Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
MAJ 2015 GROWTH OPPORTUNITIES IN EUROPE Rappor t udarbejdet af Copenhagen Economics for Axcelfuture Priorities for Growth in the EU: The Main Danish Export Market Helge Sigurd Næss-Schmidt, May 2015 An economic shock hit the World in 2008 including the countries in the European Union (EU) with EU GDP dropping by over 4 per cent from 2008 to 2009. The impact of the crisis has been markedly different across EU countries and so has the speed of recovery. Current forecast suggest that EU as a whole may only be back on track by 2018, i.e. GDP hitting the same structural level given unchanged policies in labour and product markets. This matters for the Danish Economy. Faster growing markets outside the EU is becoming increasingly important for Danish firms, but the EU market is still projected to account for around 60 per cent of exports by the end of this decade. So policy measures aiming to speed up the EU recovery and improve its long term potential matters for the Danish economy and its firms. At the national level labour market reforms will be a key to success. Some countries such as Spain and Italy with notoriously structural problems in their labour markets, notably high costs associated with adjusting the labour force to actual production has taken the crisis as an opportunity to reform. Other countries such as France have been slower to react. As a whole, progress has been patchy with respect to labour market reforms. By contrast, more reforms have been undertaken across the board to make business related regulation more growth friendly, including easing conditions for startups. At the EU level, the focus has been on containing the crisis, especially given the high risk of contagion related to weak balance sheets for governments and financial institutions, notably in Southern Europe. Banks have been forced to improve their capital base while governments are being insistently asked to reduce public deficits, preferably with reforms that boost growth and bring fiscal consolidation at the same time. It would be fair to say that reform efforts in the banking sector – not the least recapitalisation of banks and focus on bail-in of investors – took a long time to get done. That is especially when comparing to the US. EU growth has suffered from this belated approach. Passing a corner in the recovery process, the incoming Juncker Commission has launched a number of initiatives to refocus on growth potential: (1) a € 315 billion EU investment plan to mobilise new private sources of finance for infrastructure investments (2) A Capital Market Union to reduce the high reliance on bank financing for EU firms and tap much more into risk capital products such as bond and equity financing and (3) some more general relaunch of the Internal Market. There are many good ideas in these proposals, but as always the devil is in the detail. 1 The Main Danish Export Market 1 The EU’s Twin Economic Deficits: Matters for Denmark The shock that hit the EU economy has been followed by now 7 years of meagre growth and left the region as a whole with two deficits that have begun to unwind only recently. First, following bubbles in a number of countries – particularly related to real estate and consumer spending – a slack development was seen from 2009 and onwards with substantial underuse of productive capacity (capital and labour). Projections from late 2014 still suggest that the so-called negative output gap, i.e. production below potential, will remain in the order of 1 per cent of GDP by the end of 2016, cf. Figure 1. Furthermore, as discussed below, such projections mask considerable variation across the EU countries. Second, the collapse in economic activity has been followed by a marked overall deterioration of public finances. Public debt as a share of GDP in EU has risen as a result of high net public borrowing, which jumped to over 6 per cent of GDP in 2009 and is projected to stay high in the future, cf. Figure 1 (negative net lending). Figure 1. Output gaps and government net lending (EU-28) % 4 2 0 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 -2 -4 -6 -8 Output gap Note: Government net lending to GDP Output gap of the EU-28 in 2010 market prices. Government net lending to GDP for the EU-28. Before 2010 net lending is not consistently available for Poland, Lithuania, Greece and Estonia. These countries are only included in the years where data is available. Source: European Commission’s AMECO database. The drop in economic activity has been followed by a massive shedding of labour and cut-back in investments. Unemployment in 2015 remains around 11 per cent while investment’s share of total production (GDP) has fallen well below historical norms, especially in the southern Euro-area countries, cf. Figure 2. 2 The Main Danish Export Market Figure 2. Investments to GDP National investments to GDP 26% 24% 22% 20% 18% 16% 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 Euro-area (12) Note: Southern Euro-area Core Euro-area North America National investments are defined as gross fixed capital formation at current prices: total economy. The core Euro-area countries are defined as Germany, France, Austria and Benelux. The Southern Euro-area countries are defined as Spain, Greece, Italy and Portugal. Source: European Commission’s AMECO database. Both the impact of the crisis and the ability of EU countries to re-ignite growth have been very unevenly distributed across the region. Figure 3 below maps EU countries in both dimensions (impact of the crisis measured as the increase in the output gap from 2008 to 2009 and pace of recovery measured as the reduction of the output gap from 2009-2016). Somewhat surprisingly, countries that are now facing the most pressing problems with public finances and weak growth such as France, Italy, Portugal, and Spain only saw a weak or intermediate slowdown in the their economies from 2008 to 2009 but further reductions in output gap later on. Conversely, countries that were largely affected in the beginning of the crisis such as Sweden, Ireland and Germany with output gaps shrinking more than 6 per cent initially have since rebounded. Greece and Estonia are in their own categories as opposite extremes: Greece with a relative modest impact at the start of the crisis and a near collapse later, Estonia with by far the largest impact at the start of the crisis but also the strongest rebound later. 3 The Main Danish Export Market Figure 3. Impact of crisis and strengths of recovery, 20082016 Note: Initial impact of the crisis is measured as the percentage change in the output gap 2008-2008, and the strength of recovery is measured as the percentage change in output gap 2009-2019. All are measured in 2010 market prices. Countries with a black dot use the Euro, countries with a red dot use a floating currency, and countries with a blue dot use a currency with a fixed (or partly fixed) exchange rate vis-à-vis the Euro. The grey break even line signifies a return to 2008 output gab levels. Countries to the north-east of this line (none) perform better relative to their potential than in 2008. Greece, Slovenia, and Estonia are very far behind. Source: OECD Economic Outlook no. 96, November 2014. Five countries – Poland, UK, Sweden and Germany (and the US) – are expected to be nearly back on track in 2016 in terms of having the same output gap as before the crisis. This is indicated by how close they are to the sloping line in Figure 3, which indicate the combinations of initial changes in output gap from 2007 to 2008 that is exactly compensated by subsequent recovery from 2009 to 2016. It is worth noting that four of the five countries have floating exchange rates (all countries with red dots in Figure 3 have floating exchanges rates). This may be as much driven by a higher underlying degree of flexibility in these countries and other specific factors as their choice of currency regime. A comparison between Sweden and Denmark provides some insights on this issue. The floating rate regime of Swede allowed a much quicker recovery of international competiveness than Denmark over the period 2008-2010. This is seen in Figure 4, which compare the Danish and Swedish real effective exchange rate (REER) from 2007 and onwards. As seen the REER of Sweden acts as a buffer and depreciate in 2009-2010, where after it slowly adjust upwards and basically follows the same trend as Denmark from 2011. The figure also shows how this adjustment process clearly works through nominal exchange rate (EURSEK). 4 The Main Danish Export Market Figure 4. Real effective exchange rates and the EUR/SEK REER (2010=100) EUR/SEK 110 12 105 11 100 95 10 90 9 85 80 2007 8 2008 2009 2010 REER Denmark Note: 2011 2012 REER Sweden 2013 2014 2015 EURSEK (sec. axis) The real effective exchanges rate indexes are BIS effective exchange rate (CPI-based), Broad Indices. Source: BIS and http://www.investing.com/. However, very different developments of housing prices may also have played a role in Sweden getting quicker out of the crisis than Denmark. Housing price busts were some of the typical amplifiers of the crisis with ‘hard hit countries’ very much characterised by a boom-bust structure before and after the crisis. The point here is that Sweden never saw the same boom nor the same bust as Denmark but rather a steady rise over the last 10 years which have not yet stopped as illustrated in Figure 5. This does not reflect larger differences in official policy rates but other structural differences in Swedish and Danish housing markets. 5 The Main Danish Export Market Figure 5. Nominal housing prices; Denmark and Sweden Housing price index 150,0 140,0 130,0 120,0 110,0 100,0 90,0 80,0 70,0 60,0 01.03.2005 01.11.2006 01.07.2008 Denmark Note: 01.03.2010 01.11.2011 01.07.2013 Sweden For Sweden the figure shows prices on All properties and for Denmark the figure shows data on All types of dwellings. Source: BIS. The weak state of the EU economy also affects Danish growth. While the share of exports to EU countries has been declining over time, it is projected to remain around 60% until the end of this decade, cf. Figure 6. As a result, slow growth in the EU matters considerably for the ability of Danish firms to sell products and services abroad. 6 The Main Danish Export Market Figure 6. Share of Danish exports to main regions, billion DKK Danish Exports by Destination 100% 171 231 164 174 80% 60% 308 396 Rest of the World USA 193 226 Rest of the EU 40% 20% Neighbouring countries 0% 2005 Note: 2010 2015 2019 “Neighbouring countries” consists of Germany, Norway, the Netherlands, Sweden, and the UK. “Rest of the EU” consists of all countries in EU-28 except Germany, the Netherlands, Sweden, and the UK. Exports consist of goods (airplanes and ships excluded) and services. The data for 2015 and 2019 are based on IMF-projected growth rates of GDP and assume no significant changes in current accounts, import propensities, or market shares. Source: Trade data from Statistics Denmark series UHV2 and UHT4S2, GDP data from IMF World Economic Outlook Database (US dollars, current prices), own calculations. 2 “Never Let a Good Crisis Go to Waste” President Obama’s first chief of Staff, Emanuel Rahm, has reputedly in the context of the US economy expressed the view that one should “never let a good crisis go to waste”. The statement could certainly also be used this side of the Atlantic in the sense that an economic crisis can provide impetus to change the course of economic policies. The aim should not only be to create new jobs for those who lost them but also to boost productivity by increasing the share of the population with gainful employment. That will allow for a stronger and sustainable increase in real wages. The potential from such reforms is substantial. The OECD has reviewed the extent to which the performance of the Euro-area countries could be improved by closing the gap to regulatory best practices. The results are encouraging. The GDP growth rates could double towards 2020 if the laggards not only closed their output gaps and found jobs for those who lost them, but if they were also capable of putting in place economic policies that were “best in class”, cf. Figure 7. The rise in potential output due to GDP productivity gains and labour market reforms in 2020 are as large as removing the 2015 slack in the economy. 7 The Main Danish Export Market Figure 7. Growth potential for Euro area countries overall Index 100=baseline value for potential output in 2008 120 115 110 105 100 95 90 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 Baseline Note: Labour market reform Productivity reform Actual GDP Euro-15 area, not EU (data not available for the entire EU). Labour market reform is closing half the gap to best EU-practice in terms of skills in the labour market and labour market participation rates, including second-order effects. Productivity reform is an assumed additional 2% higher total-factor productivity in 2020. Index 100=baseline value for potential output in 2008. Source: OECD Economic Outlook Database (No. 95, May 2014, Long-term baseline projections), output gab series and real GDP series, Varga and Jan in ‘t Veld (DG ECFIN). The growth potential is unevenly distributed across countries and with very different underlying drivers. In Figure 8 we have listed the most important EU countries according to their importance in terms of Danish exports, and the tendency is clear. The growth reform potentials are lowest for the more important Danish export markets, namely Germany, UK and Sweden. Furthermore, these three economies are almost working at normal capacity, having rebounded a lot since the crisis as described above. Nonetheless, baseline market potential in both Sweden and UK will be supported by, e.g., positive developments in demographics and above average growth in the working age population as reflected in OECD growth projections. By contrast, the reform potential is much higher in some Euro-area countries like Greece, Ireland and Italy. That is even on top of a high expected growth resulting from closing the large current output gap in these countries. Also countries like the Benelux, France and Austria will have a relatively high growth reform potential, but they are less important for Danish exports. 8 The Main Danish Export Market Figure 8. Growth potential for important Danish export markets Potential for Danish export Growth expectations and potential 2014-2020 25% 4,0% 2,3% 20% 3,1% 15% 10% 3,1% 5% 7,3% 17,7% 3,4% 3,0% 3,9% 16,8% 11,3% 5,8% United Kingdom Benelux, Austria, France, Finland Ireland, Italy, Greece 3,1% 5,5% 0% 1,0% 0,0% Germany Note: 2,0% Sweden Portugal, Spain Closing the output gap OECD baseline growth expectations Potential of reforms Potential effect on Danish export (sec. axis) Closing the output gap refer to the growth related to the closing of the output gap in OECD’s expectations. Potential of reforms include a labour market reform and a productivity reform. Labour market reform is closing half the gab to best EU-practice in terms of skills in the labour market and labour market participation rates, including second-order effects. Productivity reform is an assumed additional 2% higher total-factor productivity in 2020. Southern Euro-area countries includes Greece, Spain, Italy and Portugal, and Other Euro-area countries include France, Netherlands, Ireland, Finland and Luxemburg. The potential effect on Danish export is calculated as the total growth given reforms scaled by the share of Danish export in 2013, where we assume an growth to export elasticity of 1,5. Source: OECD Economic Outlook Database (No. 95, May 2014, Long-term baseline projections), output gab series and real GDP series, Varga and Jan in ‘t Veld (DG ECFIN). These facts raise the question: has the EU and its member countries used the crisis to reset priorities in favour of growth-enhancing economic policies? We start with the individual countries first and then turn to the common policies of the EU. 3 EU National Reform Efforts A key requirement for EU member states is to improve the functioning of labour markets. Countries in the EU with sustained high unemployment rates such as France, Greece, Italy, and Portugal are characterised by high degrees of protection against dismissal for so-called permanent employees and much lower degrees of protection for socalled temporary workers, e.g. workers employed on short term contracts with fixed duration. At the same time, income compensation is low for many workers when they lose their jobs or at least highly unequal for different types of jobs. There is a strong case for these countries to adopt labour market reforms such as those undertaken particularly in the Northern part of the EU during the last two decades. The results have been substantially higher employment rates and unemployment rates more equally distributed across the working force. Indeed, there is strong evidence that the principle of Flexicurity works: employers have the right to match the number of employees to the amount of goods and services they can sell without excessive severance payments, while the government provides a meaningful safety net in the period where displaced workers seek alternative employment. 9 The Main Danish Export Market Unfortunately, effective progress on labour market reform has been patchy since the crisis started, with no overall reduction in the restrictiveness of labour market rules during the period 2008 to 2013, cf. Figure 9. Overall restrictiveness was broadly unchanged. However, recent OECD surveys indicate a new beginning in reform efforts in a number of countries including France, Italy, and Spain that all operate dual labour market systems. Figure 9. Restrictiveness of employment protection, 20082013 Restrictiveness index 3,5 3 2,5 2 1,5 1 0,5 0 2013 Note: 2008 The scale of the restrictiveness index is 0-6, from least to most restrictive. The index is an average of sub-indeces for regular employment, temporary employment, and collective dismissals. Source: OECD Structural Reform data base Particularly in a context of weak and uncertain growth prospects, policy reforms that would make it less risky for firms to invest in employment could help the growth process to gather pace. Recent tentative steps in Italy for example are encouraging: new rules effectively allow employers to recruit new people for up to three years on temporary contracts in nearly all positions, all while broadening the social benefit system. By focusing reforms on conditions pertaining to the newly employed as opposed to the existing staff, they can help maintain confidence among the workers who are already employed, while making hiring of new employees less risky. In this way, employed workers would not cut back on spending and employment should expand. Progress in product markets have been more pronounced. Across the EU, state ownership of firms has been reduced (apart from certain banks in countries with severe financial crises) and regulation of network industries such as energy, water, and transportation has become more market-oriented as evidenced by OECD monitoring of reforms in these areas. Conditions for entrepreneurship have also improved, cf. Figure 10 and 11. 10 The Main Danish Export Market Figure 10. Restrictiveness of product market regulation, 2008-2013 Restrictiveness index 3,5 3 2,5 2 1,5 1 0,5 0 2013 Note: 2008 The scale of the restrictiveness index is 0-6, from least to most restrictive. The index is an average of sub-indeces for product market regulation and state control through ownership and involvement in business operation. Source: OECD Structural Reform data base. Figure 11. Barriers to entrepreneurship, 2008-2013 Restrictiveness index 3 2,5 2 1,5 1 0,5 0 2013 Note: 2008 The scale of the restrictiveness index is 0-6, from least to most restrictive. The index is an average of sub-indeces for burdens on start-ups, complexity of regulation, and protection of incumbents. Source: OECD Structural Reform data base. Overall, it would seem fair to say that EU member states will need to step up reform efforts considerably, particularly in the labour market area, in order to realise the potential associated with best country practice. Fiscal consolidation and growth enhancing reform measures can go well together. For instance, a measure such as the new Italian rules that incentivise recruitment and preserve or even increases consumer confidence will also improve public finances. Raising the retirement age for pension systems will reduce public outlays, increase the work force and boost growth potential. Hence, there is no inherent conflict between improving public finances and boosting short term economic performance if the right policy design is put in place. 11 The Main Danish Export Market 4 Action at the EU Level Focused on Macro and the Financial Sector Since the start of the crisis in 2008, economic policy making at the EU level has in practice focused attention on containment of the crisis. In the immediate aftermath of the crisis, the EU countries and the US responded strongly to the global agreements in the context of G20 which suggested that countries should underpin their recoveries by increasing public spending and allowing tax revenues to decline with economic activity. However, already from 2010 it became clear that a number of countries that had seen major increases in inflation and foreign borrowing to pay for consumption and real estate booms, started to lose the confidence of international investors. As a result, borrowing costs for governments went up and they had to start a consolidation process to stop public debts rising to non-sustainable This pattern was particularly clear for countries with substantial pre-crisis deterioration of net foreign asset position problems such as Spain, Ireland and some Baltic states and for countries with public finance problems prior to the crisis such as Greece and Portugal. (Italy and France moving in this latter group as well) As a result of the financial crisis, the EU has devoted considerable attention to making the financial sector more stable and pushing member states to shore up public finances. This has led to an avalanche of regulation initiatives targeting the banking sector, requiring higher cushions of capital as well as stronger provisions to bail-in private investors when banks run into trouble. Most assessments suggest that this direction of policy towards the banking sector has been necessary to safeguard against future financial crises. Yet, in a context of weak growth and weakened banks, the policy focus has tended to reduce short to medium term growth. For instance, one side-effect of the new capital requirements is that banks with weak balance sheets have tended to reduce lending in order to replenish their capital reserves, rather than issuing new equity. Meanwhile, the ECB as well as other central banks have pursued extremely expansionary monetary policies. As a direct response to the emerging crisis in 2008, official interest rates were cut to 1 per cent or lower by the ECB as well as by the UK, Swedish and Danish central banks, cf. Figure 12. The rates were then adjusted upwards again towards 2011, although they remained low by historical levels. With renewed pressures on the economy and in particular the need to sustain growth in hard-pressed countries within the Eurozone, the ECB has again cut interest rates aggressively, this time to levels close to zero, cf. Figure 12. In order to maintain the Danish hard peg vis-à-vis the Euro, interest rates on deposits with the central bank are now negative, as is also the case in Sweden. Most recently, the ECB has followed the example from the US and embarked on a new programme of so-called Quantitative Easing (QE), buying public and private sector securities in order to push down long-term borrowing costs. 12 The Main Danish Export Market Figure 12. Some EU central banks’ interest rates % 7,00 6,00 5,00 4,00 3,00 2,00 1,00 0,00 -1,00 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 ECB Main Refinancing Rate Bank of England Official Bank Rate Nationalbanken Indskudsbeviser Sveriges Riksbank Räporenta Inflation expectations (2%) Note: The vertical axis shows the nominal rates. To get an impression of what the real rates might be, simply think of the 2% line as the horizontal axis. The last observation is May 2015. Source: Central bank statistics of the various countries. The ECB’s low interest rate policy has been successful in reducing the cost of obtaining credit faced by firms, but with one caveat. While the borrowing costs in Germany and other countries with relative strong government and bank balance sheets have gone down in tandem with official ECB rates, this has not been the case in Spain and Italy where the borrowing costs are higher now than in 2011, cf. Figure 13. In other words, the spread in the costs of financing investment has gone up (shaded area in Figure 13), with firms in the crisis-prone countries facing the highest costs. The fact that the policy of low central bank interest rates has not led to low borrowing costs everywhere is without doubt a factor in the ECB’s decision to by-pass the banks and buy up private sector debt directly. 13 The Main Danish Export Market Figure 13. Nominal costs of borrowing from banks for nonfinancial firms % Cross-country std. dev. 7,0 1,8 1,6 6,0 1,4 5,0 1,2 4,0 1,0 3,0 0,8 0,6 2,0 0,4 1,0 0,2 0,0 2004 0,0 2006 2008 cross-country std dev (rhs) Note: 2010 DE ES 2012 FR 2014 IT NL EA The left vertical axis shows nominal interest rates in % p.a. The right vertical axis shows the dispersion of the interest rates across countries, measured as the standard deviation. 3-month moving averages. The last observation is November 2014. Source: ECB Bulletin 2015:1 Chart B. As a consequence of the large interest rate spreads and inefficiently operating capital markets we also still see large differences in the marginal product of capital across the Euro areas countries, cf. Figure 14. Put very simple, the fact that firms in Southern Europe face so high financing costs suggest that they are dropping investment with rates of return that are likely to exceed investment in EU countries with much lower interest rates. Figure 14. Marginal efficiency of capital: total economy, 2014 Marginal efficiency of capital 15% 14% 13% 12% 11% 10% 9% 8% 7% 6% 5% European Union Note: Euro-area (12) Southern Euro-area countries Core Euro-area countries The marginal efficiency of capital is defined as the change in GDP in year t per one extra unit of gross fixed capital formation invested in year t-5. All are measured in constant market prices. For the southern and core Euro-area country groups we rely on simple averages. The core Euro-area countries are defined as Germany, France, Austria and Benelux. The Southern Euro-area countries are defined as Spain, Greece, Italy and Portugal. Source: European Commission’s AMECO database. 14 The Main Danish Export Market By launching its quantitative easing programme (QE), the ECB has focused very much on the need to avoid a deflation and recession scenario particularly in Southern Europe, but this focus also entails substantial risks. Firstly, there are doubts as to how effective the additional stimulus will be at this point. In the US, the combined effect of a very explicit QE policy of buying up securities and keeping official rates low may have lowered the unemployment rate with 1½ per cent in 2015 and increased the rate of inflation by ½ percentage point in 2016 (compared to a “standard” crisis response policy)1. Given the much lower role of capital markets in the financing of EU firms and the already very low policy rate before initiating the program, the additional effect of ECB’s QE program must be significantly lower than the effects of the US program, both in terms of getting inflation back towards the target and in terms of lifting growth. Secondly, the extremely low interest rate environment has led to a surge in the pricing of securities, leading to legitimate concerns about yet another asset bubble in the making. It is worth remembering that the expansionary monetary policies in the US following the dotcom collapse in 2001 – and partly also in the EU – was a significant factor in the financial instability leading to the current crisis2. Equity prices across the globe are now back in the territory from 20007-2008 as measured by the ratio of equity prices to GDP cf. Figure 15. At least for the US, these valuations require future returns that – based on several metrics about future developments – appear unrealistic3. That might also be the case in the EU. 1 FED(2015) See our review of the triggers for the current crisis in the CE study for European Parliament(2009). 3 US Treasury, Office of Financial Research(2015), “Quicksilver markets” 2 15 The Main Danish Export Market Figure 15. Equity prices relative to GDP in global financial markets, 1991-2015 index (primo 1992 = 100) 300 Stoxx 600 Europe 250 Stoxx 600 North America 200 FTSE 100 UK 150 100 50 Stoxx 600 Asia-Pacific 0 1992 Note: 1995 1999 2003 2007 2011 Stoxx 600 Europe Stoxx 600 Asia-Pacific Stoxx 600 North America FTSE 100 UK 2014 All indexes are measured relative to the total GDP in the countries included in the index, where GDP is based on moving averages of quarterly GDP in current prices. Source: OECD, IMF, http://www.stoxx.com/indices/ and http://finance.yahoo.com/. As a third important point, currency areas as the euro-area where several countries share a common monetary policy always run the risk of so called monetary stress, where the policy set by the central bank is not ideally suited for each individual member country at the same time. This problem may be particularly strong in relation to aggressive monetary policy such as QE programs which may be far from the optimal policy in countries such as Germany (and Denmark) where the recovery was well under way and lending rates were already relatively low before ECB’s QE program was initiated. So the bottom line on monetary policy is that the very low interest environment has been helpful in boosting growth, but that there are non-trivial risks associated with a continuation of such expansionary policies for a sustained period of time. How much does it help getting firms to invest in long term viable projects and how much does it simply increase prices of existing assets with potential new bobbles as the result? This risk is most pertinent for countries with a recovery well under way – arguably countries such as Denmark and Sweden and potentially also Germany within the Eurozone as well as the US. Indeed, it may be more productive to deal directly with the remaining balance sheet problems in banks and private firms in the individual countries rather than to push up prices of existing assets across the entire EU region. In short, what non-financial firms and banks may need is more equity rather than more bank loans, thus reducing too 16 The Main Danish Export Market high debt-to-assets ratios. More about this issue in the section on capital market union below. 5 Juncker Commission: A Change of Tack With the main legislative banking regulation proposals adopted and under implementation, the new EU Commission has clearly changed tack, and it is now more strongly focused on improving structural policies and boosting growth at the same time. There are three key initiatives: • Proposing an EU investment plan focused on infrastructure. • Creating a Capital Market Union. • Getting the internal market back on track. The EU investment plan The EU Commission has proposed an ambitious investment plan4 which has precisely been motivated by the co-existence of two major economic problems in the EU: the severity of the economic crisis, most notably expressed as low investments, and a potential large stock of viable investments being held back by a number of factors. Hence, the EU Commission has proposed an investment plan based on three key principles: (1) mobilising (new sources of) finance for investments, (2) making sure this finance reaches the real economy in order to support growth and jobs, and (3) improving the investment environment. To unlock private and public investment, the EU Commission and the European Investment Bank have more specifically launched a partnership to increase investment by 315 billion over the period 2015-2017. Designated target areas are infrastructure (notably broadband and energy networks), transport infrastructure in industrial centres, education, research and innovation, and, last but not least, renewable energy and energy efficiency. In order to implement this strategy, a European Fund for Strategic Investments (EFSI) has been proposed and a joint Task Force (Member States, the Commission and the EIB) has identified projects worth € 1.3 trillion out of which € 500 billion could be carried out during the next three years. The challenge now is to make sure that the EFSI actually delivers. Clearly the initiative has been partly motivated by the fact that budget constrained public governments have difficulties in funding otherwise viable infrastructure projects in traditional ways. However, the real success of the programme should be measured on its ability to use private sector skills, competences and risk management capacities in the construction, running and funding of large investment projects often in areas where consumers ultimately bear the cost of the activities5. If so the EU can deliver in three dimensions (1) boost growth now (2) raise productivity (3) improve public finances in the short run by reducing unemployment while being broadly neutral in the long run as costs are absorbed by the private, not public, sector. The Capital market union 4 An overview of the objectives, targets and instruments is provided in factsheet 1 and 3 from the European Investment Bank (2014 a and b). 5 In a recent study for five major Danish institutional investors, the key to successful use of private sector infrastructure investments were spelt out (Ernst & Young and Copenhagen Economics(2012)) 17 The Main Danish Export Market The EU Commission has presented a green paper6 that proposes the creation of a capital market union. The plan is very much motivated by the fact that compared to other parts of the world, European businesses rely heavily on banks for funding and relatively less on capital markets such as corporate bond and equity markets. Stronger capital markets would complement banks as a source of financing, and it is intended to “unlock more investment for all companies, especially SMEs and infrastructure … (and to) … make the financial system more stable by opening up a wider range of funding sources”6. Improved access to capital markets is indeed likely both to make European firms more resilient during times of financial stress and to improve their long term productivity performance. In a large study of more than 15.000 firms it is found that firms with a strong equity base and access to long term guaranteed loan financing (for example corporate bonds) came out much stronger during the recent crises than less solid firms7. Moreover, there is a strong empirical basis for the assertion that access to risk capital from capital markets is a requirement for more risky and longer term investments and commitments to boost innovation and expansion of production, markets and firms with the ability and drive to grow. The US biotech industry offers a particular compelling evidence for how important improved access to equity financing is for investments in research and development. In essence then the capital market union should be less about increasing investment as about improving the quality of investments by reallocating capital to firms with the strongest potential for growth and productivity increases. Indeed a number of studies suggest that the biggest gains from improved capital markets come from a shift of investments and employment from larger to smaller firms. The Capital Market Union is thus really about two separate issues. Removing barriers to capital provision across borders – which is very much an internal market perspective – and reducing the costs associated with providing capital market products to mid-cap firms and potentially also smaller firms: a job to be done both at the national and at the EU level. The areas to be looked into are many and well known, e.g., insolvency, security and tax law. However, the private sector can do a lot: some countries in the Europe such as Germany and Norway are leading the way in the area of making corporate bond financing a real alternative option, even for loans as low as € 10 to 15 million. Earlier the minimum sizes was around € 75 million. The idea here is to standardise credit ratings, covenant structures as well as insolvency procedures, i.e. to keep agency and monitoring costs for investors to a minimum. The EU commission has already announced that it will take initiative in a number of areas: • develop proposals to encourage high quality securitisation and free up bank balance sheets to lend, • review the Prospectus Directive to make it easier for firms, particularly smaller ones, to tap capital markets • look at ways to ease funding across borders 6 7 European Commission (2015),”Building a Capital Market Union” Bruegel (2012), “Still standing: how European firms weather the crisis” and Altomonte et al. (2012), “The triggers of competitiveness” 18 The Main Danish Export Market • • • start working on ways to improve the availability of credit information on SMEs and thereby ease investors’ decision-making work with the industry to put into place a pan European private placement regime to encourage direct investment into smaller businesses support the take up of new European long term investment funds to channel investment in infrastructure and other long term projects. A successful policy in the above areas will help member states to identify both national barriers to expansion of risk capital to small and medium sizes enterprises building on best practice. At the same time it will help building cross-border providers of financial services in this area. Development of common standards for credit scoring, simplified covenants for corporate bonds and solvency procedures can both help push down the cost of providing risk capital to smaller firms and develop financial specialist capable of acting at regional or even EU level. The Single market While the EU Commission has not yet launched a major re-launch of a big Internal Market project, a number of key priorities have already been identified. Both the Capital Market Union and the EU Investment plan include key Internal Market components. In addition, it is likely that the EU Commission will focus on a number of “old” barriers to a well-functioning internal market as recently identified in a study by the European Parliament on the cost of non-Europe: completing the Digital Single Market (€ 520 billion), the Single Market for Consumer and Citizens (€ 235 billion), a Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership with EU (€ 60 billion) and Integrated Energy Markets (€ 50 billion) may together add close to € 900 billion of increased productivity to the EU economy. Denmark has notable interest in the completion. As a small open country Denmark will always benefit disproportionally from a more open external trading environment. In addition, Denmark benefit in particular from increased market access to the US in area of pharmaceutical products. 19 The Main Danish Export Market 6 References Arpaia, A., Kiss, A., Palvolgyi, B., & Turrini, A. (2014). Labour mobility and labour market adjustments in the EU. Brussels: European Commission. Badel, A., & McGillicuddy, J. (2015). The effect of recent ECB Policy on Inflation Expectation. Hentet fra stlouisfed.org: https://www.stlouisfed.org/on-theeconomy/2015/february/the-effect-of-recent-ecb-policy-on-inflationexpectations Bank, E. C. (2015). ECB Staff Macroeconomic projections for the Euro Area. Brézillon, J., Guichard, S., & Turner, D. (2010). Trade Linkages in the OECD Trade System. OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 811, OECD Publishing. Hentet fra http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5km4t0fj2p6l-en Bruegel. (2012). Still standing: how European firms weather the crisis. Carlo Altomonte, T. A. (2012). The triggers of competitiveness. The EFIGE crosscountry report. Codogno, L., & De Grauwe, P. (2015). Why Denmark should either abandon its peg to the euro or join the single currency. Hentet fra http://blogs.lse.ac.uk: http://blogs.lse.ac.uk/europpblog/2015/03/12/why-denmark-should-eitherabandon-its-peg-to-the-euro-or-join-the-single-currency/ Copenhagen Economics. (2010). The Economic Impact of a European Digital Sigle Market. De Fiore, F., & Uhlig, H. (2015). Corporate Debt Structure and the Financial Crisis. European Central Bank. del Monte, M. (2013). The Cost of Non-Europe in the Single Market for Energy. European Parliamentary Research Service, European Added Value Unit. European Parliament. Engen, E. M., Laubach, T. T., & Reifschneider, D. (2015). The Macroeconomic Effects of the Federal Reserve's Unconventional Monetary Policy. Washington, D.C.: Finance and Economic Discussion Series 2015. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. European Central Bank. (2013). RESEARCH BULLETIN No. 18. European Central Bank . European Central Bank. (2014). Financial Stability Review. European Central Bank. (2015). Economic Bulletin. European Central Bank. (2015). European firm adjustment during times of economic crisis. European Cetral Bank. (2015). Labour market Adjustments in Europe and the US: How different? European Commission. (2015). Building a Capital Market Union. Brussels: European Commission. European Commission. (2015). European Economic Forecast. Brussels: DirectorateGeneral for Economic and Financial Affairs. European Commission. (2015). Quarterly Report on the Euro Area. DirectorateGeneral for Economic and Financial Affairs. 20 The Main Danish Export Market European Parliament. (2012). Towards a genuine Economic and Monetary Union. European Parliamentary Research Service, European Added Value unit. European Parliament. Francois, J., Manchin, M., Norberg, H., Pindyuk, O., & Tomberger, P. (2013). Reducing Transatlantic Barriers to Trade and Investment. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research. Internatinal Monetary fund. (2014). World Economic Outlook: Legacies, Clouds, Uncertainties. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund. International Monetary Fund. (2014). FRANCE: STAFF REPORT FOR THE 2014 ARTICLE IV CONSULTATION. Washington, D.C. : International Monetary Fund. Muller, P., Devnani, S., Laher, R., & Lane, M. (2013). Better Governance of the Single Market. European Parliament. European Added Value Assessment. OECD. (2014). Economic Surveys: European Union 2014. OECD Publishing. OECD. (2014). OECD Economic Outlook, Vol. 2014/1,. OECD Publishing. Hentet fra http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/eco_outlook-v2014-1-en OECD. (2014). OECD Economic Surveys: Spain. OECD Publishing. OECD. (2015). Economic Policy Reforms 2015: Going for Growth. Paris: OECD Publishing. Hentet fra http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/growth-2015-en OECD. (2015). Economic Surveys: Italy 2015. Paris: OECD Publishing. OECD. (2015). OECD Economic Surveys: France. Paris: OECD Publishing. Office of Finacial Research. (2015). Volatility Returns Amid Oil Price Declines European Developments. OFR Market Monitor. Office of Financial Research. (2015). Divergent Monetary Policies Continue to Drive Market Trends. OFR Market Monitor. Office of Financial Research. (2015). Quicksilver-Markets. Varga, J., & in ’t Veld, J. (2014). The potential growth impact of structural reforms in the EU: A benchmarking exercise. Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs. Brussels: European Commission. 21