GDP Figure 6: Japan DM3 and real GDP % y/y % y/y 2012 4.5 India Divisia M4 20 2014 DM3 4.0 25 4 2 0 Japan real GDP (RHS) 1.5 1.0 India CPI India real GDP 0 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 -8 -0.5 -10 -1.0 -12 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 Source: Bloomberg, Economic and Social Research Institute Japan Figure 7: UK Divisia M4 and real GDP Figure 8: US Divisia M4 and real GDP % y/y % y/y 12 6 10 4 UK real GDP (RHS) 8 15 10 0 5 4 -2 0 2 -4 0 -6 UK DM4 -2 2003 2006 2009 Source: Bloomberg, BoE, Standard Chartered Research 2012 US DM4 incl USTs 2 6 10 March 2016 -4 0.0 Source: India Central Statistical Organisation, RBI, Standard Chartered Research 2000 -2 -6 0.5 5 6 3.0 2.0 10 8 3.5 2.5 15 -4 0 2004 30 4 8 4 5 6 Euro-area Real GDP (RHS) -8 2015 -5 US real GDP -10 1968 1971 1975 1979 1983 1986 1990 1994 1998 2001 2005 2009 2013 Source: Bloomberg, Centre for Financial Stability, BEA 7 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Why money supply is important Theory and history For transactions, people need money For more than 200 years economic theory has recognised a close link between money and GDP. One way of thinking of this is that for people to make transactions they need to get the money together first. Another is that people try to keep the ratio of their money holdings to other assets broadly constant, so if they accumulate more money relative to other assets they will seek to spend it to restore equilibrium. That said, economists since Keynes have often disputed the direction of causation between money and GDP. And since the failure of the monetarist experiments in the 1980s, many have doubted the practicality of using money as an indicator, particularly since financial innovation continues to generate new instruments that can be used for transactions (see Appendix 1 for more on the historical context). The quantity theory of money The clearest formulation of the quantity theory is usually known as the Fisher equation MV = PT or Money * Velocity = Prices * Transactions Velocity (V) is the number of times money changes hands. Note that transactions (T) include not just goods and services, i.e., GDP. It includes all transactions including financial transactions. Hence a rise in money may portend an increase in stock or house purchases. This effect can be seen in some of our analysis – e.g., the jump in US money growth in 1987 ahead of the stock-market crash of that year and again during the stock and housing bubbles around the turn of the century. While strictly speaking the Fisher equation is an accounting identity, not a causal relationship, classical theory (and monetarists) insists that a rise in M will flow through to more transactions (and eventually higher prices). Some analysts argue that an expanding money supply might have little effect because velocity may simply decline to offset it. However, this view goes against more than two centuries of theory and experience. That said, the links between money supply and the economy come with what economist Milton Friedman called ‘long and variable lags’. Simple sum money measures are unstable The practical problem with using money supply as an indicator is that since the 1980s SSMs have proven relatively unstable and not well-correlated with GDP trends. China is one of the few countries that still uses a money supply target for reference; most central banks pay little attention to money supply. Modern financial systems have too many instruments that have some degree of moneyness. Simple sum aggregation can provide misleading signals. Divisia may be the answer Divisia money could overcome some of the shortfalls of SSMs The use of Divisia measures of money addresses these problems and provides more confidence we are looking at a meaningful measure of money. This may be especially important amid current low and even negative interest rates, as the usefulness of interest rates as an indicator of the economy or policy stance is in question. For example, few people now are confident that low rates mean that monetary policy is super-stimulatory and that growth will surge. We need an alternative way to look at monetary conditions. 10 March 2016 8 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Money supply and quantitative easing QE needs to be enough to take money growth to a healthy rate Another reason for looking at money supply is that central banks are now employing QE as a stimulus technique. Many of them view QE primarily as a way to signal their intention to keep interest rates low for a long time by bringing down long-term interest rates. But its success as well as the inflation risk involved can also be judged by what happens to money growth. If broad money growth picks up to a healthy rate the amount of QE is probably about right. What is a healthy rate? For a developed economy somewhere in the 4-7% range is probably about right, in our view. For China and India a range of 10-15% may be enough to support GDP growth of 6-8%, moderate inflation and some financial deepening. QE does not necessarily boost money supply There is a more or less 1-1 relationship between central bank purchases and M0 or so-called central bank money. But broader measures of money from M1-M4 only include money in circulation, which is what affects GDP. And reserves tucked away at the central bank (included only in M0) are not in circulation. This is why the big rise in M0 since 2009 in the US and other developed countries has not brought either an economic boom or higher inflation. Unfortunately, when central banks purchase securities from banks there is no direct impact on the money supply beyond M0. Banks simply substitute reserves at the central bank for the securities they have sold. QE only raises money in circulation if the securities are purchased from non-bank institutions such as pension funds or insurance companies. The central bank directly credits those institutions’ bank accounts with newly created money. QE may have been inadequate QE was not enough to compensate for deleveraging We believe our Divisia estimates give us a good way of assessing whether the right amount of QE has been done. Evidence suggests that if anything, quantitative easing has been less than required since 2009. Money growth in the US, UK and euro area remains far less buoyant than pre-GFC. This is likely partly because too much was purchased from banks. Also QE needed to be enough to compensate for deleveraging. Especially in the immediate aftermath of the GFC, the private sector was paying down debt and banks were raising capital and trying to reduce their balance sheets. These actions have the effect of reducing the money supply. The good news is that money growth has picked up in the past year, notably in the euro area where QE began in Q1-2015. But the euro area and Japan will likely need to continue QE for a long time yet, and we cannot rule out further QE from the US and UK if growth disappoints. Money growth in the US is at the low end of our ‘healthy’ rate of 4-7%. Figure 9: Money supply components as a share of GDP % of nominal GDP, 2015 M0 M1 M2 M3 M4 China 8.7 56.0 198.4 215.4 219.8 India 10.6 17.4 17.8 80.4 81.7 Euro area 10.3 99.7 136.6 148.0 NA Japan 18.2 126.4 237.2 245.1 NA United Kingdom 4.0 - - - 84.7 United States 7.6 17.1 69.0 - - Source: Bloomberg, IMF, Standard Chartered Research 10 March 2016 9 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator How Divisia money is calculated Weighting money components by their usefulness as money Divisia money assesses the degree of ‘moneyness’ of different components Conventional measures of money supply are calculated by simply adding together the components, ranging from currency and demand deposits in M1, time deposits and money market funds in M2 and instruments such as CDs, commercial paper and short-term debt securities for broader measures such as M3 and M4 (see Appendix 2). The moneyness of each asset is assumed to be the same. In reality the degree of moneyness varies, depending on ease and convenience of use and reliability as a store of value. Currency and checking accounts are the purest form of money and are mostly held for transactions. Using time deposits for payments may incur a penalty or a delay or involve some inconvenience (such as visiting a branch). Often time deposits are intended to be held for the longer term. Securities such as commercial paper or short-term bonds can usually be sold easily but may require time for settlement and their value could change due to market or credit conditions. A theoretically robust method A theoretically robust weighting methodology Divisia money is a theoretically robust method for weighting the components of money supply according to their degree of moneyness. The technique is named after French economist Francois Divisia (1889-1964) and has been developed and championed primarily by US economist William Barnett. The weights are calculated according to the interest rate paid on each component; those which are less useful for transactions will enjoy a higher rate. Cash and checking accounts which pay zero interest have the highest weight while relatively illiquid assets that earn closer to the benchmark rate have the lowest weight. The weights will change as the structure of interest rates change, allowing Divisia money to compensate for shifts among components. How to construct a Divisia money index To calculate a Divisia index for money requires the following: Simple sum measures have been found to be unstable The amounts outstanding, and interest rates earned for each component. A ‘benchmark’ interest rate against which the rate for each component can be compared. This benchmark asset should enjoy the typical interest rate return in the economy but be relatively illiquid and not be used for transactions. The infographic on page 4 includes a simple illustration of how to calculate M2, assumed to consist of cash, checking accounts and time deposits, where the first two earn zero interest, time deposits earn 2% and the benchmark rate is 4%. M2 simply sums the three components. Divisia M2 includes only half the time deposits (calculated by taking 4/2). In practice the calculation is made using growth rates, so the weighting of the growth of time deposits is cut in half. If interest rates fell to 1% on time deposits and 3% on the benchmark asset, a higher weight is given to the growth of time deposits, two-thirds. So is the money supply suddenly larger? It depends, because people will respond to different interest rates by moving assets from one component to another. When interest rates fall people hold relatively more in demand deposits, because there is less advantage to keeping money in time deposits. 10 March 2016 10 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator A comparison of trends in US M1 and M2 with the federal funds target rate shows this behaviour clearly: M1 and M2 move in opposite directions when interest rates shift, more in M1 when rates go down and more in M2 when rates go up (Figure 10). This shift in money supply measures is one of the key reasons why simple sum money was found to be unstable in the past. The other was new instruments, which could be used for money. Choosing the benchmark rate The benchmark rate must be higher than the rates on all the components In practice it is hard to find an asset that exactly matches the requirements for the benchmark asset; most assets have some degree of liquidity, while those that have less, such as small stocks or private equity, involve high risk and volatility and are hard to value. Moreover, since the benchmark rate must not be below the rate paid on the money components (as negative moneyness makes no sense), this rules out using a long-term bond yield as the yield curve can sometimes be inverted. One approach is to use a bank lending rate (as we do for India). Another approach formerly used by the BoE is to arbitrarily add a spread to a rate, in this case local government bills plus 200bps. Yet another technique, which the BoE now uses, assumes that the benchmark asset is the component of money supply that pays the highest interest rate at any given time. Despite these difficulties, research suggests that the choice of benchmark rate is less important than it may appear because it is primarily used to measure the relative moneyness of different components. The trend of Divisia growth rates turns out to be not much affected by the choice of benchmark rates (Barnett 2011). Figure 10: M1 and M2 go in opposite directions when rates change US M1, M2 less M1 % y/y, and the federal funds target rate % 25 20 15 M1 10 5 FFTR 0 M2 - M1 -5 -10 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014 Source: US Federal Reserve, Standard Chartered Research 10 March 2016 11 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Why Divisia money is superior Better in theory In summary, Divisia monetary aggregates are better in principle than simple sum counterparts for four reasons: 1. The simple sum approach implies that all components of money stock are substitutes or alike in their moneyness, which is plainly not true. 2. Simple sum fails to take into account substitution effects in the event of a change in the relative interest rates on different monetary assets (as discussed in the example above). Simple sum aggregates especially do not cope well with extreme situations such as inverted yield curves or QE policies. 3. Using Divisia instead of simple sum overcomes many of the distortions of new monetary instruments because the degree of moneyness of the new instruments is automatically taken into account. 4. Using relative interest rates to derive the weights is a theoretically consistent approach. Better in practice too Divisia money performs better than simple sum aggregates for most countries Studies covering at least 10 countries have found that Divisia money aggregates are better than simple sum (Figure 11). Divisia money is not a magic crystal ball but it is generally found to be more reliably correlated with GDP than simple sum aggregates. Moreover, several studies find that it adds useful information for forecasters and nowcasters (gauging the state of the economy ahead of other indicators). Our investigations also find that Divisia money performs better than simple sum aggregates for most countries, though the stories vary. Our approach In our country analysis, we focus on the linkages between changes in money growth and changes in real GDP. This is a simplification of the theory that suggests that the linkage should be between nominal money growth and nominal domestic demand (GDP plus imports less exports). We present this data in Figures 28-33 for those interested. But gauging nominal trends in demand does not tell us the breakdown between real demand and prices. We believe it is better to view money growth as first influencing real growth, then after time it may influence inflation. For example weaker money growth is likely to first slow real demand growth, then lower the inflation rate. What about the distinction between domestic demand and GDP? This matters periodically, when a country sees a big change in its net export picture. For example, it is likely to be important for the US this year because the strong USD means that aggregate demand will likely be higher than GDP. But the difference is usually fairly small. Some analysts prefer to compare real money growth (after subtracting inflation) with real GDP (see Figures 34-39). 10 March 2016 12 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Figure 11: Past studies suggest Divisia is better than SSMs Studies producing Divisia Monetary Aggregates Summary 1980 Economic Monetary Aggregates: An Application of Aggregation and Index Number Theory – William Barnett Barnett’s pioneering derivation of the Divisia money formula and computation and discussion of the use of Divisia monetary aggregates. 1984 The New Divisia Monetary Aggregates – First empirical comparisons of Divisia monetary aggregates with William Barnett, Edward Offenbacher SSM in policy applications; Divisia money, especially at higher levels and Paul Spindt of aggregation, usually performs better than simple sum when tested against conventional policy-relevant criteria. 2011 How Better Monetary Statistics Could Have Signaled the Financial Crisis – William Barnett and Marcelle Chauvet Most recessions in the past 50 years were preceded by contractionary monetary policy, which is better indicated by Divisia than by SSM data. Divisia monetary aggregate growth rates were generally lower than SSM growth rates in the period preceding the mid-1980s and higher since. 2005 Divisia Money – Matthew Hancock BoE produces an improved measure of UK Divisia money and argues for its usefulness. 2014 Does Money Matter in the Euro Area? Evidence from a New Divisia Index – Zsolt Darvas (Bruegel) Money matters for output, prices and interest rates and the ECB can influence monetary developments. VAR models reveal significant euro-area output and price responses to Divisia money shocks. Divisia money reacts to user costs. Most of these results are not significant when SSM is used. 2015 Chinese Divisia Monetary Index and GDP Nowcasting – William Barnett and Biyan Tang Divisia monetary aggregates contain more indicator information than SSM aggregates; factor model produces the best available nowcasting results. Divisia money showed that China’s money supply declined at the beginning of 2010 after which the growth rates of Divisia M1, M2, M3 and M4 all steadily decreased, reflecting the tightened monetary conditions in China. 2010 Empirical evidence suggests that Divisia monetary aggregates might The Divisia Monetary Indices as Leading have an edge over SSM in a liberalised financial market regime in Indicators of Inflation – M. predicting inflation. As countries such as India continue to liberalise Ramachandran, R. Das and Binod Bhoi their interest rate structure and deepen their financial systems, Divisia measures will become more important. 2009 Divisia monetary aggregates are superior over SSM in that they Comparison of Simple Sum and Divisia perform better for the financial innovation period of the early 1980s Monetary Aggregates Using Panel Data and 1990s. Divisia seems to overcome simple sum aggregates’ Analysis – S. Celik and S. Uzun inability to react to financial innovation and provide a stable money demand function. Indonesia 2010 Financial Liberalisation and Money Demand in Indonesia: Implications for Weighted Monetary Aggregates – Hiew Lee Chea Looks at Indonesia’s monetary regime changes and the significance of Divisia monetary aggregates in shaping monetary policy in Indonesia from 1981-2005. Empirical findings indicate that Divisia monetary aggregates have proven to be superior to SSM as a useful measure of money for Indonesia. Malaysia 2008 Revisiting Money Demand in Malaysia: Simple-Sum Versus Divisia Monetary Aggregates – Chin-Hong Puah, ChoiMeng Leong et.al Attempts to determine whether Divisia monetary aggregates are superior monetary instruments in Malaysia where monetary targeting has been replaced by interest rate targeting due to the inadequacy of SSMs in predicting economic activities. Germany 2015 The Information Content of Monetary Statistics for the Great Recession: Evidence from Germany – Wenjuan Chen and Dieter Nautz Introduces a Divisia monetary aggregate for Germany. Divisia money and SSM are highly correlated in normal times but began to diverge before the 2008 crisis, suggesting that Divisia was a better predictor of the crisis. UAE 2012 Divisia Monetary Aggregates for the GCC Countries – Ryadh Alkhareif and William Barnett Divisia indexes are superior to the officially published SSM aggregates in monitoring business cycles. Divisia money provides critical information to policy makers regarding liquidity conditions. 2009 An Empirical Study of Simple Sum and Divisia Monetary Aggregation: A Comparison of their Predictive Power Regarding Prices and Output in Turkey – Dogan Karaman (PhD thesis, University of Kansas) Uses several models and methods to compare SSM and Divisia aggregates in predicting Turkish inflation and output growth in the last two decades; overall, money provides a good amount of information in predicting inflation and output in Turkey. In highinflation periods, Divisia aggregates clearly provide better information than SSM, while in low-inflation periods simple sum aggregates are a better predictor. Country Year United States United Kingdom Euro area China India Japan Turkey Source: Centre for Financial Stability, Standard Chartered Research 10 March 2016 13 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Country studies Global – Picking up but still lacklustre Our aggregate is heavily influenced by China Our global index shows weak money growth during 2009-11 We aggregate the six major countries in this study to create a global index and compare it with a global index using simple sum money in each country and also with GDP trends (all using the same aggregation methodology, see below). We find that Divisia matches GDP trends better than SSMs especially during the global financial crisis. In 2008-09, when Divisia money growth declined sharply in line with the economic slowdown, simple-sum money actually accelerated, reflecting quantitative easing (Figure 12). From 2009-11 Divisia money growth was weak, in line with the weak global recovery. It briefly approached a 7% growth rate in 2012 before slowing again. The most recent reading shows Divisia money growth of 7.6% y/y, the fastest since 2008 (Figure 13). That said, a comparison with 2008 needs to allow for the hugely increased weight for China: 21% in 2015 versus 8% in 2007. With China’s Divisia money growing at 15% compared with developed country rates of 4-6%, the aggregate rate of growth is hiding big changes in composition. (Calculated at China’s 2006 weight, global Divisia money would be growing at only 6.2%). This is another reminder of the increase in importance of policy and performance in China compared with less than 10 years ago. Still, we view the acceleration in our global Divisia aggregate since 2014 as positive, as it reflects a significant pick-up in the euro area and China. A note on the aggregation methodology We smooth exchange rate moves to avoid confusion The six countries here cover 68% of world GDP and all the major reserve currencies. To weight countries, we use market exchange rates but smooth changes over three years to avoid sharp exchange rate moves dominating money supply moves. Otherwise a sudden change in the euro (EUR) could significantly affect the global money supply in a way that we doubt makes sense in analysing the relationship between money growth and GDP. This method still allows us to capture broad shifts in economic gravity. Since 2007 the euro-area weight declined from 31% to 25%, the US from 39% to 35% and China increased from 8% to 21%. The rise of China reflects mainly its GDP growth and to a lesser extent exchange rate appreciation. The EUR exchange rate changes little over the period using our smoothing method. The large decline in weight reflects its poor GDP performance. Figure 12: Our global Divisia estimate Figure 13: Global Divisia and GDP growth Divisia and simple sum money % y/y 10 12 Divisia 8 10 6 8 SSM 4 Global GDP growth index 2 6 DM 0 4 -2 2 0 2007 -4 2008 2009 2010 Source: Standard Chartered Research 10 March 2016 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 -6 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 Source: Standard Chartered Research 14 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator China – Fastest rate in three years We publish new broad money statistics We present estimates for simple sum and Divisia M3 and M4 not published by the authorities Official money supply statistics from the Peoples Bank of China (PBoC) provide data for M1 and M2. We construct new broad money measures for China covering M3 and M4 based on a research paper by Barnett (2015). The official M2 aggregate includes currency in circulation and corporate, personal and other deposits. Our wider definitions take into account debt instruments up to three years, including commercial bank bonds, corporate bonds, commercial paper, local and central government bonds and also money market funds. The broader definitions are comparable to the broader definitions available elsewhere, including in the UK, US, and euro area. Divisia is a better fit with GDP than official M2 For China, official M2 and our calculations of Divisia M4 mostly track fairly closely but there is one major exception, in 2012 (Figures 14 and 15). Official M2 bounced strongly in that year, yet GDP did not, suggesting that official M2 gave an inferior signal. Barnett’s analysis also found that Divisia aggregates contain more indicator information than simple sum aggregates and were better at now-casting China GDP. Divisia M4 differs comparatively little from simple sum M4 (both calculated by us). But China has liberalised interest rates only recently and plans further financial-sector liberalisation. We expect this to lead to more flexibility and eventually bring the potential for greater divergence between Divisia and SSMs. That said DM4 was stronger than simple M4 in 2009-10, which probably more accurately reflected the strength of the economy then. In general as financial markets deepen in emerging markets, we expect Divisia money to diverge more from SSMs. For this reason it will be increasingly important to monitor Divisia. Divisia money is picking up China’s Divisia money growth has picked up since mid-2015, suggesting the economy may stabilise Money supply growth, both the official M2 and our Divisia M4 estimate, has picked up since the middle of 2015, suggesting that the economy may stabilise this year. This supports our view that a hard landing is unlikely and our above-consensus GDP forecast of 6.8%. The government has cut interest rates and reserve requirements, as well as stoked fiscal policy and we expect more stimulus in coming months. China has also relaxed macro-prudential policies, bringing a rise in housing-market activity (see Special Report, 23 November 2015, ‘Asian housing: Ride the cycle’). Figure 14: China Divisia M4 vs official M2 Figure 15: China Divisia M4 vs real GDP % y/y % y/y 30 30 25 20 China DM4 15 China M2 2009 2011 Source: ChinaBond, Standard Chartered Research 10 March 2016 25 25 20 20 China M4 15 15 10 10 5 2007 30 China DM4 2013 2015 5 0 2007 10 5 China real GDP 0 2009 2011 2013 2015 Source: ChinaBond, Standard Chartered Research 15 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Euro area – A strong bounce in 2015 Divisia money grew very slowly during 2010-14 Euro area Divisia grew slowly during 2010-14, underlining weak monetary conditions Divisia euro-area money supply at times differs quite markedly from its SSM counterpart, in terms of both profile and growth rate (Figure 16). In the 2004-07 period Divisia M3 did not accelerate as much as official M3, making it a better fit with real GDP growth, which was only mildly up (Figure 17). The European Central Bank (ECB) raised rates in 2006-07 and even hiked again in July 2008, despite the worsening financial crisis. The main fear was that higher oil prices would feed into inflation expectations, but the double-digit growth in simple M3 may have been a concern too. The Divisia measure, in contrast, peaked at 10% in September 2007 and slowed significantly by mid-2008. Both measures did decline significantly during and after the GFC. This is different to the experience in the UK and US, where simple sum surged initially and could be because the ECB did not do quantitative easing at the time. During 2010-14 Divisia money grew slowly, especially compared with pre-GFC growth, underlining the weakness of monetary conditions. This sluggishness suggests that the ECB should have begun QE long before it did in January 2015. Divisia is now growing at 7% Both measures of M3 have accelerated in the past 18 months, with Divisia money now growing about 7%. This puts money growth only slightly below the 2003-07 average and likely reflects both active QE and the recent rise in lending to the private sector. But GDP growth has been lacklustre and most indicators suggest it will remain modest: Our 2016 GDP forecast of 1.4% is close to consensus. In contrast strong Divisia money growth could be pointing to a growth surprise. ECB studies (2001 and 2010) and others have concluded that Divisia monetary aggregates display favourable econometric properties. The Bruegel Institute publishes quarterly estimates of euro-area Divisia M3. Its analysis comparing Divisia money with simple-sum measures reaches a number of conclusions: Divisia aggregates have impacts on euro-area output and prices, output is impacted three to nine quarters after a Divisia-money shock, the output shock is temporary, and the ECB in practice reacts to developments in monetary aggregates. When measured via SSM, the results are less meaningful. Figure 16: Euro-area M3 vs Divisia M3 Figure 17: Euro-area M3 vs real GDP % y/y % y/y 14 14 12 12 10 Euro-area DM3 8 10 8 Euro-area DM3 6 6 4 4 2 Euro-area M3 2 0 -2 2004 Euro-area M3 0 Euro-area real GDP -2 -4 2006 2008 2010 Source: Bruegel, Standard Chartered Research 10 March 2016 2012 2014 -6 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 Source: Bruegel, Eurostat, Standard Chartered Research 16 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator India – Running slowly since 2012 Divisia M4 diverges significantly from simple M4 Divisia suggests an improvement in India’s economic growth Our analysis finds that Divisia M4 (DM4) shows a closer correlation with GDP than does simple M4 (published by the Reserve Bank of India, ‘RBI’). The two series diverge in four periods (Figure 18). From late 2006 to 2008 signs of overheating in India’s economy are better captured by the Divisia measure, which was running higher. During this period India sustained GDP growth at over 8.5% and the RBI tightened policy to control inflation. In 2008-09 the growth of Divisia money fell sharply, which seems to fit well with the sharp economic slowdown at the time. In contrast, simple M4 remained high during the crisis, giving misleading signals. It likely picked up the effects of the RBI’s policy actions (multiple cuts in the cash reserve ratio and interest rates) to inject liquidity and arrest India’s declining growth rate. In April 2009 the growth in DM4 started to pick up, reflecting the economic recovery, before falling sharply when India’s growth slowed again. In contrast, simple sum M4 only rose and fell slightly. Divisia picks up trends in inflation too India differs from the other countries in this study in that there was a major change in the inflation rate during the period. Wholesale price inflation of 10-11% in 2010-12 came down to the 5-6% range in 2014 before falling even more in response to lower commodity prices. Consumer price inflation, the central bank’s target now, has also fallen significantly from 10-12% in 2009-13 to 5-6% now (Figure 19). We believe our Divisia index is broadly consistent with this trend. Moreover the volatility in our measure of DM4 seems to pick up the volatility of consumer prices during 2011-14, falling sharply, then spiking then falling again. Since 2012 both measures have moved broadly sideways in line with GDP, though DM4 has been on a slight strengthening path while simple M4 has been slowing a bit. Divisia is signalling an improvement in economic growth or at least suggests a continuing moderate pace. Figure 18: India M4 and real GDP growth Figure 19: India Divisia M4 and headline inflation % y/y % y/y 30 30 25 25 20 20 15 M4 DM4 10 15 India DM4 10 India CPI 5 Real GDP 0 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 Source: RBI, Bloomberg, CEIC, Standard Chartered Research 10 March 2016 5 0 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 Source: RBI, Bloomberg, Standard Chartered Research 17 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Japan – Up with Abenomics Divisia differs little from simple money We are not convinced that faster growth in Japan’s Divisia points to stronger GDP growth Data limitations and the flatness of Japan’s yield curve mean that when we estimate Divisia money differentiation between assets is limited. The series therefore differs little from simple money (Figure 20). That said, the trends in Japanese money are hard to interpret. Japan’s economy grew quite solidly during 2003-07 (averaging about 1.75% p.a. despite the declining labour force) and deflation even eased up, with core CPI climbing to zero in early 2008. Yet money growth slowed in this period and even went negative in 2007 (Figure 21). The expected relationship with GDP growth is missing One possible reason for this weak money growth is that the Bank of Japan (BoJ) ended its first QE programme in 2005 (it began in 2001) and cut the size of its balance sheet in 2006). Still, the expected linkage to GDP is lacking for Japan. So, while faster growth of Divisia money in the last two years is encouraging, it is difficult to be confident that this points to stronger GDP growth or higher inflation. Moreover, despite substantial QE, with the BoJ balance sheet much larger as percentage of GDP than the that in the US or euro area, the fact that broad money is still growing ‘only’ 4% suggests scope for an even faster pace of QE. Figure 20: Japan DM3 vs M3 Figure 21: Japan DM3 and real GDP % y/y % y/y 5 4 8 6 DM3 3 SM3 2 1 5 DM3 4 4 4 2 3 3 0 -2 -4 2 Real GDP (LHS) -6 2 1 1 -8 0 -10 -1 -1 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 -12 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 -1 Source: Bloomberg, Standard Chartered Research Source: Bloomberg, Economic and Social Research Institute Japan 0 10 March 2016 18 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator UK – Slower recently In the UK Divisia money seems to fit much better with economic trends than SSMs such as M4 (Figures 22 and 23). During the early 2000s upswing DM4 remained solid in the 7-10% range from 2001 until late 2007. In contrast, simple M4 showed a distinct uptrend in 2005-07. Yet economic growth did not accelerate in this period. Headline inflation and wages picked up a little but house-price growth slowed. It is not clear that the acceleration in simple M4 was a useful signal. The base rate was raised significantly in 2006-07 but monetary policy may have been too lax throughout the period, as is implied by DM4 growing at a high 7-10%, rather than that monetary tightening was especially warranted in 2006-07. Divisia has performed especially well since 2007 Since 2007, DM4 has been a better indicator in the UK Since 2007 DM4 has been a much better indicator than simple M4. DM4 growth began to slow in 2007 and slumped to near zero well ahead of the Lehman bankruptcy, correctly signalling the recession. In contrast, simple M4 slowed slightly in 2007 but remained high and then soared during 2008-09, giving misleading signals as it picked up the effects of liquidity provision and quantitative easing. In 2010 DM4 recovered to growth of about 5%, reflecting the initial economic upswing, before falling back again when UK growth slowed during the 2011-12 euro crisis. Simple M4 slumped to below zero in early 2011, again distorted by financial conditions. Since then it has roughly followed the same profile as DM4 but whereas DM4 has averaged growth around 6%, consistent with the solid recovery since then, simple M4 has ranged around 0%. The most recent Divisia growth rate is slightly lower than two years ago, again consistent with the slowdown to around 2% GDP growth currently from 3% previously. Figure 22: UK Divisia M4 vs real GDP Figure 23: UK Divisia M4 vs real GDP % y/y % y/y 12 20 UK DM4 10 15 8 6 2 5 0 0 -2 UK M4 -4 -5 UK real GDP -6 -8 1991 UK Divisia M4 10 4 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 Source: Bloomberg, BoE, Standard Chartered Research 10 March 2016 2009 2012 2015 -10 2000 2005 2010 2015 Source: Bloomberg, BoE, Standard Chartered Research 19 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator US – Stuck in low gear Money supply is largely ignored The strength in US DM4 suggests economic growth will continue in 2016 In the US simple money aggregates like M2 have proven unhelpful in understanding the economy especially in the short and medium term, and neither the Federal Reserve (Fed) nor most private economists pay much attention to these measures. The Fed no longer even publishes broader measures of money, such as M3. Yet Divisia M4 (DM4) calculated by the Centre for Financial Stability does seem to perform much better than M2 historically (see Barnett 2011). In particular, the two measures diverged sharply during two crucial episodes: the monetarist experiment in 1979-82 and the GFC (Figures 24-25). DM4 correctly signalled the double-dip recessions in 1980-82 The US monetarist experiment beginning in November 1979 aimed to bring inflation down gradually without a recession by targeting reduced money growth. It was abandoned in November 1982 after two recessions in two years, which occurred despite buoyant M2 growth. But DM4 did signal both recessions, suggesting that by focusing on simple money measures, the Fed erred with overly tight policy. Simple M2 growth gave false signals in 2008-09 and 2012 The most recent big divergence has been since 2007 (Figure 26). At the height of the crisis in late 2008, M2 soared, reflecting the various emergency liquidity measures taken by the Fed and the first round of QE beginning in November 2008. But DM4 collapsed, reflecting the economic slump, a much more useful signal. M2 surged to show growth of almost 10% in the first half of 2012, suggesting a robust recovery and even supporting some inflation concerns. DM4 was much weaker, particularly in H1 2012, correctly signalling the sluggish nature of the recovery and the need for QE3, which duly began in September 2012. Divisia money is still growing slower than pre-2008 In the past two years DM4 has picked up a bit but at 4% y/y is still at the floor of our suggested healthy range of 4-7%. It is also well below the 6-8% range prevailing pre2008. The recent pick-up suggests a new recession, as some have feared, will likely be avoided. But the strength of the US dollar means that some spending in the US will leak abroad. Overall the weakness of Divisia money growth combined with the strong USD supports our below-consensus GDP forecast of 1% for 2016. Figure 24: US official M2 vs Divisia M4 Figure 25: US official M2 vs Divisia M4 since Jan 2006 % y/y % y/y 15 12 US M2 10 10 US M2 8 6 4 5 2 0 0 -5 -2 US DM4 exUSTs SA -4 -6 -8 US DM4 exUSTs SA -10 1968 1973 1978 1983 1988 1993 1998 2003 2008 2013 -10 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 Source: Bloomberg Source: Bloomberg 10 March 2016 20 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Divisia and the USD We find a good relationship between money trends and the major multi-year swings in the US dollar over the past 40 years (Figure 27). When money growth is accelerating, the trade-weighted index tends to be rising and vice-versa. The intuition here is straightforward. Accelerating money supply growth occurs when the economy is strengthening; this also tends to be when the US dollar is strong. However the relationship between money growth and exchange rates is complex because it depends on whether the change in money growth is caused by increased money demand (as in the US case) or increased money supply (as in the case of Japan in recent years). Japan’s QE programme, promising faster money growth, led to a sharp fall in the exchange rate. Because of these complications and also because a full analysis of exchange rates requires looking at relative money growth between different countries, we leave the subject for future discussion. Figure 26: US Divisia M4 vs real GDP growth Figure 27: US Divisia M4 vs USD trade-weighted index % y/y 15 140 US DM4 excl Treasuries 10 US real TWI 120 15 10 100 5 0 -5 US real GDP -10 1968 1973 1978 1983 1988 1993 1998 2003 2008 2013 Source: Bloomberg, Centre for Financial Stability, BEA 10 March 2016 80 5 60 0 40 20 US DM4 incl USTs 2 yr mov avg (RHS) 0 1973 1976 1980 1984 1987 1991 1995 1998 2002 2006 2009 2013 -5 -10 Source: Bloomberg, Centre for Financial Stability, BEA 21 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Why don’t central banks use Divisia? Despite the evidence for its usefulness, only the UK’s central bank regularly publishes Divisia data. While others have looked at it, Divisia has yet to catch on in a major way either in central banks or academic circles. Money supply is out of fashion. We think there are six reasons for this: 1. Modern economic theory, the so-called Keynesian-Neoclassical synthesis, uses only a short-term interest rate to link the financial sector to the real economy, (though this proved hopelessly inadequate in 2008 when models based on this theory had no way to incorporate a financial crisis). 2. When theorists go beyond the interest rate they tend to focus on credit more than money. Former Fed Chairman Bernanke based his prior academic career on the case that credit rather than money is the key to the economy. And the Bank for International Settlements, which is critical of standard theory, also emphasises the credit cycle rather than money trends. 3. The monetarist experiments in the late 1970s and early 1980s left an institutional distaste in many central banks for focusing on money. They believe that the inflation-targeting regime, perhaps supplemented by macro-prudential measures, is the best approach. And, with fears that money trends can be misleading, especially in the short and medium run, central banks are reluctant to draw much attention to money. 4. Concerns remain that financial innovation can confuse trends and that Divisia money might not neutralise the effect. 5. Calculations of Divisia money can be hard to explain and may appear to be a ‘black box’. See Appendix 2 for a further discussion of this issue 6. Even if Divisia money has outperformed in the past, it remains to be seen whether it can still work well with low or negative interest rates and flat yield curves. Our research suggests that it is effective, but it is early days. The case of Japan is a concern. Conclusion – Add Divisia to your dashboard Central banks should pay more attention to Divisia money Our findings suggest that using Divisia estimates instead of simple-sum measures significantly improves money growth as an indicator. The method of estimating makes it a theoretically more trustworthy indicator of trends in money growth and it can be used as a guide both to monetary policy stance and GDP trend. Significant acceleration or deceleration in Divisia growth rates (2-3ppt or more) seem to presage moves up or down in the GDP growth rate. Particularly slow money growth, of 4% or below, seems to correlate with disappointingly slow GDP growth, while fast growth rates of 7% or more in developed countries (as prior to 2008) or rates of 20% or more in China and India are associated with overheating economies. Divisia is not a magic crystal ball, but it looks like a useful indicator to monitor alongside the usual closely watched activity and survey data. We hope central banks will pay more attention as more data on the components of money supply and the interest rates they earn could improve the precision of Divisia estimates. We plan to provide regular updates and keep a close eye on Divisia. 10 March 2016 22 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Figure 28: China Divisia and domestic demand Figure 29: Euro area Divisia and domestic demand % y/y, annual avg Divisia growth rate % y/y 30 15 25 10 20 5 DM4 15 Euro area DM3 0 -5 10 Domestic demand 5 0 2008 -10 Domestic demand -15 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 Source: ChinaBond, National Bureau of Statistics, Standard Chartered Research Source: Eurostat, Standard Chartered Research Figure 30: India Divisia and domestic demand Figure 31: Japan DM3 and nominal aggregate demand % y/y, INR bn % y/y 18 2,500 16 6 4 2,000 14 12 1,500 India DM4 10 5 Domestic demand (RHS) 2 DM3 3 0 SM3 -2 8 1,000 6 Domestic demand (RHS) 4 2 500 0 2012 2013 2014 -4 1 0 -10 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2015 Source: RBI, Bloomberg, Standard Chartered Research Source: Ministry of Finance Japan, Standard Chartered Research Figure 32: UK Divisia and domestic demand Figure 33: US DM4 and domestic demand % y/y % y/y 12 20 UK DM4 2 -6 -8 0 2011 4 -1 15 15 10 10 8 5 6 US DM4 incl Treasuries 10 5 0 4 2 0 -2 2000 -5 Domestic demand (RHS) -10 -5 Domestic demand -15 -20 2003 2006 Source: Eurostat, Standard Chartered Research 10 March 2016 0 2009 2012 2015 -10 2000 2001 2002 2003 2005 2006 2007 2008 2010 2011 2012 2013 2015 Source: Bloomberg, Standard Chartered Research 23 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Figure 34: China real Divisia and real GDP Figure 35: Euro-area real Divisia and real GDP % y/y % y/y 30 10 8 25 6 20 4 Real Divisia 15 Real GDP 2 0 10 -2 5 0 2007 Real Divisia Real GDP 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 -4 -6 -8 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 Source: ChinaBond, Standard Chartered Research Source: Bloomberg, Standard Chartered Research Figure 36: India real Divisia and real GDP Figure 37: Japan real Divisia and real GDP % y/y % y/y 25 8 6 20 Real Divisia (using WPI) 15 Real Divisia 4 2 0 10 -2 Real GDP 5 -6 -8 0 -5 2005 Real GDP -4 -10 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 -12 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 Source: India Central Statistical Organisation, RBI, Standard Chartered Research Source: Bloomberg, Economic and Social Research Institute Japan Figure 38: UK real Divisia and real GDP Figure 39: US real Divisia and real GDP % y/y % y/y 10 2014 15 8 Real Divisia 10 6 4 Real Divisia 5 2 Real GDP 0 0 -2 -4 Real GDP -5 -6 -8 2000 2003 2006 2009 Source: Bloomberg, BoE, Standard Chartered Research 10 March 2016 2012 2015 -10 1968 1973 1978 1983 1988 1993 1998 2003 2008 2013 Source: Bloomberg, Centre for Financial Stability, BEA 24 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Appendix 1: The quantity theory of money Quantity theory used to be central to economics Central bankers lost faith in the simple measures of money supply Until the 1930s the quantity of money was a major focus of economics. Famous monetary theorists including Hume, Ricardo, Marshall, Fisher and Keynes (in his earlier writings) argued that a rise in the money supply led to increased economic growth in the short run, though in the long run GDP would fall back leaving only a rise in the price level. The workings of the Gold Standard were much studied and seen as operating through changes in the money supply and in wages. The publication of Keynes’ ‘General Theory’ in 1936 transformed economic theory by suggesting that, at least in times of inadequate aggregate demand, wages might not adjust properly and even active monetary policy (freed from the constraints of the Gold Standard) might be incapable of restoring growth (Keynes 1936). Instead expansionary fiscal policy would be needed. Theory after Keynes has continued to emphasise the key role of aggregate demand. Changes in interest rates, which would influence aggregate demand, became both the instrument and measure of monetary policy, in place of the quantity of money. The monetarist revival For a brief period in the 1970s and early 1980s the quantity theory came back to the forefront of economics during the monetarist experiments. Central banks in the US, UK and Europe tried to target the growth of money supply with the aim of gradually bringing down high inflation without a recession. For a few years money supply releases became the most-watched economic indicator, moving markets in a way that employment or purchasing managers indices do today. Inflation did come down (under the guidance of Paul Volcker at the Fed and Margaret Thatcher in the UK) but only at the expense of severe recessions and high unemployment. Meanwhile the targeted quantities (principally M2 in the US and Sterling M3 in the UK), proved unpredictable and unstable. Within a few years monetarism was abandoned and mainstream theory shifted back to the focus on interest rates, increasingly ignoring money supply trends. Why did monetarism fail? There were several reasons for the failure of monetarism. If a particular measure of money is targeted it becomes unreliable as an indicator of economic trends (known as Goodheart’s law after monetary theorist Charles Goodheart). This is because investors know it is targeted and seek to make money from the expected central bank response, which distorts the outcome. Meanwhile, during the monetarist experiments interest rates were high and volatile, again changing money demand and supply in ways that models were unable to predict. Finally the 1970s and 1980s was also the beginning of a period of rapid financial innovation, partly due to deregulation but also in response to high interest rates, high inflation and monetary targeting itself. New liquid assets appeared and holdings grew rapidly, including money market funds and various shortterm securities. Central bankers lost faith in the meaning of simple measures of money supply and concentrated instead on interest rates. In the 2010s interest rates are no longer a reliable signal In past cycles, low interest rates were a clear signal that monetary policy was expansionary and the economy should strengthen. Today, amid fears that demand is so weak that interest rates cannot be pushed low enough, low interest rates are not necessarily a signal of coming expansion, or a reliable policy instrument. 10 March 2016 25 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator QE and the money supply QE has played an important role but more may be needed Although central banks have actively used quantitative easing, they have generally understood this in terms of interest rates not the quantity of money, despite the name. (QE is only the modern name for what used to be called ‘open market operations’, a standard policy in the past.) In the US QE1 was widely seen as an exercise to bring down credit spreads, particularly on mortgage securities, as a way of boosting growth. It is generally seen as a major success. QE2 and QE3, introduced when credit spreads were more normal, have been heavily criticized and remain controversial, as does ongoing QE in Japan and the euro area. Standard theory takes it that the driver of spending decisions is expected future real short-term interest rates. So QE is seen as a tool to help drive down expected future interest rates and is used alongside inflation targets and explicit forward guidance, as the BoJ and ECB do today. Central banks have therefore looked at the impact of QE on long-term interest rates as an indicator of success, since long-term rates can be seen as the sum of future short term rates. But if QE is expected to boost growth prospects and future inflation then it should raise long-term bond yields, not cut them. So trying to gauge the success of QE by looking for a fall in bond yields is flawed. Using money supply to judge QE effectiveness Since bond yields are misleading, a better approach theoretically is to look at the impact on money supply. Here some analysts made a basic mistake. They saw the rise in the monetary base, which is caused by QE (on essentially a one-for-one basis), as hugely inflationary. But the monetary base consists largely of reserves tucked away at the central bank. These excess reserves have no influence on the economy (and are not included in money supply measures such as M1 to M4). Classical theory is quite clear that these broader measures, that is money in circulation, are what matters. QE only directly increases the money supply (M1 upwards) in two circumstances. One is if the bonds are purchased from non-bank entities such as pension funds or insurance companies, in which case the central bank pays the seller in newly created money. The other is if the bonds are purchased from banks and the banks respond with new lending and/or purchases of securities from non-banks. Unfortunately, if central banks purchase bonds from banks who simply replace them with reserves at the central bank, there is no increase in broad money and no economic effect. In principle, a good way to measure whether QE is effective is to see whether broad money is expanding. Bear in mind that if the private sector is deleveraging or banks are ultra-conservative, broad money could decline. As people repay bank loans or banks raise their capital ratios banks shrink both their assets and liabilities. Hence QE has to be enough to offset this if money supply is to rise. As discussed above, our findings are that money supply growth, properly measured by Divisia, has picked up but remains well below pre-2007 levels. This suggests that QE has played an important role but more may be needed. 10 March 2016 26 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Appendix 2: Calculating Divisia money Calculating Divisia Divisia money is calculated as a weighted average of the growth rate of the different components of money supply. The weights for the components are determined by their usefulness for making transactions, which is proxied by the user cost of holding these assets. The user cost of a component is measured by the difference between the benchmark rate, which is the post-tax interest rate paid on balances with no use for transactions, and the post-tax interest rate paid on the component balance. Divisia money supply growth is therefore calculated as follows: ∆Dt N = Dt–1 ∑ i=1 1 ∆Mi,t 2 (Wi,t + Wi,t–1) Mi,t–1 Wi,t = Mi,t (rB,t – ri,t) N ∑ Mi,t (rB,t – ri,t) i=1 Where: Mi = the level of the ith money holding Wi = the weight on the ith component rB = the rate on the benchmark asset ri = the rate on the ith asset. Figure 40: Definitions of money supply Lowest measure of money supply that includes component Component Currency in circulation Demand deposit/other checkable deposits Savings deposits China Euro area India Japan UK US M0 M0 M0 M0 M0 M0 M1 M1 M1 M1 M4 M1 M1 M1 M4 M3 M1 M4 M2 Time deposits M2 Foreign currency deposits M3 M2 (deposits redeemable at a period of notice up to 3 months) Other deposits Money market funds Repurchase agreement M3 (SC) M2 (quasi-money) M4 M4 M2 (money market accounts, retail money market funds), M3 (institutional money market mutual funds) M3 M4 M2 M3 M3 M2 (post office savings deposits), M4 (other post office deposits) Postal savings deposit Certificate of deposit Debt instruments M3 M3 M3 (SC): Central bank bonds, Policy bonds, Commercial bank bonds, M3 (debt corporate bonds, securities up commercial paper, to 2 years) T-bills), M4 (SC): Treasury bonds, local government M4 (bonds, commercial paper, FRNs, instruments M4-(commercial of up to and paper), M4 including five (T-bills) years original maturity, bank bills) Source: Standard Chartered Research 10 March 2016 27 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Divisia money growth produced by Standard Chartered Bank (SC) Figure 41: China Money supply Components Interest rate for Divisia calculation Source M0 (official) Currency in circulation Assumed zero People’s Bank of China M0 Corporate demand deposits M1 Corporate deposits Personal deposits Other deposits M2 Central bank bonds Policy bank bonds Commercial bank bonds Corporate bonds Commercial paper Money market funds M3 Treasury bonds Local government bonds Corporate demand deposit People’s Bank of China 3-month time deposit People’s Bank of China Central bank bill rate Inter-bank policy bank bond yield Inter-bank commercial bank bond yield Chinabond corporate bond yield Inter-bank commercial paper yield One-day interbank repo-rate Inter-bank treasury bond yield Chinabond local government security yield China Central Depository and Clearing Corporation Limited M1 (official) M2 (official) M3 (SC) M4 (SC) Benchmark rate WIND Bloomberg China Central Depository and Clearing Corporation Limited Short term corporate bond yield + 100 bps Source: Standard Chartered Research Figure 42: India Money supply Components Interest rate for Divisia calculation Source M0 (official) Currency in circulation Assumed zero Reserve Bank of India (RBI) Prime lending rate RBI M1 (official) M2 (official) M0 Deposit money of the public (includes demand deposits with Banks and other deposits with Banks) M1 + Post Office Savings Deposits Post Office savings Bank account rate 1 year time deposit rate Average of 1yr and 3 yr time deposit rates 3 yr time deposit rate 5 yrs and above time deposit rate M3 (official) M1 + time deposits with banks M4 (official) M3 + total Post Office deposits Post Office time deposit account rate Benchmark rate Prime lending rate RBI State Bank of India RBI Source: Standard Chartered Research Figure 43: Euro area Money supply M1 (official) M2 (official) M3 (official) Benchmark rate Components Interest rate for Divisia calculation Source Currency in circulation Overnight deposits M1 Deposits with agreed maturity of 2 years Deposits redeemable at a period of notice up to 3 months M2 Repurchase agreements Money market funds Debt securities up to 2 years Currency rate assumed zero Overnight deposit rate European Central Bank (ECB) The rate on deposits with agreed maturity of 2 years The rate on deposits redeemable at notice of up to three months ECB The rate on repurchase agreements Eonia rate BofA Merrill Lynch 1-3 year Euro Financial Index ECB Bloomberg BofA Merrill Lynch 1-3 year Euro Financial Index + 100 bps Source: Standard Chartered Research 10 March 2016 28 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Figure 44: Japan Money supply Components M0 Currency in circulation M1 M3 Currency in circulation + demand deposits M1 + quasi-money (household) Quasi-money (corporate) M2 + CDs Benchmark rate Average rate on short-term loans, city banks M2 Interest rate for Divisia calculation Assumed zero Assumed zero 2-3 yr deposit rate 3m deposit rate CD rate Source Bank of Japan Source: Standard Chartered Research Divisia money growth produced by others Figure 45: UK Money supply M0 (official) M4 (official) Components Currency in circulation Banks operational deposits with the Bank of England M0 Deposits (including certificate of deposits) Commercial paper Bonds FRNs and other instruments of up to and including five years of original maturity issued by UK MFIs Repos Bank bills Divisia Divisia M4 produced by Bank of England Source: Standard Chartered Research Figure 46: US Money supply Components M0 (official) Currency in circulation M1 (official) M2 (official) M3 (Centre for Financial Stability) M4- (Centre for Financial Stability) M4 (Centre for Financial Stability) M0 Demand deposits Travellers’ checks Checkable deposits M1 Money market accounts Retail money market funds Certificate of deposits M2 Large time deposits Institutional money market mutual funds balances Deposits of euro dollars Repurchase agreements M3 Commercial paper M4T-bills Divisia Centre for Financial Stability produces Divisia M1, Divisia M2, Divisia M3 and Divisia M4 Source: Standard Chartered Research 10 March 2016 29 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Practical problems in calculating Divisia money While we have made every effort to calculate useful data there are some practical difficulties in estimating Divisia, where more central bank data could help: 1. Data availability issues. Full breakdowns of different instruments and their interest rates are not always available, especially for long time series. Sometimes simplifying assumptions have to be made, for example applying the interest rate on one-year time deposits to all time deposits. 2. Bundled services. The interest rate may not always be the full return on a particular instrument. For example checking accounts often provide free transaction services and automatic overdraft facilities. Time deposits sometimes have complex introductory teaser rates or even gifts (from toasters to telephone minutes). 3. Choice of the benchmark interest rate. The Benchmark interest rate is often difficult to choose or not easy to fully justify. That said, Divisia growth money trends (if not rates) are not unduly sensitive to this because what matters is the relative moneyness of each asset. 4. No allowance for adjustment time and costs. As discussed above, when interest rates change, Divisia money automatically changes the weights on components but in practice, asset holdings are only adjusted over time, which may be partly due to inertia and partly to costs of switching. Divisia assumes that assets holdings are always at their desired values. This means that trends in Divisia can only be watched over time; short-term moves may be misleading. Figure 47: Divisia and our forecasts % y/y Divisia money growth Divisia money growth (latest) 2012-14 average GDP forecast 2016 Consensus forecast 2016 China 15.4 14.2 6.8 6.5 Euro area 7.7 3.5 1.4 1.6 India 11.8 10.3 7.6 7.4 Japan 3.5 2.9 1.0 0.9 United Kingdom 5.4 5.2 1.9 2.1 United States 3.8 3.3 1.0 2.2 Source: Standard Chartered Research 10 March 2016 30 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator References Barnett W and Chauvet M, Financial Aggregation and Index Number Theory, World Scientific, 2011. Barnett W and Biyan Tang, ‘Chinese Divisia Monetary Index and GDP Nowcasting’, University of Kansas and Centre for Financial Stability, New York, October 2015. Darvas Z, ‘Does Money Matter in the Euro Area? Evidence from a New Divisia Index’, Bruegel Working Paper 2014/12, November 2014 (updated April 2015). Hancock M, ‘Divisia money’, Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 2005. Ramachandran M and Rajib Das et. al., ‘The Divisia Monetary Indices as Leading Indicators of Inflation’, Department of Economic Analysis and Policy, Reserve Bank of India, 2010. 10 March 2016 31 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Global Research Team Management Team Dave Murray, CFA +65 6645 6358 Marios Maratheftis +971 4508 3311 Head, Global Research [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Chief Economist [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Thematic Research Madhur Jha +44 20 7885 6530 Enam Ahmed +44 0207 885 7735 Samantha Amerasinghe +44 20 7885 6625 Senior Economist, Thematic Research [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Senior Economist, Thematic Research [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Economist, Thematic Research [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Global Macro Strategy Eric Robertsen +65 6596 8950 Mayank Mishra +65 6596 7466 Head, Global Macro Strategy and FX Research [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Macro Strategist [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Economic Research Africa Asia Razia Khan +44 20 7885 6914 David Mann +65 6596 8649 Chief Economist, Africa [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Chief Economist, Asia [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Victor Lopes +44 20 7885 2110 Southeast Asia Senior Economist, Africa [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Greater China Shuang Ding +852 3983 8549 Head, Greater China Economic Research [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank (HK) Limited Edward Lee Wee Kok +65 6596 8252 Kelvin Lau +852 3983 8565 Head, ASEAN Economic Research [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Senior Economist, HK [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank (HK) Limited Jeff Ng +65 6596 8075 Betty Rui Wang +852 3983 8564 Economist, SEA [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Economist, NEA [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank (HK) Limited Chidu Narayanan +65 6596 7004 Se Yan +86 10 5918 8302 Economist, Asia [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Senior Economist, China [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank (China) Limited Usara Wilaipich +662 724 8878 Lan Shen +86 10 5918 8261 Senior Economist, Thailand [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank (Thai) Public Company Limited Economist, China [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank (China) Limited Aldian Taloputra +62 21 2555 0596 Tony Phoo +886 2 6603 2640 Senior Economist, Indonesia [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Indonesia Branch Senior Economist, NEA [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank (Taiwan) Limited South Asia Korea Anubhuti Sahay +91 22 6115 8840 Chong Hoon Park +82 2 3702 5011 Head, South Asia Economic Research [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, India Head, Korea Economic Research [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Korea Limited Senior Economist, Latam [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank NY Branch Saurav Anand +91 22 6115 8845 Kathleen B. Oh +82 2 3702 5072 Economist, South Asia [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, India Economist, Korea [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Korea Limited Europe Middle East and North Africa Sarah Hewin +44 20 7885 6251 Dima Jardaneh +971 4 508 3591 Bilal Khan +92 21 3245 7839 Chief Economist, Europe [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Head of Economic Research, MENA [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Senior Economist, MENAP [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank (Pakistan) Limited Achilleas Chrysostomou +44 20 7885 6437 Carla Slim +971 4 508 3738 Philippe Dauba-Pantanacce +44 20 7885 7277 Economist, Europe [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Economist, MENA [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Senior Economist, Global Political Analyst [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Sarah Baynton-Glen +44 20 7885 2330 Economist, Africa [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Edward Cheng +44 20 7885 5284 Economist, Africa [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Emmanuel Kwapong +44 20 7885 5840 Economist, Africa [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank The Americas Mike Moran +1 212 667 0294 Head, Economic Research, The Americas [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank NY Branch Thomas Costerg +1 212 667 0468 Senior Economist, US [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank NY Branch Italo Lombardi +1 212 667 0564 10 March 2016 32 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator FICC Research Rates Research Credit Research FX Research Kaushik Rudra +65 6596 8260 Kaushik Rudra +65 6596 8260 Eric Robertsen +65 6596 8950 Head, Rates & Credit Research [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Head, Rates & Credit Research [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Head, Global Macro Strategy and FX Research [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Nagaraj Kulkarni +65 6596 6738 Shankar Narayanaswamy +65 6596 8249 Robert Minikin +44 20 7885 8674 Senior Asia Rates Strategist [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Head, Credit Strategy & Financials [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Head, Asian FX Strategy [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Arup Ghosh +65 6596 4620 Bharat Shettigar +65 6596 8251 Eimear Daly +44 20 7885 6162 Senior Rates Strategist [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Head, IG/Sovereign Credit Research [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch G10 FX Strategist [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Lawrence Lai +65 6596 8261 Jaiparan Khurana +65 6596 7251 Nick Verdi +1 646 845 1279 Asia Rates Strategist [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Credit Analyst, IG/Sovereign [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Senior FX Strategist [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank NY Branch Hee Eun Lee +65 6596 8690 Simrin Sandhu +65 6596 6281 Devesh Divya +65 6596 8608 Asia Rates Strategist [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Senior Credit Analyst, Financials & ME Corporates [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Asia FX Strategist [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Becky Liu +852 3983 8563 Nikolai Jenkins, CFA +65 6596 8259 Eddie Cheung +852 3983 8566 Senior Asia Rates Strategist [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank (HK) Limited Credit Analyst, Financials [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Asia FX Strategist [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank (HK) Limited John Davies +44 20 7885 7640 Zhi Wei Feng +65 6596 8248 Lemon Zhang +65 659 69498 US Rates Strategist [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Head, HY Credit Research [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch [email protected] Analyst, FX Research / Global Macro Strategy Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Samir Gadio +44 20 7885 8618 Chun Keong Tan, CFA +65 6596 8257 Head, Africa Strategy [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Credit Analyst, HY [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Eva Murigu +25 42 0329 4004 Jiacheng Chen +65 6596 8710 Africa Strategist [email protected] Standard Chartered Investment Services Kenya Limited Credit Analyst, HY [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Flows Research Melinda Kohar +65 6596 9543 Michael Trounce +44 20 7885 2058 Senior Strategist, Flows Research [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Credit Strategist [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Commodities Research Paul Horsnell +44 20 7885 6913 Head, Commodities Research [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Nicholas Snowdon +44 20 7885 2276 Metals Analyst [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Yuhan Xia +44 207 8858670 Commodities Analyst [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank Suki Cooper +1 212 667 0319 [email protected] Precious Metals Analyst Standard Chartered Bank NY Branch Priya Balchandani +65 6596 8254 Energy Analyst [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Serene Shang Yi Lim +65 6596 6064 Energy Analyst [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch Judy Zhu +86 21 6168 5016 Metals Analyst [email protected] Standard Chartered Bank, Singapore Branch 10 March 2016 33 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator This page is intentionally blank. 10 March 2016 34 Special Report – Economics: Money supply – The forgotten indicator Disclosures appendix Analyst Certification Disclosure: The research analyst or analysts responsible for the content of this research report certify that: (1) the views expressed and attributed to the research analyst or analysts in the research report accurately reflect their personal opinion(s) about the subject securities and issuers and/or other subject matter as appropriate; and, (2) no part of his or her compensation was, is or will be directly or indirectly related to the specific recommendations or views contained in this research report. On a general basis, the efficacy of recommendations is a factor in the performance appraisals of analysts. Global Disclaimer: Standard Chartered Bank and/or its affiliates (“SCB”) makes no representation or warranty of any kind, express, implied or statutory regarding this document or any information contained or referred to in the document. The information in this document is provided for information purposes only. It does not constitute any offer, recommendation or solicitation to any person to enter into any transaction or adopt any hedging, trading or investment strategy, nor does it constitute any prediction of likely future movements in rates or prices, or represent that any such future movements will not exceed those shown in any illustration. The stated price of the securities mentioned herein, if any, is as of the date indicated and is not any representation that any transaction can be effected at this price. While reasonable care has been taken in preparing this document, no responsibility or liability is accepted for errors of fact or for any opinion expressed herein. The contents of this document may not be suitable for all investors as it has not been prepared with regard to the specific investment objectives or financial situation of any particular person. Any investments discussed may not be suitable for all investors. Users of this document should seek professional advice regarding the appropriateness of investing in any securities, financial instruments or investment strategies referred to in this document and should understand that statements regarding future prospects may not be realised. Opinions, forecasts, assumptions, estimates, derived valuations, projections and price target(s), if any, contained in this document are as of the date indicated and are subject to change at any time without prior notice. Our recommendations are under constant review. The value and income of any of the securities or financial instruments mentioned in this document can fall as well as rise and an investor may get back less than invested. Future returns are not guaranteed, and a loss of original capital may be incurred. Foreign-currency denominated securities and financial instruments are subject to fluctuation in exchange rates that could have a positive or adverse effect on the value, price or income of such securities and financial instruments. Past performance is not indicative of comparable future results and no representation or warranty is made regarding future performance. While we endeavour to update on a reasonable basis the information and opinions contained herein, there may be regulatory, compliance or other reasons that prevent us from doing so. Accordingly, information may be available to us which is not reflected in this material, and we may have acted upon or used the information prior to or immediately following its publication. SCB is not a legal, regulatory, business, investment, financial and accounting and/or tax adviser, and is not purporting to provide legal, regulatory, investment, financial and accounting and/or tax advice. Independent legal, regulatory, business, investment, financial and accounting and/or tax advice should be sought for any queries relating to the legal, regulatory, business, investment, financial and accounting and/or tax implications of any investment. SCB and/or its affiliates may have a position in any of the securities, instruments or currencies mentioned in this document. SCB and/or its affiliates or its respective officers, directors, employee benefit programmes or employees, including persons involved in the preparation or issuance of this document may at any time, to the extent permitted by applicable law and/or regulation, be long or short any securities or financial instruments referred to in this document and on the SCB Research website or have a material interest in any such securities or related investments, or may be the only market maker in relation to such investments, or provide, or have provided advice, investment banking or other services, to issuers of such investments and may have received compensation for these services. SCB has in place policies and procedures and physical information walls between its Research Department and differing public and private business functions to help ensure confidential information, including ‘inside’ information is not disclosed unless in line with its policies and procedures and the rules of its regulators. Data, opinions and other information appearing herein may have been obtained from public sources. SCB expressly disclaims responsibility and makes no representation or warranty as to the accuracy or completeness of such information obtained from public sources. SCB also makes no representation or warranty as to the accuracy nor accepts any responsibility for any information or data contained in any third party’s website. You are advised to make your own independent judgment (with the advice of your professional advisers as necessary) with respect to any matter contained herein and not rely on this document as the basis for making any trading, hedging or investment decision. SCB accepts no liability and will not be liable for any loss or damage arising directly or indirectly (including special, incidental, consequential, punitive or exemplary damages) from the use of this document, howsoever arising, and including any loss, damage or expense arising from, but not limited to, any defect, error, imperfection, fault, mistake or inaccuracy with this document, its contents or associated services, or due to any unavailability of the document or any part thereof or any contents or associated services. This material is for the use of intended recipients only and, in any jurisdiction in which distribution to private/retail customers would require registration or licensing of the distributor which the distributor does not currently have, this document is intended solely for distribution to professional and institutional investors. Country-Specific Disclosures – If you are receiving this document in any of the countries listed below, please note the following: United Kingdom and European Economic Area: SCB is authorised in the United Kingdom by the Prudential Regulation Authority and regulated by the Financial Conduct Authority and the Prudential Regulation Authority. This communication is not directed at Retail Clients in the European Economic Area as defined by Directive 2004/39/EC. Nothing in this document constitutes a personal recommendation or investment advice as defined by Directive 2004/39/EC. Australia: The Australian Financial Services Licence for Standard Chartered Bank is Licence No: 246833 with the following Australian Registered Business Number (ARBN: 097571778). Australian investors should note that this communication was prepared for “wholesale clients” only and is not directed at persons who are “retail clients” as those terms are defined in sections 761G and 761GA of the Corporations Act 2001 (Cth). Bangladesh: This research has not been produced in Bangladesh. The report has been prepared by the research analyst(s) in an autonomous and independent way, including in relation to SCB. THE SECURITIES MENTIONED IN THIS REPORT HAVE NOT BEEN AND WILL NOT BE REGISTERED IN BANGLADESH AND MAY NOT BE OFFERED OR SOLD IN BANGLADESH WITHOUT PRIOR APPROVAL OF THE REGULATORY AUTHORITIES IN BANGLADESH. Any subsequent action(s) of the Recipient of these research reports in this area should be subject to compliance with all relevant law & regulations of Bangladesh; specially the prevailing foreign exchange control regulations. Botswana: This document is being distributed in Botswana by, and is attributable to, Standard Chartered Bank Botswana Limited which is a financial institution licensed under the Section 6 of the Banking Act CAP 46.04 and is listed in the Botswana Stock Exchange. Brazil: SCB disclosures pursuant to the Securities Exchange Commission of Brazil (“CVM”) Instruction 483/10: This research has not been produced in Brazil. The report has been prepared by the research analyst(s) in an autonomous and independent way, including in relation to SCB. THE SECURITIES MENTIONED IN THIS REPORT HAVE NOT BEEN AND WILL NOT BE REGISTERED PURSUANT TO THE REQUIREMENTS OF THE SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION OF BRAZIL AND MAY NOT BE OFFERED OR SOLD IN BRAZIL EXCEPT PURSUANT TO AN APPLICABLE EXEMPTION FROM THE REGISTRATION REQUIREMENTS AND IN COMPLIANCE WITH THE SECURITIES LAWS OF BRAZIL. China: This document is being distributed in China by, and is attributable to, Standard Chartered Bank (China) Limited which is mainly regulated by China Banking Regulatory Commission (CBRC), State Administration of Foreign Exchange (SAFE), and People’s Bank of China (PBoC). Germany: In Germany, this document is being distributed by Standard Chartered Bank Germany Branch which is also regulated by the Bundesanstalt für Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht (BaFin). Hong Kong: This document, except for any portion advising on or facilitating any decision on futures contracts trading, is being distributed in Hong Kong by, and is attributable to, Standard Chartered Bank (Hong Kong) Limited 渣打銀行(香港)有限公司 which is regulated by the Hong Kong Monetary Authority. India: This document is being distributed in India by Standard Chartered Bank, India Branch (“SCB India”). SCB India is a branch of SCB, UK and is licensed by the Reserve Bank of India to carry on banking business in India. SCB India is also registered with Securities and Exchange Board of India in its capacity as Merchant Banker, Investment Advisor, Depository Participant, Bankers to an Issue, Custodian etc. For details on group companies operating in India, please visit https://www.sc.com/in/india_result.html. The particulars contained in this document are for information purposes only. This document does not constitute an offer, recommendation or solicitation to any person to execute any transaction with SCB India. Certain information or trade ideas in this document may not be specifically permissible under Indian regulations; hence, users of this document should seek professional legal advice before acting on any information. Indonesia: The information in this document is provided for information purposes only. It does not constitute any offer, recommendation or solicitation to any person to enter into any transaction or adopt any hedging, trading or investment strategy, nor does it constitute any prediction of likely future movements in rates or prices or represent that any such future movements will not exceed those shown in any illustration. Japan: This document is being distributed to Specified Investors, as defined by the Financial Instruments and Exchange Law of Japan (FIEL), for information only and not for the purpose of soliciting any Financial Instruments Transactions as defined by the FIEL or any Specified Deposits, etc. as defined by the Banking Law of Japan. Kenya: Standard Chartered Bank Kenya Limited is regulated by the Central Bank of Kenya. This document is intended for use only by Professional Clients and should not be relied upon by or be distributed to Retail Clients. Korea: This document is being distributed in Korea by, and is attributable to, Standard Chartered Bank Korea Limited which is regulated by the Financial Supervisory Service and Financial Services Commission. Macau: This document is being distributed in Macau Special Administrative Region of the Peoples' Republic of China, and is attributable to, Standard Chartered Bank (Macau Branch) which is regulated by Macau Monetary Authority. Malaysia: This document is being distributed in Malaysia by Standard Chartered Bank Malaysia Berhad only to institutional investors or corporate customers. Recipients in Malaysia should contact Standard Chartered Bank Malaysia Berhad in relation to any matters arising from, or in connection with, this document. Mauritius: Standard Chartered Bank (Mauritius) is regulated by both the Bank of Mauritius and the Financial Services Commission in Mauritius. This document should not be construed as investment advice or solicitation to enter into securities transactions in Mauritius as per Securities Act 2005. New Zealand: New Zealand Investors should note that this document was prepared for “wholesale clients” only within the meaning of section 5C of the Financial Advisers Act 2008. This document is not directed at persons who are “retail clients” as defined in the Financial Advisers Act 2008. This document does not form part of any offer to the public in New Zealand. NOTE THAT SCB IS NOT A “REGISTERED BANK” IN NEW ZEALAND UNDER THE RESERVE BANK OF NEW ZEALAND ACT 1989. Pakistan: The securities mentioned in this report have not been, and will not be, registered in Pakistan, and may not be offered or sold in Pakistan, without prior approval of the regulatory authorities in Pakistan. Philippines: This document may be distributed in the Philippines by, Standard Chartered Bank (Philippines) which is regulated by the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (Telephone No. (+63) 708-7701, Website: www.bsp.gov.ph). This document is for information purposes only and does not constitute, and should not be construed as an offer to sell or distribute in the Philippines securities that are not registered with the Securities and Exchange Commission unless such securities are exempt under Section 9 of the Securities Regulation Code or such offer or sale qualifies as an exempt transaction under Section 10 thereof. Singapore: This document is being distributed in Singapore by SCB Singapore branch and/or Standard Chartered Bank (Singapore) Limited, provided that research reports relating to certain products may be distributed only to accredited investors, expert investors or institutional investors, as defined in the Securities and Futures Act, Chapter 289 of Singapore. Recipients in Singapore should contact SCB Singapore branch or Standard Chartered Bank (Singapore) Limited (as the case may be) in relation to any matters arising from, or in connection with, this document. South Africa: SCB is licensed as a Financial Services Provider in terms of Section 8 of the Financial Advisory and Intermediary Services Act 37 of 2002. SCB is a Registered Credit Provider in terms of the National Credit Act 34 of 2005 under registration number NCRCP4. Thailand: This document is intended to circulate only general information and prepare exclusively for the benefit of Institutional Investors with the conditions and as defined in the Notifications of the Office of the Securities and Exchange Commission relating to the exemption of investment advisory service, as amended and supplemented from time to time. It is not intended to provide for the public. UAE: For residents of the UAE – Standard Chartered Bank UAE does not provide financial analysis or consultation services in or into the UAE within the meaning of UAE Securities and Commodities Authority Decision No. 48/r of 2008 concerning financial consultation and financial analysis. UAE (DIFC): SCB is regulated in the Dubai International Financial Centre by the Dubai Financial Services Authority. This document is intended for use only by Professional Clients and Market Counterparties and should not be relied upon by or be distributed to Retail Clients. United States: Except for any documents relating to foreign exchange, FX or global FX, Rates or Commodities, distribution of this document in the United States or to US persons is intended to be solely to major institutional investors as defined in Rule 15a-6(a)(2) under the US Securities Exchange Act of 1934. All US persons that receive this document by their acceptance thereof represent and agree that they are a major institutional investor and understand the risks involved in executing transactions in securities. Any US recipient of this document wanting additional information or to effect any transaction in any security or financial instrument mentioned herein, must do so by contacting a registered representative of Standard Chartered Securities (North America) Inc., 1095 Avenue of the Americas, New York, N.Y. 10036, US, tel + 1 212 667 0700. WE DO NOT OFFER OR SELL SECURITIES TO U.S. PERSONS UNLESS EITHER (A) THOSE SECURITIES ARE REGISTERED FOR SALE WITH THE U.S. SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION AND WITH ALL APPROPRIATE U.S. STATE AUTHORITIES; OR (B) THE SECURITIES OR THE SPECIFIC TRANSACTION QUALIFY FOR AN EXEMPTION UNDER THE U.S. FEDERAL AND STATE SECURITIES LAWS NOR DO WE OFFER OR SELL SECURITIES TO U.S. PERSONS UNLESS (i) WE, OUR AFFILIATED COMPANY AND THE APPROPRIATE PERSONNEL ARE PROPERLY REGISTERED OR LICENSED TO CONDUCT BUSINESS; OR (ii) WE, OUR AFFILIATED COMPANY AND THE APPROPRIATE PERSONNEL QUALIFY FOR EXEMPTIONS UNDER APPLICABLE U.S. FEDERAL AND STATE LAWS. Any documents relating to foreign exchange, FX or global FX, Rates or Commodities to US Persons, Guaranteed Affiliates, or Conduit Affiliates (as those terms are defined by any Commodity Futures Trading Commission rule, interpretation, guidance, or other such publication) are intended to be distributed only to Eligible Contract Participants are defined in Section 1a(18) of the Commodity Exchange Act. Zambia: Standard Chartered Bank Zambia Plc is licensed and registered as a commercial bank under the Banking and Financial Services Act Cap 387 of the laws of Zambia and is regulated by the Bank of Zambia, the Lusaka Stock Exchange and the Securities Exchange Commission. © Copyright 2016 Standard Chartered Bank and its affiliates. All rights reserved. All copyrights subsisting and arising out of all materials, text, articles and information contained herein is the property of Standard Chartered Bank and/or its affiliates, and may not be reproduced, redistributed, amended, modified, adapted, transmitted in any form, or translated in a ny way without the prior written permission of Standard Chartered Bank. Document approved by Document is released at Marios Maratheftis Chief Economist 14:12 GMT 10 March 2016 10 March 2016 35