Download Is China the New France?

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Fear of floating wikipedia , lookup

Exchange rate wikipedia , lookup

Balance of payments wikipedia , lookup

Foreign-exchange reserves wikipedia , lookup

International monetary systems wikipedia , lookup

Currency war wikipedia , lookup

Currency War of 2009–11 wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Is China the New France?
August 6, 2013
by Marianne Brunet
Imagine a country that grows its economy by greatly devaluing against the reserve currency to develop
a strong export sector. As the country becomes a major world power, it accumulates massive amounts
of the reserve currency, and fears grow that its actions could destabilize global markets.
If you think that description sounds like China today, you're right. But it also describes France in the
1920s. Lessons from that era are instructive for those seeking to forecast China’s long-term position in
the world.
France faded and never regained the stature that it achieved in the 1920s. I’ll discuss whether China is
headed toward a similar outcome. First, however, let’s look at the striking parallels between the two
countries, including currency pegs, reserve accumulation and urbanization.
Currency-fueled export growth
Both China today and France in the 1920s devalued their currencies and later maintained a peg to the
reserve currency – dollars and sterling, respectively. These actions created a global market for their
exports.
When a currency is pegged, it does not trade freely on international markets. The foreign exchange
rate of the pegged currency is fixed because its availability to settle transactions is very tightly
regulated. James Rickards, author of Currency Wars: The Making of the Next Global Crisis, explains
that for China, “The surest way to rapid, massive job creation was to become an export powerhouse.
The currency peg was the means to this end.”
France employed this strategy to gain status globally in the 1920s, as an abundance of young men
were returning from the war.It positioned itself to bolster its export sector in 1922 with currency
devaluations. But within four years, the depreciation that drove its trade became too problematic,
promptingPrime Minister Raymond Poincaré to step in and stabilize the franc. In an effort to address
the domestic problems provoked by the weak currency and sustain growth in the export sector, the
franc was pegged to the world reserve currency, the sterling.
Page 1, ©2017 Advisor Perspectives, Inc. All rights reserved.
Rickards’s account of China’s rise follows a very similar track. The modern Chinese economic miracle
took off in 1978. The integration of a new market-oriented system at that time allowed China to start
fueling its export sector by utilizing the massive labor force it had available. China concluded in 1997,
based on multiple currency devaluations, that its best strategy was to peg the renminbi (RMB) to the
world reserve currency, the American dollar.
Through export-driven growth, both nations established themselves on the world stage. France and
China saw increased production in various industries, including the mining sector and textiles. Within a
decade, France had tripled its total and consumer goods exports and quadrupled capital exports. China
also reported striking statistics. In 2010, China held the title of the world’s largest exporter. In 2012,
China reported approximately $2.05 trillion in exports.
Page 2, ©2017 Advisor Perspectives, Inc. All rights reserved.
These remarkable rises in exports led to dramatic growth in gross domestic product (GDP). Within a
decade, both France and China were able to double their GDPs. Though the trade and industrial
components of GDP saw the most progress, both countries also experienced some growth in
agriculture.
A problematic accumulation of the reserve currency
A cheap currency and a strong export sector leads to a current account surplus and an accumulation
of global reserves.
France and China undoubtedly had remarkable economic growth. However, they were unable to
achieve it without accumulating foreign reserves. Following World War I, the United Kingdom pegged
the sterling to its pre-war level. That rate did not account for massive wartime inflation, leaving the
sterling overvalued (and the franc undervalued) for years. Additionally, when Poincaré stabilized the
franc, the French government mandated that the Bank of France buy foreign currencies to avoid
excessive appreciation.
Those two factors led France to accumulate a bulging portfolio of foreign currency. By 1928, France
held half of the world’s volume of foreign reserves, which at the time was convertible to gold. But
Page 3, ©2017 Advisor Perspectives, Inc. All rights reserved.
market instability grew as France sterilized the monetary impact of its accumulated gold reserves. That
is, France effectively printed more francs in order to maintain its gold stock.
We can see parallels in China’s accumulation of foreign reserves. China’s pegged currency has
essentially led it to outsource its monetary policy to the U.S. Federal Reserve. As the Fed has printed
more currency, the People’s Bank of China (PBoC) has had to purchase dollars with newly printed
RMB. As China sought to invest its newly acquired dollars safely and with a reasonable rate of return,
it began purchasing massive quantities of U.S. Treasury obligations, which further aggravated China’s
accumulation of foreign currency. As a result, China has found itself with $3.312 trillion of foreign
exchange and gold.
Do China and France face similar fates?
Both nations accumulated global reserves in their respective eras, feeding worldwide concern over
their influence on markets. The worries over France proved to be warranted, as the country’s foreign
reserves accumulation was ultimately detrimental. As the value of the pound declined in 1930, the
Bank of France was pushed into a no-win situation. France had to support the sterling, since
liquidating its pounds would have prompted a sterling collapse.
Ultimately, France suffered a a huge exchange loss. When the British depreciated the sterling in
September 1931, the Bank of France’s financial health deteriorated, as its dependency forced it into a
precarious position. Ultimately, the Bank of France registered a capital loss of 2.35 billion francs on its
sterling holdings, equal to twice the available capital and reserves.
As the franc lost value, the cost of imports rose and France faced inflation. By the end of the 1930s,
patriotism in France was dwindling. Citizens underwent hardships amplified by government efforts to
defend the franc and rebalance the budget. Since these massive losses, France has never truly been
able to reestablish itself as a global world power.
Given that both China and France effectively accumulated global reserves in their respective eras,
France’s experience prompts us to consider whether China will suffer a similar fate. Michael Pettis, a
leading expert on China’s economy, argues that China will not follow France’s path. Pettis is a senior
associate at Carnegie Endowment for International Peace and a finance professor at Peking
University’s Guangua School of Management, where he specializes in Chinese financial markets. He is
the author of the recently released and widely acclaimed book, The Great Rebalancing.
Pettis agrees that “China buys dollars, a floating currency, for the same reason that France bought
sterling – to support its manufacturing sector.” But, he argues, “the undervalued RMB feeds into the
domestic imbalances that Beijing is trying to reverse and so it must continue to rise.” Pettis explains
that unlike France in the 1930s, China will not face a loss as the RMB gains value unless the U.S. acts
to depreciate the purchasing power of the dollar – which Pettis does not expect to happen. He expects
the value of China’s reserves to remain unchanged in terms of the country’s purchasing power abroad.
(Foreign holdings can only be used to make purchases abroad.)
“There will of course be losses for the PBoC as the RMB appreciates, because all of its dollar reserves
Page 4, ©2017 Advisor Perspectives, Inc. All rights reserved.
are funded by RMB borrowing,” Pettis concedes. But “these losses will be matched by an increase in
the purchasing power of Chinese households.” Therefore, Pettis believes it is unlikely China will be
pushed into the precarious position France faced. He explains that even if China did start to feel
concerned about the value its dollars, it would be reluctant to reduce its foreign holdings because the
value of the RMB would soar, severely hurting the country’s export sector.
Another parallel between the two nations is urbanization. As France grew in the 1920s, there was a
notable increase in urbanization. But by late 1934, urbanization had begun to reverse. “Urbanization is
almost always pro-cyclical,” according to Pettis. “It speeds up during times of growth and slows down
or even reverses when the economy stops growing.” This same theory could certainly be applied to
China, which has seen an increase in urbanization along with its export driven growth. Pettis stated
that he “would be surprised if we did not see the same [reversal] happen in China.”
One of the main differences between these two nations is that China faces asset bubbles, particularly
in real estate values. Pettis explained that until Poincaré stabilized the franc at 80% below its pre-war
level, France faced substantial balance-of-payments pressures due to uncertainty and weakness in its
economy. With high interest rates and a struggling economy, France was not susceptible to an asset
bubble. In China, according to Pettis, the accumulation of foreign reserves is part of massive monetary
expansion. Due to artificially low interest rates, an asset bubble was essentially inevitable.
Conclusion
The overall parallel between France and China holds true in that both nations devalued their currencies
to build their export sectors. This allowed both countries to increase GDP, expand urbanization and
accumulate more foreign reserves as they moved into internationally influential positions. But it is not a
perfect parallel, given that differing global environments make it unlikely China will replicate France’s
downfall.
Ultimately, France’s decline prior to the Great Depression was because its export sector could not
generate continued economic growth, and its devalued currency led to high inflation and political
unrest. China may someday face a crisis of slower growth and higher inflation, but it doesn’t today.
Marianne Brunet is an associate editor with Advisor Perspectives.
Page 5, ©2017 Advisor Perspectives, Inc. All rights reserved.