Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Session 11 The legacy and challenge of fiscal policy in sub-Saharan Africa Krige Siebrits and Estian Calitz1 Paper to be presented at the XIVth International Economic History Conference (Helsinki, Finland, 21-25 August 2006) During the past two to three decades, the ongoing process of globalisation has profoundly changed the international economic order. This order now faces new challenges in the wake of several recent financial crises and growing resistance from groups and countries who perceive themselves to be excluded from the claimed benefits of globalisation. Over the same period, views about the economic role of government have changed markedly, in large part because of the renewed preference for market-based solutions to economic problems. The debate about the economic role of fiscal policy is continuing, with questions about the optimal extent and nature of government intervention in market economies remaining contentious. Few participants in this debate, however, would deny that fiscal policy has an important role in developing countries, both with regard to the promotion of sustained economic growth and the reduction of poverty. Fiscal policy is likely to be of particular importance in the African context, where the challenges of raising growth rates and reducing poverty are acute. This paper traces salient aspects of the evolution of fiscal policy in sub-Saharan Africa since 1960 (mainly its contribution to the region’s economic problems and the fiscal adjustment process during the 1980s and 1990s) and highlights the need for further reforms to consolidate the fiscal gains of the recent past. We take a broad view of the scope of fiscal policy that includes all national government decisions regarding the nature, level and composition of government expenditure, taxation and borrowing. This view encompasses the interdependent macroeconomic and microeconomic dimensions of fiscal policy, where the latter includes efficiency and equity issues. 1 Senior Lecturer in Economics, University of South Africa, and Executive Director: Finance and Professor of Economics, University of Stellenbosch, respectively. We are grateful to Christo Luus for permission to draw on an article prepared for Absa Group Economic Research (Siebrits & Calitz, 2004b). Earlier versions of this paper were presented at an Economic History Society of South Africa session of the Biannual Conference of the Economic Society of South Africa in Durban on 17 September 2005, and at seminars at the Universities of South Africa and Stellenbosch. We thank members of the audiences at these presentations for valuable comments and discussions. 2 The nature and context of fiscal policy in sub-Saharan Africa Proper understanding and assessment of recent developments in fiscal policy in subSaharan Africa require cognisance of at least three aspects of the regional and global contexts, namely the economic performance of the region, changing views about the economic role of government, and the fiscal implications of globalisation. After growing briskly during the 1960s and the first half of the 1970s (the first decade or so after colonial rule), the economy of sub-Saharan Africa performed poorly during the next twenty-five years. Real GDP growth slowed from an annual average of 5.4% in the period 1960-1974 to 2.0% in the period 1975-1999; the corresponding average annual rates of growth of per capita GDP were 2.6% and -0.9% (Fosu, 2002: 282).2 Both the level of these growth rates and the nature of economic growth were wholly inadequate to overcome poverty in the region. The World Bank (2005: 67), for example, estimates that the number of people in sub-Saharan Africa who live on US$1 or less per day increased from 164 million (41.6% of the region's population) in 1981 to 313 million (46.4% of the population) in 2001. Commentators have long debated the relative contributions to sub-Saharan Africa's poor growth performance of exogenous and policy-related factors (for a survey of this debate, see Collier & Gunning, 1999a). According to some, economic growth in sub-Saharan Africa was hampered mainly by factors beyond the control of policymakers, including the small size of many countries, tropical climates, poor soils, erratic rainfall patterns, high levels of ethno-linguistic diversity, long distances from industrial country markets and heavy reliance on the exportation of a narrow range of commodities (many of which have been characterised by falling demand and volatile prices). Others have emphasised the growth-sapping effects of policies that contributed to macroeconomic instability3, the excessive expansion of public sector activity and employment, poor service delivery, the crowding out and stifling regulation of private economic activity, highly protectionist trade 2 All the major country groupings experienced slower growth during the 1980s than during the 1970s. However, the slowdown was significantly more pronounced in sub-Saharan Africa and Latin America than in Asia and the OECD countries. See, for example, Schmidt-Hebbel (1996: 11). 3 Composite indices show that sub-Saharan African and Latin American countries experienced considerably more macroeconomic instability during the 1970s and 1980s than their counterparts in East and South Asia (Collier & Gunning 1999b: 73; Schmidt-Hebbel, 1996: 18). Such indices measure the extent of instability in the inflation rate, the exchange rate, the terms of trade, monetary growth, the current account of the balance of payments and other relevant variables. 3 regimes, overvalued exchange rate regimes and the discouragement of production for export. A detailed discussion of these issues falls outside the scope of this paper; the important point for our purposes is that the economic performance and prospects of sub-Saharan Africa began to improve from the second half of the 1990s onwards (African Development Bank, 2004: 1-8; Funke & Nsouli, 2003: 5-10). Data in the statistical appendix to the latest issue of the World Economic Outlook (International Monetary Fund, 2006) confirm this conclusion. Whereas average real output growth in sub-Saharan Africa lagged world output growth by more than one percentage point per annum from 1988 to 1997, it is expected to exceed world output growth by 0.1 percentage point per annum from 1998 to 2007.4 In every year from 2000 to 2005, at least 15 countries in sub-Saharan Africa achieved real growth rates of 5% or more. The average annual change in consumer prices decreased from 34.6% from 1988 to 1997 to a projected 12.4% from 1998 to 2007, having dipped to 9.7% in 2004. Faster growth and accelerated debt relief reduced the external debt burden of sub-Saharan African countries from 67.2% of GDP in 1998 to 37.8% in 2005; interest payments on external debt accordingly dropped from 6.8% of exports of goods and services in 1998 to 3.0% in 2005. The growth performance of African countries still exhibits considerable variation and many countries remain vulnerable to external shocks because of their small size and heavy reliance on foreign assistance and primary commodity exports. The growth prospects of more and more Sub-Saharan African countries are nonetheless improving, fuelled by factors such as greater political stability, increased awareness and understanding across the continent of the international market criteria for good economic governance, greater access to industrial country markets, debt relief, favourable revisions of multilateral grants and debt repayment schedules, and stronger commitment by African leaders to assume responsibility for their countries’ economic destinies. At the global level, the comprehensive review of the role of government in the economy that had begun in the 1970s continued into the new millennium, as did international integration of economic activity in the form of regionalisation and globalisation. Underpinning the global spread of market-friendly policies, the reconsideration of the role 4 From 1988 to 1997, average real output growth in sub-Saharan Africa and the world economy was 2.3% per annum and 3.4% per annum respectively. The IMF expects the corresponding average annual growth rates from 1998 to 2007 to be 4.2% and 4.1%. 4 of government has focused on halting or reversing the expansion of the public sector that had occurred in most industrial and developing countries from the end of World War II onwards (see Tanzi & Schuknecht, 1997). It also has had major implications for what is perceived internationally to be “best practice” in fiscal policy, with many countries adopting the package of policies known as the Washington consensus. Although it is now generally agreed that the Washington consensus is an inadequate overall framework for economic development (which, incidentally, it probably never was intended to be), there is still widespread support for its main fiscal elements: low budget deficits, the restructuring of public expenditure to increase the allocations for social spending and infrastructure, tax reform to broaden the tax base and reduce marginal income tax rates, and the restructuring of institutions and enterprises in the public sector (which may include privatisation) (Williamson, 2000: 253). Some of the potential advantages of globalisation – such as increased access to world markets, suppliers, capital and new technologies – hold particular promise for subSaharan African countries if and when they materialise. But globalisation also brings fiscal challenges (see Calitz, 2000; Tanzi, 2004). It has raised the importance of adopting international best practices in fiscal policymaking (mostly resembling the fiscal guidelines of the Washington consensus), both as a requirement for attracting foreign investment and as partial protection against the contagion effects of financial crises. In this way, globalisation is increasingly limiting the scope for independence in economic policymaking.5 Aspects of globalisation, however, complicate compliance with the key guideline of low budget deficits. Trade liberalisation usually reduces governments' income from trade taxes, and the increased international mobility of tax bases puts downward pressure on tax rates. On the expenditure side, globalisation creates pressure for increased public spending on infrastructure and social safety nets (especially to assist those who lose their jobs or capital because of increased exposure to foreign competition). These issues are particularly worrying in the sub-Saharan African context, where tax bases tend to be relatively small, social safety nets non-existent or rudimentary and pressure for increased government spending on social services strong. Besides, despite various preferential trade arrangements – including the European Union’s Lomé and For more detailed discussions of the impact of globalisation on the autonomy of fiscal policymakers, see Calitz (2000; 2003). 5 5 Cotonou Conventions and the US African Growth and Opportunity Act (AGOA) – African economies generally have had less access to OECD markets than, for example, Chile and Mexico (vis-à-vis the United States) and the East Asian “Tigers” (vis-à-vis Japan). Fiscal policy in sub-Saharan Africa since 1960: a synopsis Fiscal structures and pressures at independence Great Britain and France managed their colonies as fiscally autonomous entities, and granted aid and subsidies in exceptional circumstances only (Ehrlich, 1973: 662; SuretCanale, 1971: 342). Portugal treated Angola and Mozambique as provinces; as such, they were constitutionally prohibited from running budget deficits (Samuels & Abshire, 1969: 235). Furthermore, the metropolitan powers exercised strict control over colonial borrowing. These arrangements ensured that the public finances of the colonies were sound, and the (admittedly scant) evidence indicates that African countries had low public debt burdens at independence (cf. Fieldhouse, 1986: 51-53; United Nations Economic Commission for Africa, 1968: 205-207). They also inherited basic revenue collection and public expenditure management systems.6 On the whole, however, sub-Saharan African countries embarked upon independence with extremely fragile systems of public finance.7 Their tax bases were narrow, and most countries depended heavily on customs duties and, to a lesser extent, export taxes for government revenue. Other indirect taxes, such as excise and sales taxes, also contributed significant amounts to the public coffers of some countries. With the exception of a few countries – notably South Africa – low per capita incomes, small corporate sectors and limited revenue collection capacity had prevented the development of broad-based personal and company income tax systems. At the same time, pressures to increase public spending were strong and fuelled by rapid population growth. Independence brought new responsibilities for African governments, including the maintenance of defence forces and diplomatic missions abroad. Furthermore, new rulers were expected to quickly upgrade their countries’ deficient physical infrastructures and social services. The colonial states’ investment in physical 6 For a comparison of British- and French-based systems of public expenditure in sub-Saharan African countries, see Lienert (2004). 7 The remainder of this section draws heavily on two early overviews of public finance systems in Africa by the United Nations Economic Commission for Africa (1961; 1968). 6 infrastructure was heavily influenced by the needs of sectors involved in international commodity trading: ports and rail networks were established and maintained, whereas road networks and the supply of electricity were neglected (Fieldhouse, 1986: 35-36). At independence the education and health systems of the vast majority of sub-Saharan African countries were also severely underdeveloped. In 1960 the adult literacy rate on the African continent was only 16%, and the average primary and secondary school enrolment rates were 36% and 3% of the relevant age groups respectively (Fieldhouse, 1986: 34). According to the World Bank (1981: 10) the entire region, excluding South Africa, at the time produced some 8,000 secondary school graduates per annum and had less than 10,000 university students, with 40% of the former and some 65% of the latter group coming from Ghana and Nigeria. The weak human resource base cemented African countries’ heavy dependence on expatriate professional, managerial and technical skills, including those required for policymaking and implementation. In many key sectors, however, the required skills were not found abroad either. Thus, in 1960 sub-Saharan Africa (excluding South Africa) had one physician for every 50,000 people, compared to one for every 12,000 people in other low-income countries (World Bank, 1981: 10). Such skills shortages were evident in the continent’s poor levels of social development. To name but one example: in 1960 the mortality rate of children aged four or younger (39 per 1,000) was more than 50% higher than the average for all developing countries (23 per 1,000) (World Bank, 1981: 10). The twin problems of a narrow tax base and heavy pressure for increased government spending were obviously not unique to sub-Saharan African countries. To a greater or a lesser extent, they were (and continue to be) germane to all developing countries.8 Be that as it may, the fragility of the fiscal systems inherited by almost all the newly independent countries of sub-Saharan Africa meant that the sustainable management of the public finances required considerable wisdom, sustained economic growth and even some good luck (in the form of an absence of severe exogenous shocks). Fiscal crises and reform The complexity of fiscal management in the sub-Saharan African context became apparent as early as the 1950s, the decade in which the decolonisation process got off the 8 In fact, some aspects of the public finances were in better shape in sub-Saharan Africa than elsewhere in the developing world. For example, a comparative study of tax effort in developing countries in the first half of the 1960s (Lotz & Morss (1967), found that African countries generally exploited their tax bases more effectively than their Latin American counterparts. 7 ground. In a review of fiscal developments from 1950 to 1958, the United Nations Economic Commission for Africa (1961) showed that nearly all the African countries for which data were available had experienced rapid growth in government expenditure. Indeed, the growth in public spending outpaced that of government revenue to such an extent that several countries severely depleted reserve funds accumulated to finance future capital spending. According to the United Nations Economic Commission for Africa (1961: 6-7), the major reasons for the rapid growth in government outlays in Africa during the 1950s were the assumption of additional responsibilities by the governments of newly independent countries, the expansion of social services (notably education, health care and low-cost housing) and increases in recurrent spending related to earlier development programmes. The pattern of faster growth in outlays than in revenues continued during the 1960s and 1970s. At the ideological level it reflected one or more of several influences ranging from a strong focus on post-independence nation-building to statist socialist ideas and the heavily interventionist Western theories of economic development of the time (Wolgin, 1997: 54). In practical terms, the sources of government spending growth in sub-Saharan Africa ranged from the laudable to the downright wasteful. A major portion of the additional public spending was much needed and contributed to notable improvements in the values of several indicators of economic development in sub-Saharan Africa during the second half of the 20th century. These indicators include life expectancy at birth, female enrolment in primary and secondary education, and stocks of physical infrastructure (cf. Sender, 1999: 90-96). In many cases, factors such as increases in global interest rates, civil wars and political conflict also stimulated rapid growth in government spending. The major problems, however, were politically motivated expansion of public employment and excessive intervention in economic activity aimed at accelerating the processes of development and industrialisation. Many governments were guilty of heavily subsidising loss-making public enterprises, of providing quasi-fiscal support to central banks involved in the allocation of subsidised foreign exchange and credit, and of using windfall gains from commodity booms to fund expenditure with minimal economic returns. The result was that many African countries expanded the provision of regulatory, economic and social services beyond their fiscal and administrative capacities, eventually making it impossible to maintain – let alone expand – service provision (Williams 2004: 4). The small population size of many countries in relation to the full spectrum of government services associated with independent states arguably was a contributing factor. 8 Moreover, the resulting high budget deficits fuelled the accumulation of crippling external debt burdens. During the 1970s, for example, the average public deficit of African countries amounted to 6.4% of GDP – well above the corresponding figures for Latin America and the Caribbean (4.6%), other developing countries (4.5%) and the OECD countries (1.2%) (Schmidt-Hebbel, 1996: 11). According to Greene (1989: 840), the external debt of sub-Saharan African countries increased from 14.6% of the region’s GDP in 1970 to 28.7% in 1980.9 Debt service payments accordingly increased from 7.8% of the region’s exports of goods and services to 13.7%. The region’s debt burden remained manageable while it experienced rapid economic growth (which, in many cases, was closely linked to buoyant commodity prices). Matters came to a head, however, with the global slowdown in economic growth after the second oil price shock in 1979 and 1980. The external debt burden of sub-Saharan Africa, which was still dominated by publicly guaranteed liabilities, mushroomed from 28.7% of GDP (96.2% of exports of goods and services) in 1980 to 53.0% of GDP (250.1% of exports of goods and services) in 1985 (Greene, 1989: 840). Over the same five-year period, actual debt service payments rose from 13.7% of exports of goods and services to 33.9%.10 Progressively worsening macroeconomic conditions and dwindling access to private foreign capital forced more and more African countries to borrow from the International Monetary Fund (IMF) or the World Bank, thus subjecting them to the lending conditionalities imposed by the Bretton Woods institutions and the uncertainty of official aid flows. Figure 1 shows how the number of active IMF programmes in sub-Saharan Africa increased from the mid-1980s onwards. In most years since 1988, at least 20 of the 48 sub-Saharan African countries had an IMF loan with policy conditionalities. The figure also emphasises that the nature of IMF lending to African countries has changed entirely from shorter-term facilities aimed at resolving balance of payments difficulties (Stand-By Arrangements and Extended Fund facilities) to longer-term structural adjustment facilities with wider-ranging policy conditionalities (Structural Adjustment Facilities, Enhanced Structural Adjustment Facilities and Poverty Reduction and Growth Facilities). If the combined impact of policy conditionalities and the policy surveillance and technical assistance activities of the Fund and the World Bank are taken into account, it is probably 9 The publicly guaranteed portion of sub-Saharan Africa’s external amounted to 85% and 75% of the total amounts in 1970s and 1980s respectively (Greene, 1989: 839). 10 Greene (1989: 841) estimates that scheduled debt service payments (the sum of actual payments and arrears) approached 50% of exports of goods and services in 1986 and 1987. 9 fair to say that the evolution of budgetary policies in the region during the past twenty-five or so years have been shaped heavily by the views of these institutions, the core fiscal aspects of which have been the Washington consensus elements summarised earlier. This conclusion should be qualified in two ways. The first point is that the fiscal-policy views of the Bretton Woods institutions are not formed in a vacuum. As Peter Heller (2000:3) put it: While the IMF has certainly contributed to the literature on the economic and financial impact of fiscal policy, it is not its own insights that principally distinguish the IMF's perspective. The IMF is clearly a user of a body of theoretical and empirical analysis that has been elaborated over the last halfcentury… and thus much of its views are likely to be seen as in the mainstream of conventional wisdom on fiscal policy. A second point that suggests that the actual influence of the IMF on fiscal policymaking in sub-Saharan Africa (and elsewhere in the developing world) has been less powerful than is commonly thought is the relatively poor implementation record of structural adjustment programmes – an issue to which we return later in this section. Figure 1 Active IMF programmes in sub-Saharan Africa (1976-2004) 33 30 27 24 21 18 15 12 9 6 3 0 1976 1980 1984 Total 1988 1992 SAF/ESAF/PRGF 1996 2000 SBA/EFF Source: International Monetary Fund (various issues) 2004 10 Looking back at the past twenty-five or so years of fiscal reform in sub-Saharan Africa, several events or developments stand out as having been of particular significance. The first was the shift in emphasis in the IMF from an almost exclusive focus on the macroeconomic aspects of fiscal policy (embodied in adjustment-programme ceilings for the levels of budget balances and public spending) to a broader perspective that includes microeconomic issues such as the details of tax reform and public spending priorities. The Fund initially regarded involvement in such microeconomic issues as unnecessarily resource-intensive activities and – more importantly – as interference in the domestic affairs of borrowing countries. But in the 1980s it became clear that the so-called macroeconomic and microeconomic dimensions of fiscal policy are too closely intertwined to be viewed in isolation. Countries typically needed microeconomic (structural) reforms to complement the growth-promoting effect of fiscal stabilisation, and the various tax and expenditure options for reducing budget deficits can have very different effects on growth, the efficiency of resource allocation, and the distribution of income (Tanzi, 1987). This shift in emphasis paved the way, within and outside the IMF, for greater appreciation of the need to shift the burden of expenditure cutbacks to less productive items (such as defence spending and subsidies to public enterprises) while protecting social spending and public investment. It also highlighted the common tendency among African and other developing countries to maintain their often bloated public payrolls during adjustment while allowing inflation to erode real pay levels – a tactic that contributed greatly to low productivity, poor service delivery and corruption in the public sector, as well as losses of skills to the private sector (Lindauer, Meesook & Suebsaeng, 1988). A second event that has had important ramifications for the process of fiscal reform in subSaharan Africa is the increasing emphasis on governance. This has contributed to the review of the role of government referred to earlier – in particular by highlighting that the government should contribute not only to allocative efficiency (by ensuring that the public sector does the right things), but also to technical or X-efficiency (by ensuring that these “right things” are done as well as possible). Governance-enhancing efforts in the area of civil service reform focus on the improvement of systems and operations and the creation of incentives for attracting quality human resources to the public sector; accordingly, they are known as second-generation reforms to distinguish them from the initial efforts to reduce government employment and to reverse pay erosion (Ul Haque & Aziz, 1999: 76). The growing focus on governance has also called attention to broader issues; in an important report about fostering good governance in Africa, the African Development Bank 11 (2001) emphasised considerations such as the creation of an enabling environment for private-sector growth (which includes institutional foundations such as the rule of law, security of property rights, et cetera) and accountable and transparent economic management.11 Thirdly, although various aspects of the World Bank/IMF Heavily Indebted Poor Country (HIPC) debt-relief initiative remain controversial, its launching reflected the recognition by the global community that the sustainable resolution of the fiscal (and broader economic) predicaments of the world’s poorest countries requires more than internal policy reform. Concrete steps should also be taken to improve the global economic environment within which these countries – the majority of which are in sub-Saharan Africa – attempt to bring and keep their houses in order. In the same vein, the IMF’s Annual Report for 2004 (International Monetary Fund, 2004b: 11) calls for more aid to poor countries, the continuation of debt relief and greater access to the markets of industrial countries. In another development that may prove to be particularly significant for the future of fiscal reform in sub-Saharan Africa, recent IMF assessments of the effectiveness of structural adjustment have emphasised the importance of country ownership of reforms. The notion of country ownership essentially boils down to strong government commitment to the implementation of reforms.12 Several IMF studies (eg Khan & Sharma, 2002) have probed the possibility that the high failure rate of the traditional carrot and- stick approach of lending conditionalities is related to inadequate country ownership.13 One of the outcomes of this development has been that adjustment efforts supported by the Fund's Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility (PRGF) are now guided by country-owned Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers (PRSPs). Of course, commitment is as important in “home- 11 The current emphasis on property rights reminds one of an anecdote in a speech by former IMF Managing Director Michel Camdessus. He told the story of two government leaders at opposite sides of the world who both told him that the most important ministry in the process of economic development was that of justice. 12 The IMF (2001: 6) defines country ownership as “… the assumption of responsibility for an agreed program of policies, by officials in a borrowing country who have the responsibility of carrying out these policies, based on an understanding that the program is achievable and is in the country’s own interest”. 13 Ivanova, Mayer, Mourmouras and Anayiotos (2003) found that 70% of the 170 Fund-supported programmes approved between 1992 and 1998 experienced interruptions, while 44% were not completed. A major study by the IMF's Independent Evaluation Office (2003) reported that Fund-supported fiscal adjustment programmes achieve only about one-half of the programmed change in fiscal balances, with some 60% of such programmes underperforming with regard to their deficit targets. In fiscal adjustment programmes, the probability of success is closely related to the state of the business cycle at the onset of reform (Bulir & Moon, 2003). Of course, failure on the part of governments to accept ownership for economic reform programmes can be indicative of the perception that the accompanying lending conditionalities are politically or economically infeasible. 12 grown” reform efforts (such as that undertaken by South Africa in the 1990s and Nigeria's ongoing National Economic Empowerment and Development Strategy) as in Fundsupported ones. An assessment of the fiscal reforms Attempts to assess the success of fiscal reforms in sub-Saharan Africa since the early 1980s are complicated by the diverse fiscal structures and experiences of the 48 countries in the region. Several broad trends can nonetheless be discerned. In this section we review the existing literature on these trends and summarise information from various IMF and World Bank databases to accentuate salient points. Reliable time-series data on public-debt levels in sub-Saharan African countries are too scarce to enable assessment of debt sustainability. Despite the very real possibility that reductions in budget deficits do not necessarily improve the net worth of the government (cf. Easterly, 1999), we therefore first consider trends in budget balances. Figure 2 shows that budget balances improved significantly in many countries, especially from the mid1990s onwards: the GDP-weighted central government balance for sub-Saharan Africa as a whole changed from a deficit of 6.9% of GDP in 1981 (and a peak of 8.2% in 1993) to a surplus of 0.2% in 2005 (International Monetary Fund, 2006: 203). The trend is not affected when the two largest economies in sub-Saharan Africa (South Africa and Nigeria) are excluded from the calculation. In 2004 fully 18 sub-Saharan African countries achieved grants-inclusive budget surpluses or deficits that did not exceed 3% of GDP (International Monetary Fund, 2005: 30).14 Further consolidation may well be needed in many countries – Adam and Bevan (2005) recently found statistical evidence of a growth payoff to reducing the budget deficit (including grants) to 1.5% of GDP – but it clearly is no longer true that the majority of African countries suffer from large budget deficits. A growing body of literature suggests that not only the extent but also the details of fiscal consolidation matter for its sustainability and its impact on economic growth (cf. Gupta, Clements, Baldacci & Mulas-Granados, 2004a; 2004b). Table 1 summarises changes in key fiscal aggregates in sub-Saharan Africa from 1980 to 2003. For each aggregate, the table provides the unweighted means of the averages for the periods 1980-1982 and 14 We use the cut-off value of 3% of GDP here simply to indicate that almost 40% of the countries of subSaharan Africa met the Stability and Growth Pact deficit rule of the European Economic and Monetary Union in 2004. It has no independent normative value in the sub-Saharan African context. 13 2000-2003 for all countries for which data are available. The data are from various editions of the World Bank’s African Development Indicators. % of GDP Figure 2 Mean GDP-weighted central government budget deficits in sub-Saharan Africa (1981-2007) 2 1 0 -1 -2 -3 -4 -5 -6 -7 -8 -9 -10 -11 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 All countries Excluding SA and Nigeria Source: IMF World Economic Outlook database (April 2006) Note: Values for 2006 and 2007 are projections The unweighted mean revenue-to-GDP ratio (inclusive of grants) decreased from 23.9% in the period 1980-1982 to 22.9% in the period 2001-2003, whereas the unweighted mean government spending ratio dropped from 31.0% of GDP to 27.0%. The reality that the interest payments increased significantly as a percentage of GDP in the vast majority of African countries over the past two decades means that the decrease in the unweighted mean primary-expenditure-to-GDP ratio was smaller than that in the overall expenditureto-GDP ratio. The revenue-to-GDP as well as the expenditure-to-GDP ratios decreased in the majority of countries. It therefore appears as if the trend toward lower budget deficits in sub-Saharan Africa mainly reflects expenditure cutbacks. The reality that so few countries in sub-Saharan Africa succeeded in increasing their revenue-to-GDP ratios (and especially the tax components thereof) is unfortunate in view of indications that deficit reductions 14 Table 1 Changes in selected fiscal aggregates in sub-Saharan Africa (1980-2003) Unweighted means 2001-03 1980-82 % of GDP: Revenue Grants Revenue and grants Expenditure and net lending Interest on public debt Primary expenditure and net lending % of total revenue: Taxes on income and profits Taxes on international trade Non-tax revenue % of total expenditure: Salaries and wages Other goods and services Interest on public debt Capital spending and net lending Number of countries: Total Increases Decreases 21.1 2.8 23.9 31.0 1.5 28.2 19.8 3.1 22.9 27.0 3.7 24.4 13 17 12 9 22 6 19 13 21 24 3 19 33 33 33 33 25 25 25.3 33.1 13.8 26.9 28.8 20.5 23 13 23 11 17 11 34 30 34 26.1 19.2 6.0 28.2 25.4 21.7 12.8 24.7 15 16 27 10 16 11 1 22 31 27 28 32 Source: World Bank (various issues) Note: Appendix Table A1 lists the countries included in each sample based mainly on revenue increases tend to persist longer in developing countries than those based mainly on expenditure cutbacks (cf. Gupta et al, 2004b).15 Tax reform is a complex undertaking in developing countries, especially when foreign aid is a major component of current revenue. A considerable number of sub-Saharan African countries reduced their dependence on taxes on international trade, partly in view of their price-distorting effects and partly to comply with World Trade Organisation agreements. The average share of total government revenue of such taxes decreased from 33.1% in the period 1980 to 1982 to 28.8% in the period 2001 to 2003, with decreasing shares reported in 17 of the 30 countries for which data are available. From an efficiency perspective this was a welcome development, but concern has been expressed over especially poorer developing countries’ apparent inability to recoup the lost revenue (Keen & Simone, 2004: 321-325). The vast majority of countries that have successfully recouped the revenue lost as a result of reductions in trade taxes did so by introducing value-added 15 Keen and Simone (2004) point out that increases in tax ratios were comparatively rare throughout the developing world in the 1990s. 15 tax – a high-yielding and relatively non-distorting tax that is now used widely in subSaharan Africa and elsewhere in the developing world (Keen & Simone, 2004: 315-321).16 Increased reliance on taxes on income and profits has also been common. The average revenue share of such taxes increased from 25.3% in the period 1980 to 1982 to 26.9% in the period 2001 to 2003, with increases in 23 of the 34 countries for which data are available. This trend occurred despite widespread reduction in personal and corporate income tax rates, which suggests some success with broadening the income tax base and/or improving tax administration. Of the thirteen countries for which we could obtain data for 1987 and 2002, eleven reduced their highest marginal income tax rates on individuals and twelve their highest rate on corporations. Some of the most significant reductions in the highest marginal rate on individuals occurred in Botswana (from 60% to 25%), Ghana (55% to 25%), Kenya (65% to 30%), Nigeria (70% to 25%), Tanzania (75% to 30%), Uganda (60% to 30%) and Zambia (75% to 30%). The biggest reductions in corporate tax rates occurred in Botswana (35% to 15%), Ghana (55% to 33%), Tanzania (50% to 30%), Uganda (60% to 30%) and Zimbabwe (53% to 30%). Weak tax administration has been a feature in many sub-Saharan African countries (see Stotsky & WoldeMariam, 1997), but the relatively successful introduction of VAT and the extent to which income tax yields have increased despite rate reductions suggest that progress is being made. A growing number of sub-Saharan African countries have established or are in the process of establishing semi-autonomous revenue authorities. These countries include Ghana, Kenya, Malawi, Mauritius, Rwanda, South Africa, Tanzania, Uganda and Zambia and several countries in West Africa (Fjeldstad & Rakner, 2003: 16). The effects of this step, however, have not been uniform across countries, ranging from major efficiency dividends in South Africa to stagnation of revenue after initial increases in Tanzania and Uganda. Turning to the composition of government expenditure, it is notable that the average expenditure shares of salaries and wages decreased from 1980-1982 to 2000-2002 in 16 of the 31 countries for which data are available. Few African countries made significant progress towards reducing civil service payrolls in the 1980s, and salary erosion (in real terms) remained the most widespread strategy for containing wage-bill growth (World Bank, 1994: 121-125). There are indications that the latter problem became less 16 In a sense, VAT disguises the partial continuation of tax on internationally traded goods: the tax base normally includes imported goods, while excluding exported goods. 16 widespread in the 1990s – in 19 of the 23 countries for which data are available in African Development Indicators, the average real salaries and wages of government employees were higher in the period 2001 to 2003 than in the period 1990 to 1992 – but cross-country information on trends in government employment is incomplete. Widespread curtailment of wage bill created some scope for increasing outlays on other goods and services, which expanded in 16 of the 27 countries for which data are available. This category of government spending includes outlays on the maintenance and operation of facilities and other assets – items that were often “crowded out” when wage bills grew rapidly (Lindauer et al, 1988: 21). Interest payments on public debt increased sharply from 6.0% of government expenditure during the period 1980 to 1982 to 12.8% in the period 2001 to 2003, with increases occurring in 27 of the 28 countries for which data are available. This trend, however, largely reflects the build-up of public debt during the first half of the 1980s: a similar comparison of the periods 1985-1987 and 1999-2001 shows decreases in the interest-toexpenditure ratios of the majority of a group of 27 countries, as well as a drop of 2 percentage points in the average interest-to-expenditure ratio of the group as a whole (Siebrits & Calitz, 2004b: 5). This confirms that faster economic growth, accelerated debt relief and smaller fiscal deficits recently have reduced the debt burdens of a number of sub-Saharan Africa countries. The releasing of budgetary resources for more productive ends is already assisting spending reprioritisation in several countries, and more stand to benefit if the recent proposal of the leaders of the Group of Eight (G8) countries to fully cancel the debts owed by participants in the HIPC initiative to the IMF, World Bank and African Development Bank is eventually implemented.17 Capital expenditure and net lending decreased from 28.2% of government expenditure in the period 1980 to 1982 to 24.7% in the period 2001 to 2003. The ratio between capital spending and total government outlays increased in only 109 of the 32 countries for which data are available. A proper assessment of this development requires information about the productivity of public investment in these countries, but it still appears to be the case that such spending often is targeted disproportionately when government expenditure is 17 In October 2004, the IMF estimated that the savings on debt service in countries that have reached their completion points in terms of the HIPC initiative had enabled pro-poor expenditure to rise by about 1.5% of GDP. Tanzania, for example, is using the revenues freed up from debt relief granted in 2001 under the HIPC initiative – about US$2 billion in net present value terms – to increase spending on education, health care and agricultural development, and to keep its debt levels sustainable (International Monetary Fund 2004b: 40). 17 reduced in sub-Saharan Africa. In a recent study, Gupta et al (2005) found that failure to protect capital spending during fiscal adjustment negatively affects economic growth in low-income countries – a finding which suggests that widespread public investment cutbacks probably represented one of the less desirable features of recent efforts to reduce budget deficits in sub-Saharan Africa. Considerations of space preclude a detailed discussion of trends in the functional composition of government expenditure in sub-Saharan Africa, but a few brief comments are in order. Sahn (1992) and Toye (2000: 27-33) reported that the governments of subSaharan African countries did not cut their spending on education and health nearly as much during reform periods as is often claimed by critics of structural adjustment. Since 1990, most countries in sub-Saharan Africa experienced drops in the GDP shares of military expenditure and public spending on education (the education cutbacks generally were of a marginal nature) and increases in the GDP ratio of public spending on health care (cf. United Nations Development Programme, 2004: 202-205). These developments suggest that modest progress was made with shifting public resources from military to social spending. A case study: fiscal adjustment in South Africa during the 1990s18 In the context of sub-Saharan Africa, South Africa has a particularly large and welldeveloped economy. One should therefore exercise caution when drawing lessons for other African countries from experiences in South Africa. South Africa’s fiscal adjustment during the 1990s, which has been hailed widely as particularly successful (cf. Tanzi, 2004: 539), nonetheless should be of considerable interest to the rest of Africa for at least two reasons. The first is that it occurred in a context very similar to that now facing many policymakers elsewhere in sub-Saharan Africa: fiscal discipline had to be restored while simultaneously addressing strong demands for redistributive public spending in a fledgling democracy characterised by a long period of relatively poor economic performance. The second is that the South African reform effort was entirely “home-grown” as opposed to driven by lending conditionalities imposed by multilateral institutions. It is therefore interesting to compare the contents and political dynamics of the reform effort with those of IMF/World Bank programmes. We discuss two aspects of fiscal policy in South Africa 18 This section draws heavily on Calitz and Siebrits (2003) and Siebrits and Calitz (2004a). 18 during the 1990s. First, what were the key fiscal policy priorities? Second, what were the results and how were they achieved? We conclude with a few observations. Priorities The post-apartheid government faced the dilemma of having to reconcile the imperative of fiscal discipline (necessitated by the macroeconomic situation and the prevailing views of “best fiscal practice” in the era of economic globalisation) with the growing demand for government expenditure resulting from political democratisation. The economic policy proposals of the African National Congress (ANC) initially exhibited socialist leanings, but the shifts that had occurred in the minds of economists, politicians, and business leaders across the globe with regard to the role of government influenced the views of the movement prior to its victory in the 1994 elections. The failure of macroeconomic populism to deliver sustainable growth in various Latin American countries during the 1970s and 1980s was a clear warning. Consequently, the post-apartheid South African Government adopted a non-populist macroeconomic strategy on growth, employment, and redistribution í known by the acronym GEAR í in 1996. Broadly in line with the Washington Consensus, the GEAR strategy acknowledged that macroeconomic stability is a necessary condition for sustained economic growth and job creation, with the latter as a necessary (though not sufficient) condition for sustainable poverty reduction and income redistribution. GEAR stressed the redistributive role of fiscal policy, but emphasised that the government intended to pursue it in a way that was compatible with macroeconomic stability. This approach reflected the conviction that higher economic growth provides the only option for financing the pent-up and growing demand for public services in South Africa in a sustainable manner. GEAR focused more on the medium and longer terms than on the short term and emphasised fiscal discipline, which the government regarded as a prerequisite for improving the longer-term growth potential of the South African economy. The fiscal goals of the GEAR strategy included a gradual reduction in the budget deficit to three per cent of GDP, maintenance of the total tax burden at 25% of GDP, the reduction of general government consumption expenditure as a percentage of GDP, and the gradual elimination of general government dissaving. The focus on fiscal discipline and other structural aspects of fiscal policy continued throughout the 1990s, and came to be associated closely with the stabilisation or even the reduction of the public sector’s claim on resources (including the total pool of savings). The strong emphasis on the pursuit of 19 price stability, based on the view that lower inflation is a necessary condition for sustained economic growth, further confirms the longer-term and structural focus of fiscal policy. Statements in the annual budget speeches of successive Ministers of Finance suggest that price stability was the most important macroeconomic objective of fiscal policy from 1994 until 1997, and the second most important in 1990, 1993, and 1998. During the 1990s, government budgets contained almost no measures aimed at deliberately stimulating economic growth in the short term. When growth regained pride of place as an objective of fiscal policy in 1999, the fiscal authorities emphasised its intention to promote growth by microeconomic reforms to boost the supply side of the economy, instead of deliberate demand stimulation. The government’s decision to adopt medium-term expenditure planning in 1998 further cemented the movement away from expenditure finetuning. In the 2001/02 Budget a post-apartheid Minister of Finance deliberately took a stimulatory macroeconomic policy stance for the first time. By 2005, the idea of a higher budget deficit (in the range of 2–3% of GDP) was acceptable to the financial sector and to international credit rating agencies. In 2005, South Africa’s international sovereign debt credit rating was upgraded yet again í this time by Standard and Poor’s í thus continuing the steady improvement in country risk ratings which had been experienced since the first ratings in 1994 and the country’s first global bond issue in December 1994. Distributional considerations became more important towards the end of the apartheid years, and significant reprioritisation of expenditure aimed at reducing interracial benefit gaps actually pre-dated the 1994 constitutional change. According to Van der Berg (2001: 257), per capita social expenditure on Africans increased from 12% of the white level in 1975 to 69% in 1993, with the major portion of the increase occurring between 1990 and 1993. The effort to increase the redistributive thrust of fiscal policy during the 1990s and beyond therefore formed part of a longer-term process. There can nonetheless be no doubt that the priorities of the South African Government have shifted further to distributional and poverty issues after 1994, especially after Trevor Manuel became Minister of Finance in 1996. 20 Results Although higher economic growth (which stimulated tax receipts and exerted downward pressure on ratios in which GDP is the denominator) and improved tax collection19 also contributed, developments during the second half of the 1990s and beyond left no doubts that the strategy of fiscal discipline paid dividends in the form of a significantly improved fiscal position. From 1993/94 to 2003/04, national government revenue increased from 21.9% of GDP to 23.4%, while total expenditure dropped from 27.5% of GDP to 25.7%. This latter trend appears to contradict the well-known Meltzer-Richard hypothesis on government expenditure growth, on the basis of which one would have expected the extension of the suffrage that accompanied the constitutional reform in 1994, to have resulted in a major increase in the share of government expenditure in the economy.20 In combination, the revenue and expenditure trends amounted to a fall in the budget deficit from 7.3% of GDP (1992/93) to 2.3% (2003/04). National government debt accordingly decreased from 50.4% of GDP at the end of 1996 to 37.0% at the end of 2004. In the process privatisation income was used to a significant degree to reduce the public debt. Since 1990, the South African Government’s efforts to promote economic growth by means of fiscal policies assumed a longer-term perspective and increasingly emphasised supply-side measures. Some aspects of fiscal policy boosted the longer-term growth prospects of the South African economy, while others added to the list of factors constraining economic growth. The positive aspects included steps that boosted investor confidence in the growth prospects of the South African economy, including the adoption of sound fiscal policies, accelerated depreciation allowances, and the opening-up of the economy by means of tariff reduction and the gradual dismantling of exchange controls. Government continued its attempts to build the country’s stock of human capital by investing heavily in education and health care. On the debit side, persistent (albeit decreasing) general government dissaving reduced the pool of savings that was available for investment to expand the productive capacity of the economy. In addition, the general government’s own contribution to gross capital formation, which had reached its highest 19 South Africa undertook a major overhaul and reform of its tax administration, which gained momentum when the tax authority gained administrative autonomy as a public body outside of the public service on 1 October 1997. During most of the second half of the 1990s and beyond the buoyancy of government revenue despite income tax rate reductions reflected much improved tax administration and tax compliance, inter alia. 20 For a possible explanation why this did not happen in South Africa, see Black, Siebrits and Van der Merwe (2005: 97-98). 21 post-1960 level of 10.6% in 1976, decreased steadily and reached a low of 2.4% in 1992. Subsequently, the fiscal authorities made considerable progress in eliminating government dissaving: the excess of general government current expenditure over general government current income dropped from 7.3% of GDP in 1992 to 0.8% in 2001 and 2002, the lowest level since 1982. The reality that the low levels of government investment were contributing to the deterioration of parts of the infrastructure (including the roads system, rolling stock of the railways, and water-supply capacity) was a further disincentive to private sector investment. There are also strong indications that inefficiency within government limited the potential growth-promoting effects of some of the largest and most important categories of government spending, including public order and safety, education, and health. During the 1990s, the fiscal authorities took a number of steps to increase allocative efficiency. The thrust of tax reform was broadly in line with the international trend towards broadening tax bases and reducing marginal rates (see Steenekamp & Döckel, 1993). The authorities broadened the tax base by eliminating various special tax preference schemes that benefited only particular industries or narrow sectoral interests, including the tax subsidies for training, welfare, health, and the general export incentive scheme (GEIS), as well as the interest rate subsidies for agriculture and housing. The overhaul of tax collection and administration indirectly broadened the tax base by reducing tax avoidance and evasion. The objective of reducing tax rates met with mixed success. The rate of income tax on companies fell from 50% at the beginning of the 1990s to 29% in 2005, but from 1993 onwards, distributed company profits became subject to a secondary tax on companies (STC). The STC rate increased from its initial level of 15% to 25% in 1994 and was then reduced to 12.5% in 1996. The top marginal rate of the personal income tax decreased from 45% to 43% in 1991, but reverted to 45% in 1995. This showed that there were times during the deficit-reduction process when efficiency considerations had to take a back seat to revenue needs. In 2002/03, when the deficit was under control, the authorities had room to lower the top marginal rate of the personal income tax to 40%. Privatisation of state assets progressed slowly, largely due to strong opposition from organised labour. Since March 1997, the Government fully sold various smaller assets (including six radio stations and Sun Air), as well as significant stakes in large public enterprises such as Telkom (30%), the Airports Company (25%) and South African Airways (20%). The total proceeds from privatisation as at 31 January 2005 was R33.7 billion. The fiscal authorities used almost three-quarters of the proceeds from 22 privatisation to finance government expenditure and the remainder to reduce the public debt. The authorities have attempted to pursue the objectives of redistribution and poverty alleviation in a sustainable manner by combining fiscal discipline with major changes in the distribution of public benefits and the incidence of financing costs, as well as far-reaching regulatory measures to redistribute assets and opportunities (including land reform, labourmarket legislation and the Broad-Based Black Economic Empowerment programme). The fiscal authorities changed the distribution of public benefits by changing the composition of government expenditure and by directly or indirectly privatising the provision of some public and merit goods. The most important development was the marked increase in the share of social spending in total government outlays. The period from 1990/91 to 2001/02 brought an increase in public outlays on social services from 38.6% of total general government spending (12.9% of GDP) to 45.6% (13.7% of GDP). This was made possible largely by expenditure reprioritisation, notably reductions in defence expenditure and outlays on economic services. Reprioritisation within functional categories of government outlays, such as increasing the importance of the primary education and primary health care components of social spending, further strengthened the distributive impact of these shifts. Increased private financing and private supply of the more sophisticated types of services (e.g. curative health care) accompanied these redistributive changes. A fiscal incidence study on the redistributive impact of more or less 60% of consolidated government expenditure (education, health, social grants, water provision and housing) during the period 1993 to 1997 affirmed the marked shift in social spending patterns from the more affluent to the poorer members of South African society (see Department of Finance, 2002: 145-46). The share of such spending benefiting the poorest 20% of households increased from 27.4% to 30.7%, while that of the wealthiest 20% dropped from 12.7% to 8.7%. From 1993 to 1997, per capita social service expenditure on the poor may have increased by as much as 34%. By contrast, outlays on the richest 20% of households probably decreased by more than 20% in per capita terms. The study also confirmed that the South African tax system is relatively progressive. It investigated the incidence of four major taxes (the personal income tax, the value added tax, specific excise duties, and the fuel levy), and found that the poorest 10% of income earners pay 11% of their incomes on these four taxes, whereas the richest 10% pay approximately 30%. 23 South Africa’s economic performance is still no match for that of fast-growing economies such as China and India, but nonetheless has improved significantly. The real average annual rate of economic growth recovered from -0.7% from 1990 to 1993 to 2.7% from 1994 to 1999 and 3.4% from 2000 to 2004. Consumer price inflation fell to a 25-year low of 5.2% in 1999, and in 2004 the inflation rate was 1.4%. By the end of 2004 the economy had been in an upward phase of the business cycle since September 1999 – a period of 64 months that represents the longest economic upswing since World War 2. The most disappointing result has been that formal-sector employment did not grown fast enough to reduce unemployment significantly. In 2006 the Government announced a shared and accelerated growth initiative for South Africa (ASGISA), aimed at achieving 6% economic growth per annum in 2010 and beyond. An analysis of this initiative falls outside the scope of this paper. Observations The South African experience leads to some important observations. It is possible for the government of a newly democratised developing country to consistently apply non-populist macroeconomic policies that meet with international best practice without losing popular support. This is confirmed by the fact that the ANC achieved overwhelming electoral support during the 1990s and increased it even further to obtain a two-thirds majority in the 2004 elections. There is a caveat, however: the current groundswell of popular discontent is a stark reminder of how important tangible local-level progress with the delivery of services is for the continued legitimacy of prudent economic policies. As we indicated earlier, the elements of South Africa’s fiscal reform effort had much in common with those of the Washington consensus. Despite all the scorn that has been heaped on the Washington consensus in recent years, the South African experience suggests that its fiscal elements have considerable merit as the broad contours for adjustment. By the same token, however, the South African case confirms that these elements are significantly more useful for achieving first-stage reform (which mainly consists of macroeconomic stabilisation) than for the considerably more complex second stage of reform (which includes priorities such as improving social conditions through enhanced service delivery and increasing international competitiveness by means of regulatory reforms and the restructuring of economic sectors) (cf. Naim, 24 1994). For success with second-stage reforms, developing countries would have to look beyond the Washington consensus for guidance. South Africa’s experience also underscores the importance of strong commitment to fiscal prudence. In the final analysis, it is such commitment (rather than lending conditionalities or elaborate rules) that makes or breaks fiscal adjustment. It should be added, though, that the discipline of the market place in the era of economic globalisation, from which no country can isolate itself, materially reduced the scope for adventurous deviating policies (cf. Calitz, 2003). It is also possible to affect significant budgetary redistribution while maintaining prudent and sustainable fiscal policies. However, reconciling these potentially conflicting priorities requires longer-term planning and consistent policy implementation. In 1997, the South African Government introduced medium-term fiscal planning, which added to transparency and facilitated orderly reprioritisation of budgetary resources. It also conveyed commitment to policy consistency, thereby adding to the credibility of selfimposed fiscal targets. Future challenges and prospects In closing, we comment on the key challenge now facing fiscal policymakers in subSaharan Africa: the need to consolidate and build on the positive developments of the last ten years. As we indicated earlier, the fiscal position of the sub-Saharan African region as a whole has improved markedly during the past ten years. By reducing excessive budget deficits and affecting changes to the structures of their tax and expenditure systems, many subSaharan African countries have extended their “fiscal space” and regained control over fiscal policymaking from the IMF and other external institutions. Most countries in the region nonetheless still face formidable fiscal challenges. Narrow tax bases and underdeveloped financial markets still leave many African countries highly dependent on grants and foreign borrowing as sources to finance government expenditure, while spending pressures and susceptibility to external shocks remain high. The gains of the recent past are therefore fragile. Moreover, the governance and service delivery deficiencies highlighted in the African Development Bank's African Development Report 2001 remain acute, as was affirmed by the findings of a survey commissioned by the United Nations Economic Commission for Africa (2004). 25 To consolidate the gains of the last decade and to tackle the remaining problems, it is imperative that sub-Saharan African policymakers commit themselves – and remain firmly committed – to sound fiscal policies. A question that arises in this respect is whether voluntary accession to evaluation of policymaking and -implementation practices in terms of the African Peer Review Mechanism (APRM) of the New Partnership for Africa’s Development (Nepad) would help to cement such commitments to fiscal prudence and to build policy credibility. The APRM is an authentically African institution and, as such, powerfully signals African leaders’ seriousness about good political and economic governance. The potential credibility benefits to accession to the Mechanism should therefore not be underestimated. The APRM, however, has at least three drawbacks as an instrument for further strengthening fiscal policymaking in sub-Saharan Africa: the reality that participation is voluntary, the vagueness of its assessment criteria21, and the lack of a credible enforcement agency. It is therefore our view that participation in the APRM (or, for that matter, the adoption of formal numerical rules such as those of the Stability and Growth Pact in the European Union) cannot substitute for sustained governmental commitment to fiscal prudence. References Adam, CS & Bevan, DL (2005): Fiscal deficits and growth in developing countries. Journal of Public Economics 89: 571– 597. African Development Bank (2001): African Development Report 2001. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Black, PA, Siebrits, FK & Van der Merwe, T (2005): Public expenditure and growth. In Black, PA, Calitz, E & Steenekamp, TJ (eds): Public Economics. 3rd edition. Cape Town: Oxford University Press: 83-103. Bulir, A & Moon, S (2003): Do IMF-supported programs make fiscal adjustment more durable? IMF Working Paper WP/03/38. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Calitz, E (2000): Fiscal implications of the economic globalisation of South Africa. South African Journal of Economics 68(4): 564-606. Calitz, E (2003): Economic policy: exploring the independence of South Africa. Journal for Studies in Economics and Econometrics 27(1): 21-38. Calitz, E & Siebrits, FK (2003): Fiscal policy in the 1990s. The South African Journal of 21 Fiscal indicators such as the following are used in APRM evaluations: the budget deficit as a percentage of GDP and its sustainability, government revenue as a percentage of GDP, public debt as a percentage of GDP and its sustainability, and the portion of the budget deficit financed by the central bank. However, Nepad documents do not suggest acceptable and inappropriate values of these indicators. See Nepad (2003: 16-18). The fiscal targets in existing regional frameworks for monetary integration (such as the SADC Memorandum of Understanding on Macroeconomic Convergence and the WAEMU Convergence, Stability, Growth and Solidarity Pact) are already much more specific than the Nepad criteria and indicators of fiscal performance. 26 Economic History 18(1&2): 50-75. Calitz, E & Siebrits, FK (2005): Fiscal policy. In Black, PA, Calitz, E & Steenekamp, TJ (eds): Public Economics. 3rd edition. Cape Town: Oxford University Press: 238-271. Collier, P & Gunning, JW (1999a): Why has Africa grown slowly? Journal of Economic Perspectives 13(3): 3-22. Department of Finance (2002): Budget Review 2002. Pretoria. Easterly, W (1999): When is fiscal adjustment an illusion? Economic Policy 14(28): 57-86. Ehrlich, C (1973): Building and caretaking: economic policy in British Tropical Africa, 18901960. Economic History Review 26(4): 649-667. Fieldhouse, DK (1986): Black Africa 1945-80: economic decolonization and arrested development. London: Allen & Unwin. Fjeldstad, O-H & Rakner, L (2003): Taxation and tax reforms in developing countries: illustrations from Sub-Saharan Africa. Unpublished paper. Bergen, Norway: Chr Michelsen Institute. Fosu, AK (2002): The global setting and African economic growth. Journal of African Economies 10(3): 282-310. Funke, N & Nsouli, SM (2003): The New Partnership for Africa’s Development (NEPAD): opportunities and challenges. IMF Working Paper WP/03/69. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Greene, J (1989): The external debt problem of sub-Saharan Africa. IMF Staff Papers 36(4): 836-874. Gupta, S, Clements, B, Baldacci, E & Mulas-Granados, C (2004a): Fiscal policy, expenditure composition, and growth in low-income countries. In Gupta, S, Clements, B & Inchauste, G (eds): Helping countries develop: the role of fiscal policy. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund: 23-47. Gupta, S, Clements, B, Baldacci, E & Mulas-Granados, C (2004a): Persistence of fiscal adjustments and expenditure composition in low-income countries. In Gupta, S, Clements, B & Inchauste, G (eds): Helping countries develop: the role of fiscal policy. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund: 48-66. Heller, P (2002): Considering the IMF's perspective on a “sound fiscal policy”. IMF Policy Discussion Paper PDP/02/8. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Independent Evaluation Office (2003): Fiscal adjustment in IMF-supported programs. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund. International Monetary Fund (2001): Strengthening country ownership of Fund-supported programs. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund. International Monetary Fund (2005): Regional economic outlook: Sub-Saharan Africa (September 2005). Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. International Monetary Fund (2006): World Economic Outlook (April 2006). Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. International Monetary Fund (various issues): Annual report. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Ivanova, A, Meyer, W, Mourmouras, A & Anayiotos, G (2003): What determines the implementation of IMF-supported programs? IMF Working Paper WP/03/8. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund. Keen, M & Simone, A (2004): Tax policy in developing countries: some lessons from the 1990s and some challenges ahead. In Gupta, S, Clements, B & Inchauste, G (eds): Helping countries develop: the role of fiscal policy. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund: 302-352. Khan, MS & Sharma, S (2002): Reconciling conditionality and country ownership. Finance and Development 39(2): 1-3. 27 Lienert, I (2004): A comparison between two public expenditure management systems in Africa. In Gupta, S, Clements, B & Inchauste, G (eds): Helping countries develop: the role of fiscal policy. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund: 494-528. Lindauer, D, Meesook, O & Suebsaeng, P (1988): Government wage policy in Africa. World Bank Research Observer 3(1): 1-25. Lotz, J & Morss, ER (1967): Measuring “tax effort” in developing countries. IMF Staff Papers 14: 478-499. Naim, M (1994): Latin America: the second stage of reform. Journal of Democracy 5(4): 32-48. New Partnership for Africa's Development (Nepad). 2003. Objectives, standards, criteria and indicators for the African Peer Review Mechanism. Sahn, D (1992): Public expenditures in sub-Saharan Africa during a period of economic reforms. World Development 20(5): 673-693. Samuels, MA & Abshire, DM (1969): Portuguese Africa: a handbook. New York: Praeger. Schmidt-Hebbel, K (1996): Fiscal adjustment and growth: in and out of Africa. Journal of African Economies 5(Supplement): 7-59. Sender, J (1999): Africa’s economic performance: limitations of the current consensus. Journal of Economic Perspectives 13(3): 89-114. Siebrits, FK & Calitz, E (2004a): Should South Africa adopt numerical fiscal rules? South African Journal of Economics 72(4): 759–783. Siebrits, FK & Calitz, E (2004b): Observations on fiscal policy in South Africa. Absa Economic Perspective 4th quarter: 2-9. Steenekamp, TJ & Döckel, JA (1993): Taxation and tax reform in LDCs: lessons for South Africa. Development Southern Africa 10(3): 319-333. Stotsky, J & WoldeMariam, A (1997): Tax effort in Sub-Saharan Africa. IMF Working Paper WP/97/107. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund. Suret-Canale, J (1971): French colonialism in Tropical Africa. London: C Hurst. Tanzi, V (1987): Fiscal policy, growth, and stabilization programs. Finance and Development 24: 15-17. Tanzi, V (2004): Globalization and the need for fiscal reform in developing countries. Journal of Policy Modelling 26: 525-542. Tanzi, V & Schuknecht, L (1997): Reforming government: an overview of recent experience. European Journal of Political Economy 13: 395-417. Toye, J (2000): Fiscal crisis and fiscal reform in developing countries. Cambridge Journal of Economics 24: 21-44. Ul Haque, N & Aziz, J (1999): The quality of governance: "second-generation" civil service reform in Africa. Journal of African Economies 8(Supplement): 68-106. United Nations Development Programme (2004): Human Development Report 2004. New York: Oxford University Press. United Nations Economic Commission for Africa (1961): Economic bulletin for Africa. New York: United Nations Organisation United Nations Economic Commission for Africa (1968): Survey of economic conditions in Africa. New York: United Nations Organisation. United Nations Economic Commission for Africa (2004): Striving for good governance in Africa. Addis Ababa. Williamson, J (2000): What should the World Bank think about the Washington consensus? World Bank Research Observer 15(2): 251-264. Wolgin, JM (1997): The evolution of economic policymaking in Africa. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 87(2): 54-57. World Bank (1981): Accelerated development in sub-Saharan Africa: an agenda for action. Washington DC: World Bank. 28 World Bank (1994): Adjustment in Africa: Reforms, Results, and the Road Ahead. New York: Oxford University Press. World Bank (2005): World Development Indicators 2005. Washington DC: World Bank. World Bank (various years): African Development Indicators. Washington DC: World Bank. 29 Appendix: Lists of countries included in the samples in Table 1 Variable(s) Countries Revenue, Grants, Revenue and grants, Expenditure and net lending Benin, Botswana, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cameroon, The Comoros, Cote d’Ivoire, Democratic Republic of the Congo, Ethiopia, Gabon, The Gambia, Ghana, Guinea, GuineaBissau, Kenya, Lesotho, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Mauritius, Niger, Nigeria, Republic of the Congo, Senegal, Seychelles, Sierra Leone, Sudan, Swaziland, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, Zambia and Zimbabwe Interest on public debt, Primary expenditure and net lending Benin, Burkina Faso, Cameroon, Democratic Republic of the Congo, Ethiopia, Gabon, The Gambia, Ghana, GuineaBissau, Kenya, Lesotho, Madagascar, Malawi, Mauritius, Niger, Nigeria, Republic of the Congo, Senegal, Seychelles, Sierra Leone, Swaziland, Tanzania, Uganda, Zambia and Zimbabwe Taxes on income and profits Benin, Botswana, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cameroon, The Comoros, Cote d’Ivoire, Democratic Republic of the Congo, Ethiopia, Gabon, The Gambia, Ghana, Guinea, GuineaBissau, Kenya, Lesotho, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Mauritius, Niger, Nigeria, Republic of the Congo, Rwanda, Senegal, Seychelles, Sierra Leone, Sudan, Swaziland, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, Zambia and Zimbabwe Taxes on international trade Benin, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cameroon, Cote d’Ivoire, Democratic Republic of the Congo, Ethiopia, Gabon, The Gambia, Ghana, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Kenya, Lesotho, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Mauritius, Niger, Nigeria, Republic of the Congo, Rwanda, Senegal, Seychelles, Sierra Leone, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, Zambia and Zimbabwe Non-tax revenue Benin, Botswana, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cameroon, Cote d’Ivoire, Democratic Republic of the Congo, Ethiopia, Gabon, The Gambia, Ghana, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Kenya, Lesotho, Liberia, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Mauritius, Niger, Nigeria, Republic of the Congo, Rwanda, Senegal, Seychelles, Sierra Leone, Sudan, Swaziland, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, Zambia and Zimbabwe Salaries and wages Botswana, Burkina Faso, Cameroon, Cote d’Ivoire, Democratic Republic of the Congo, Djibouti, Ethiopia, Gabon, The Gambia, Ghana, Guinea-Bissau, Kenya, Lesotho, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Mauritius, Niger, Nigeria, Republic of the Congo, Rwanda, Senegal, Seychelles, Sierra Leone, Sudan, Swaziland, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, Zambia and Zimbabwe Other goods and services Burkina Faso, Cameroon, Democratic Republic of the Congo, Cote d’Ivoire, Djibouti, Ethiopia, Gabon, The Gambia, Ghana, Guinea-Bissau, Kenya, Lesotho, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Mauritius, Niger, Nigeria, Rwanda, Senegal, Seychelles, Sierra Leone, Sudan, Swaziland, Togo, Zambia and Zimbabwe Interest on public debt Burkina Faso, Cameroon, Cote d’Ivoire, Democratic Republic of the Congo, Ethiopia, Gabon, The Gambia, Ghana, GuineaBissau, Kenya, Lesotho, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Mauritius, Niger, Nigeria, Republic of the Congo, Rwanda, 30 Senegal, Seychelles, Sierra Leone, Swaziland, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, Zambia and Zimbabwe Capital spending and net lending Botswana, Burkina Faso, Cameroon, The Comoros, Cote d’Ivoire, Democratic Republic of the Congo, Djibouti, Ethiopia, Gabon, The Gambia, Ghana, Guinea-Bissau, Kenya, Lesotho, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Mauritius, Niger, Nigeria, Republic of the Congo, Rwanda, Senegal, Seychelles, Sierra Leone, Sudan, Swaziland, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, Zambia and Zimbabwe