Download The Denouement: China Enters Lost Decade

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Balance of payments wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
e Denouement: China Enters Lost Decade
Anusar Farooqui*
September
* Department
,
of Mathematics, McGill University, Montreal QC H A B . Email:
[email protected]
Abstract
China’s asset price bubble is rapidly unraveling despite Beijing’s frantic efforts to
stem the tide. Before long, China is likely to enter a full-scale financial panic;
followed by secular stagnation that may last as long as Japan’s lost decade.
e
Chinese panic marks the third round of crises since
; the first being the panic
of
centered at the US; the second, the eurozone crisis of
.
All three have been driven by the systematic unraveling of global imbalances.
We have previously argued that global imbalances are the result of the highsavings strategies pursued by Germany, Japan, and China. What is unfolding in
China and global markets in the summer of
, is nothing short of the denouement of China’s high-savings strategy. In what follows, I will show why this is to be
expected and argue that China is entering into its lost decade; with vast implications
for global markets and the balance of power in Asia.
eory of large open economies
In an isolated economy without a financial sector, equilibrium national income, y∗ ,
is implicitly determined by equating desired saving and investment,
I(y) = S(y).
( )
Introducing a money market, we obtain the familiar IS-LM equations with two
endogenous variables: national income and the interest rate.
I(r, y) = S(r, y),
( )
L(r, y) = M(r, y),
( )
where L and M are the demand and supply of loanable funds. In other words, the
LM curve, equation ( ), shows the combinations of national income and the interest
rate for which the money market clears. e simultaneous solution of equation ( )
and equation ( ) determines the equilibrium interest rate r∗ and national income
y∗ .
e Mundell-Fleming model is an extension of the IS-LM model for a small
open economy in an international order with perfect capital mobility; and hence, a
single global interest rate. e economy is small in the sense that developments in
the economy have no perceptible effect on the global interest rate. is assumption
effectively means that the interest rate rw is given exogenously. Assuming that
there is a single currency in the national and international economy, one obtains
the governing equation for national income y,
S(y) = I(y) + X(y),
( )
where X(y) is the net capital outflow (“net exports” or “excess savings”).
Now consider an isolated bipolar system consisting of two open economies trading with each other. Assume again for the sake of brevity that both use the same
currency. We then have a set of three equations that determine the national incomes
of the two poles as well as the global interest rate.
S1 (r, y1 , y2 ) = I1 (r, y1 , y2 ) + X1 (r, y1 , y2 ),
( )
S2 (r, y1 , y2 ) = I2 (r, y1 , y2 ) + X2 (r, y1 , y2 ),
( )
0 = X1 (r, y1 , y2 ) + X2 (r, y1 , y2 ),
( )
where yi is national income of country i = 1, 2 and r is the global interest rate.
Equations ( ) and ( ) require the difference between domestic desired savings and
investment to be equal to net exports of the country. Equation ( ) follows from the
balance of payments identity under the bipolar assumption.
Figure : Saving, investment, and trade balance in a bipolar system
r
r
r
IUS S
IChina
SChina ŜChina
US
XChina X̂China
r∗
r∗∗
.
a cb
d
S, I
′ ′
′
ca b d
′
S, I
X∗ X∗∗
−XUS
X
It is possible to introduce exchange rates, along with money market (LM) equations for the two countries. We will keep the model straightforward and investigate
the interaction in the absence of monetary intervention and exchange rate movements.
Figure ( ) displays the comparative statics of an exogenous upward shift of the
savings in one country (“China”) on the equilibrium interest rate and the balance
of payments in the bipolar system described by equations ( - ).
e left panel
shows China’s saving and investment at given levels of the global interest rate; the
middle one shows the saving and investment in the United States; and the right
panel displays the excess savings of China (XChina ) and the United States trade
deficit (−XUS ). As a result of the bipolar assumption, the gaps between saving
and investment must match up between the two countries.
us, China’s initial
′
′
excess savings (b − a ) and the US’ initial excess savings (b − a ) are both equal in
′
′
magnitude to the trade balance (X∗ ). Similarly, |d − c | = |d − c | = |X∗∗ |.
An outward shift of China’s savings curve (from SChina to ŜChina ) is reflected
in the balance of payments, the figure on the right.
e savings shock pushes out
China’s excess savings curve to the right (from XChina to X̂China ). e new equilibrium features a larger current account surplus in China (equivalently, a larger current
account deficit in the United States). e larger the shift, the large the trade imbalance. China has effectively pushed its unwanted savings out to the United States
and imported demand. is is the essence of China’s high-savings strategy.
e new equilibrium interest rate is lower than before the exogeneous savings
shock.
is was the source of Greenspan’s conundrum—the failure of long-term
rates to rise despite monetary tightening—that Ben Bernanke called the “global
savings glut.” e lowering of the global interest rate causes an expansion of investment in both the United States and China, both of which are higher than before
′
′
the exogenous savings shock (c > a , d > b ).
China’s high-savings strategy
ere is nothing particularly novel about China’s high-savings strategy. Other
states, most notably Japan, have followed essentially the same strategy. Namely,
push down consumption and channel the high savings into growth enhancing investments. e basic weapons in the underconsumptionist arsenal are financial repression, wage suppression, and underpricing of the national currency. Since
,
Beijing has deployed all three with gusto.
China practices a strong form of financial repression.
e People’s Bank of
China (PBoC) administers ceilings for interest rates on deposits and floors for lending rates. is ensures comfortable interest rate spreads for banks and keeps the cost
of capital low for firms. In
, the average loan in China was taken out at
. per cent, compared to . per cent in the nineties. e repression of interest
rates is effectively a tax on households and a subsidy for borrowers—the state and
state-backed firms, exporters, and real estate developers. e low rates have allowed
an investment boom of unprecedented proportions.
China has a vast reserve army of workers, around
million strong, who are
underemployed in the traditional sector. is has naturally kept wages from growing rapidly; in accordance with the familiar Lewis model. However, China’s wage
suppression is also the result of conscious draconian policies. For example, migrant
Chinese workers from the interior, who work illegally in the coastal areas, have no
legal recourse against their employers. And Beijing is always quick to respond with
police power at the first sign of labor unrest. e result is that real wages have grown
slower than productivity.
When a central bank intervenes to keep the currency undervalued, it accumulates the reserve currency. China’s stupendous pile of trillion dollars in official
reserves attests to the scale of the PBoC’s efforts to keep the renminbi down. e
appreciation of the renminbi is no more than what would be natural of a developing country—the so called Balassa-Samuelson effect. Because the PBoC has
not allowed the renminbi to appreciate at anywhere near the market-clearing pace,
China has continued to accumulate foreign exchange reserves at a rapid clip.
China’s high savings strategy has driven its consumption rate down to a mindboggling
per cent of GDP, if the World Bank numbers for
are to be believed. By comparison, the United States consumes
per cent of GDP; while
Germany and Japan, both high-savings countries, consume per cent and per
cent of GDP respectively. Meanwhile, China’s gross investment rate is per cent
of GDP; another record. e gross investment rate in the United States is
per
cent, while the German investment rate is
per cent and the Japanese is
per
cent. However, unlike the other poles in the center of the world economy, China
is a developing country. Its rate of investment ought to be higher. Still, a country
investing nearly half its national income is likely to be misallocating capital on a
massive scale. is is indeed the case, as we shall see presently.
e bottomline is that China’s savings rate far exceeds its investment rate. is
means that China has been pushing its unwanted savings onto its trade partners—
the United States above all—and importing demand; in accordance with the theoretical analysis of the previous section. is crucial observation means that while
China’s growth model may be called export-led or investment-led, in terms of its
impact on the global economy, it is more properly called a high-savings strategy.
e denouement
e collapse of global demand in the aftermath of the Western financial crises meant
that China could no longer rely on importing demand from its major trade partners; especially Europe. Beijing’s immediate response was to cut interest rates and
launch a six-hundred billion dollar stimulus channeled through state-owned enterprises (SOEs). Money poured into infrastructure and housing; exacerbating the
overinvestment in these sectors. While the fiscal stimulus may have been enough
to buoy up investment demand in the short run, a one-off injection was always
unlikely to solve China’s demand deficit problem even in the medium term.
e real solution hit upon by China—and here again it was following in Japan’s
footsteps—was to expand debt. Between
and
, China’s overall debt grew
from
per cent to
per cent of GDP, or about trillion dollars. An estimated
per cent of it is held by shadow banks. Lending by shadow banks has grown at
per cent since
; compared to per cent for bank lending. Meanwhile private
debt-to-GDP ratio rose from
per cent to
per cent. By comparison, US
private debt-to-GDP peaked at
per cent in the depths of the Great Recession.
e unprecedented expansion of debt yielded a supermassive asset price bubble;
most especially in real estate. More than half of China’s ballooning debt, about
per cent, is tied to property.
Before the Chinese financial panic began this summer, China’s stock market
had more than doubled in value in the preceding twelve months.
e Shanghai
Composite Index rose from around ,
in July
, to above ,
in June
.
But the real bubble was not in the stock market—it was centered on real estate.
Since
, land prices have increased fivefold. In
alone, real estate prices rose
per cent. e scale of overinvestment in China’s real estate is truly stupendous.
In just two calendar years,
and
, China produced more cement than the
United States did in the entire twentieth century. China has billion square feet—
five years’ worth of annual demand—of new property coming online. With demand
falling instead of rising, the real estate bubble began to pop at the beginning of
.
Proceeds from land sales plunged
per cent compared to the year before. New
home prices fell for four straight months and are down per cent year on year.
In China, unlike in all other polar economies, the government owns almost
all the land and two-thirds of its productive assets. Local governments enjoy a
monopoly over the supply of land by controlling the opening of agricultural land
to urban development. Proceeds from land sales account for the bulk of the revenues of local governments. For instance, land sales accounted for
per cent of
local government revenues in
. But most of the cash in the coffers of local
governments comes from loans secured through shell companies using public land
as collateral. ere is an obvious limit to debt expansion on the backs of overvalued
marginal land: It can only go on so long as the real estate bubble keeps inflating.
Once land prices started falling, local government borrowing and debt settlement became difficult; to put it mildly. Beijing’s response was to push a massive
debt swap. Local governments would issue nearly half-a-trillion-dollars worth of
long-term bonds and retire an equivalent amount of risky short-term debt. While
this is a step in the right direction, the scale of the toxic debt hidden in opaque
off-balance sheet vehicles is unknown.
In
, China announced that private investors may take minority positions
in the roughly one hundred and fifty thousand state-backed firms.
is has exacerbated the distortion of the economy in favour of the inefficient state sector. e
borrowing costs of state-backed firms is significantly lower than private firms so
that they have cornered the capital that would otherwise flow to the more productive counterparts in the private sector.
Beijing’s trilemma
Beijing wants to avoid a full-blown financial crisis, rebalance the economy away
from dependence on exports, and keep up growth rates.
e hard truth is that
there is no way to achieve all three objectives. Indeed, Beijing will be hard-pressed
to accomplish even one of the above.
e immediate problem facing policymakers in Beijing is the slow-motion bursting of the asset price bubble. Beijing has already tried direct intervention in the
stock market. Less well-known is the manipulation of land prices by local governments—
by getting pairs of state-backed firms to buy and sell at inflated prices. Both efforts
have largely failed so far. Even if these and other measures do succeed in propping
up asset prices, they will exacerbate the deeper problems facing the economy—the
build-up of toxic debt in the shadow banking system, the massive overinvestment
in property, and the misallocation of resources with the attendant slowdown in
productivity—which will further lower growth rates.
Many observers suggest that China has enough firepower— trillion dollars’
worth—to hold the tide in a financial panic. However, China cannot deploy its
reserves at any appreciable scale without considerably strengthening the renminbi
and absorbing a large negative demand shock through the external account. As
the panic continues to built this autumn, Beijing might very well be forced to take
this route. A massive appreciation of the renminbi would indeed accomplish a
rebalancing and perhaps even avoid a full-blown financial crisis. But it would be do
so at a considerable cost: Growth rates under this scenario will be sharply lower;
perhaps even negative.
Some have argued that Beijing has demonstrated considerable skill in managing economic shocks. e central government has indeed moved deftly to deal with
demand shocks. As a rule, this has been accomplished by directing state banks to
expand lending and pushing state-backed firms and local governments to expand
investment. But expanding investment is not a solution to a crisis of overinvestment. All that can hope to accomplish is to perhaps postpone the day of reckoning.
And when the crash finally comes, it would be even bigger than otherwise.
Maintaining high growth rates in the medium term will be especially hard. e
chief obstacle to maintaining high growth rates is the considerable misallocation of
resources. e overinvestment in property is likely to take years to work itself out.
State-backed firms have cornered the lion’s share of resources at the expense of
more efficient private firms.
is distortion is unlikely to unwind by itself due to
the backing of the state. Indeed, it is getting worse as of writing. Both of these distortions will have to reverse for growth prospects in the medium term to brighten.
Growth will also be harder to maintain unless the build-up of toxic debt is taken
care of.
is is best done in one fell swoop. It would require Beijing to transfer
these debts onto its own balance sheet. e central government debt is thereofore
likely to balloon—yet again, following in Japan’s footsteps.
e
-pound gorilla in the room is of course rebalancing the economy away
from its dependence on external demand.
is would require an unwinding of
China’s high savings strategy. As argued above, China’s high savings are the result
of financial repression, wage suppression, and an undervalued exchange rate. In
order to rebalance the economy, China must liberalize interest rates, raise wages,
and let the renminbi appreciate. Rebalancing would significantly reduce growth
rates down to perhaps per cent per annum. But on the bright side, real household
income would rise at a faster clip; leaving people actually better off despite the
slowdown in the economy. It would also contribute to the global recovery.
e ideal strategy for Beijing is to therefore to avoid a full-blown financial panic
and rebalance the economy at the expense of growth rates. However, it is hard to
see policymakers in Beijing pursuing this strategy for the simple reason that all the
heavy-weights in the Party have very close ties to the beneficiaries of China’s high
savings strategy. e rank and file of the Party is also unlikely to be anywhere close
to being enthusiastic about a strategy that promises a growth rate of per cent per
annum. Beijing’s policy response is therefore likely to be muddled and rudderless.
China is unlikely to sustain high growth rates for the foreseeable future. Given
the weight of China in the world economy, the implications for global markets are
dire. e ride ahead will be bumpy. Despite the recovery in the United States, the
Fed will find it impossible to exit the zero lower bound in September and perhaps
even December. e party is officially over.
Notes
Including the exchange rate means that we need two equations to determine the equilibrium
exchange rate and national income. e second equation is then the balance of payments.
One can think of country as “rest of the world” and think of this model as one of a large open
economy; large in the sense that large domestic shocks have a perceptible effect on the global interest
rate.
e recent slowdown in productivity growth even as wages have continued growing temper this
conclusion.
US private debt-to-GDP has declined to
per cent since the financial crisis as firms and
households have rebuilt their balance sheets.