Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Intra-industry Trade and Industry Distribution of Productivity: A Cournot-Ricardo Approach April, 2009 E. Young Song* Department of Economics Sogang University * Department of Economics, Sogang University, C. P. O. Box 1142, Korea Tel: +82-2-705-8696, Fax: +82-2-705-8180, E-mail: [email protected] Intra-industry Trade and Industry Distribution of Productivity: A Cournot-Ricardo Approach E. Young Song* Sogang University Abstract This paper constructs a Cournot-Ricardo model of trade by incorporating Cournot competition in a Ricardian trade model. In this model, the share of intra-industry trade in bilateral trade volume decreases as trading partners become more different in terms of the industry distribution of labor productivity. We show that this relationship is a special case of a more general relationship: the share of intra-industry is decreasing in a specialization index. This specialization index turns out to be equal to the difference in the industry distribution of productivity in the case of our CournotRicardo model, while it is given by the difference in capital-labor in the well-known case of monopolistic competition. As both technologies and factor endowments would be important in shaping specialization patterns in the real world, we conjecture that the share of intra-industry trade is decreasing in two measures of specialization: the difference in the industry distribution of productivity and the difference in capital-ratio. Our OLS estimations strongly support this conjecture. In fixed effects regressions, both measures lose significance in the entire sample, but the industry distribution of productivity is significant in explaining trade between high income countries. Key words: Intra-industry trade; specialization; Cournot; labor productivity; industry distribution JEL classification: F11, F12 * Department of Economics, Sogang University, C. P. O. Box 1142, Korea Tel: +82-2-705-8696, Fax: +82-2-705-8180, E-mail: [email protected] 1 I. Introduction The monopolistic competition model of trade, founded by Dixit and Norman (1980), Krugman (1979) and Lancaster (1979), dominates economists’ way of thinking on intra-industry trade. The dominance is equally true in empirical arena. The finding of Helpman and Krugman (1985) that the monopolistic competition model implies an inverse relationship between the share of intra-industry trade and the difference in relative factor endowments set the stage for theory-based empirical research on intra-industry trade. Helpman (1987), Hummels and Levinsohn (1995) and many others tested this implication. These studies found somewhat mixed results, but they succeeded in placing the Chamberlinian perspective on the center stage of empirical research on intra-industry trade. Davis (1995) challenged the monopolistic competition model as an exclusive tool for understanding intra-industry trade. He showed that by introducing cross-country productivity differences in a Heckscher-Ohlin world, one can easily generate intra-industry trade. This Ricardo-Heckscher-Ohlin model also predicts that intra-industry will be high between countries with similar factor endowments. In a partial equilibrium framework, we can find another important approach to intra-industry trade. Brander (1981), and Brander and Krugman (1983) showed that international Cournot competition in segmented markets generate intra-industry trade. Bernhofen (1998) finds a good fit between the Cournotian model and the pattern of intra-industry trade observed in petrochemical industries. This paper extends the Cournotian model to a general equilibrium theory. We merge the model of Brander (1981) with the Ricardian model of Dornbusch, Fischer and Samuelson (1977). 2 From this Cournot-Ricardo model, we derive a new determinant of intra-industry trade: the industry distribution of labor productivity. The model implies that the share of intra-industry trade in bilateral trade volume increases as the industry distribution of labor productivity becomes more similar between trading partners. We try to understand this finding in a larger theoretical framework. We derive a general relationship that the share of intra-industry trade is decreasing in a specialization index, and is increasing in bilateral trade volume relative to the product of partner incomes. We go on to show that the specialization index turns out to be equal to the difference in the industry distribution of labor productivity in the case of the Cournot-Ricardo model. We also demonstrate that the famous prediction of the monopolistic competition model is a special case of the general relationship that we found: in the case of monopolistic competition, the specialization index is given by the difference in capital-labor ratio. The industry distributions of productivity or relative factor endowments affect the share of intra-industry trade because they determine the degree of specialization between trading partners. We put these theoretical observations to a test. Using production and trade data compiled by Nicita and Olarreaga (2006), we find that the degree of specialization indeed has a strong negative effect on the share of intra-industry trade. This relationship holds well in both OLS and fixed effects models. We also investigate the relationship between the share of intra-industry and two measures of specialization: the difference in the industry distribution of productivity and the difference in capital-labor ratio. In OLS estimations, we find that both measures have strong negative effects on intra-industry trade. In fixed effects models, however, the relationship becomes fragile. Still, we find that the industry distribution of productivity is significant in 3 explaining trade between high income countries. The paper is organized as follows. Section II constructs the Cournot-Ricardo model. Section III makes some theoretical observations. Section IV conducts empirical investigations. Section IV concludes. II. A Cournot-Ricardo Model. The specifications for technologies and preferences are the same as in the Ricardian model of trade with a continuum of goods by Dornbusch, Fischer and Samuelson (1977-henceforth, the DFS model). Two countries produce a continuum of goods indexed on the unit interval [0, 1]. Labor alone is used to produce goods. Unit labor requirements for good z in the home and in the foreign country are given by a(z) and a*(z). We index goods such that home country comparative advantage diminishes as z increases. Defining relative unit labor requirements as a*(z) A(z) a(z) , (1) A(z) is decreasing in z. Labor is perfectly mobile between industries. We use w and w* to denote the competitive wages in the home and in the foreign country. expresses the relative wage of the home country, w/w*. The two countries are populated by consumers with identical Cobb-Douglas tastes. Denoting the expenditure share of good z by b(z), the demand for good z in each country is determined by the following equations. 4 b(z) Y q(z) = p(z) , b(z) Y* q*(z) = p*(z) , (2) 1 with b(z) dz = 1. 0 q(z) and q*(z) are the demand for good z in the home and the foreign country. p(z) and p*(z) are the price of good z in the home and the foreign country. Y and Y* are the income levels of the two countries. The DFS model assumes that each industry is perfectly competitive. With costless trade, each good is supplied solely by the country with a lower unit cost. Thus we have no intra-industry trade. Instead we assume that each industry is a Cournot duopoly composed of a home firm and a foreign firm. As in Brander (1981), we assume that the home and the foreign market for each good z are segmented, and each firm makes distinct quantity decisions for each market. Given the unit-elastic demand curve in (2), it is easy to show that the following conditions should hold in equilibrium. p(z) = p*(z) = w a(z) + w* a*(z), (3) w* a*(z) s(z) = w a(z) + w* a*(z) = (4) A(z) . A(z) + The price of a good is identical in two countries and is determined by the sum of the duopolists’ unit costs. The market share of the home firm is given by s(z), which is increasing in the home country’s relative productivity A(z) and is decreasing in its relative wage . With the demand curves in (2), then the world supply of good z by the home firm is given by 5 s(z) (q(z) + q*(z)) = s(z) b(z) (Y + Y*) . p(z) (5) Likewise, the world supply of good z by the foreign firm is equal to (1 - s(z)) (q(z) + q*(z)) = (1 - s(z)) b(z) (Y + Y*) . p(z) (6) Let us define E[s] as the mean of s(z) over goods, where the density is given by the expenditure share of a good b(z). 1 s( z)b( z)dz . E[s] 0 To clear the home labor market, the labor supply L must be equal to the sum of the home firms’ labor demand across industries. L= 1 a( z)s( z)(q( z) q * ( z))dz 0 1 = s( z )(1 s ( z ))b( z )dz 0 Y Y * . w (7) Similarly, for the foreign country, 1 L* = a*(z) (1-s(z)) (q(z) + q*(z)) dz 0 1 = s( z )(1 s ( z ))b( z )dz 0 Y Y * . w* (8) Dividing (8) by (7), w L* = w* = L . (9) The relative wage is determined by the ratio of labor endowments. Then using equation (4), we can express the market share of the home country in each industry as a function of the two parameters: comparative advantage and relative labor endowment. 6 A(z) L/a(z) s(z) = A(z) + L*/L = L/a(z) + L*/a*(z) . (10) The income level of the home country is equal to the total expenditure on domestically produced goods. Thus Y= 1 s( z)b( z)(Y Y *)dz = E[s] (Y+Y*). (11) 0 Thus, the mean market share E[s] also equals the share of home GDP in world GDP. By construction, we have intra-industry trade in every industry. Each country supplies a fraction of each other’s market and cross-hauling occurs in every industry. Note that the size of the foreign market is equal to b(z) Y*. As the home firm supplies the fraction s(z) of this market, the exports of the home country in industry z is given by x(z) = s(z) b(z) Y* = s(z) b(z) (1-E[s]) (Y+Y*). (12) Likewise, the imports of the home country in industry z is given by m(z) = (1-s(z)) b(z) Y = (1-s(z)) b(z) E[s] (Y+Y*). (13) The net export of good z is then equal to x(z)-m(z) = (s(z) - E[s]) b(z) (Y+Y*). (14) Thus in an industry where the home country is more competitive than in the average market, it becomes a net exporter. Recall that s(z) is increasing in A(z). Thus the ratio of net export to the market size increases as the comparative advantage of the home country increases. Our CournotRicardo model preserves the basic Ricardian flavor. Using three equations above, we can calculate the Grubel-Lloyd index of intra-industry trade, 7 1 x( z) m( z) dz GL = 1 ( x( z) m( z))dz 0 1 = 1 E[ s[ z ] E ( s) ] . 2 E[ s](1 E[ s]) (15) 0 Note that E[s(z)-E[s]] is the mean absolute deviation of market shares from the national mean. The intensity of intra-industry between two countries decreases as the dispersion of market shares across industries increases. To link the dispersion index to the parameters of the model, let us denote the home labor productivity in industry z by z) (= 1/a(z)) and the foreign counterpart by z) (= 1/a*(z)). We first linearize equation (4) in terms of z) and z) around their respective means E[ and E[Thenwe substitute the linearized function s(z) into equation (15) and obtain the following equation. 1 ( z) * ( z) GL 1 E[ ]. 2 E ( ) E ( *) (16) Equation (16) is the key result of this paper. The intensity of intra-industry trade increases as the distribution of (z)/E[ across industries matches more closely with that of (z)/E[. In other words, intra-industry trade will be intense between countries that have similar industry distributions of labor productivity (relative to the national mean). III. Some Theoretical Observations In this section, we make some theoretical observations and try to understand the results of the previous section from a larger perspective. Let us use the following notations. Xijk is the value of good k shipped from country i to country j. Xij is the value of all goods shipped from country i to country j. Yik is the value of good 8 k produced in country i, and Yi is the value of all goods produced in country i. We use YW to denote the world production, Yi. Using these notations, we present the following propositions. i [Proposition 1] The world is composed of two countries i and j. They trade with each other with zero costs and trade is balanced. Consumers have identical homothetic preferences. Then IIT GRAV , SPEC (17) where 1 IIT and GL = 1 1 GL GRAV = SPEC = X ij Yi Y j YW 1 2 X ijk X kji X ij X ji , , ik kj , ik k k Yi k . Yi The proof is in the appendix. GL is the Grubel-Lloyd index of intra-industry trade. IIT stands for intra-industry trade. It increases from 1 to infinity as GL goes from 0 to 1. GRAV, which stands for gravity, is the ratio of bilateral trade to the product of partner incomes (scaled by world income). Let us call this ratio the gravity coefficient. It is well-known that the gravity coefficient is equal to unity in a world where the simple or ‘frictionless’ gravity equation holds. With trade frictions, the coefficient falls below unity. SPEC is an index of specialization between trading 9 partners. This index takes the minimum value of zero when two countries have an identical industry structure, and the maximum value of unity when there is complete specialization. Krugman (1991) employs the same index in his study on economic geography. Now it is widely used as an index of specialization between two regions. Proposition 1 states that given the volume of trade (relative to the product of partner incomes), the share of intra-industry trade in bilateral trade is decreasing in the degree of specialization between trading partners. It is important to understand that this relationship holds as an accounting identity under the hypotheses of Proposition 1. No economic theory has been used to derive the equation, and no causal chain is presumed among three variables. However, specific theories impose restrictions on these variables. For example, the following proposition can be derived from the model of the previous section. [Proposition 2] In the Cournot-Ricardo model of section II, SPEC 1 ( z) * ( z) E[ ], 2 E ( ) E ( *) (18) GRAV = 1. (19) The proof is simple. By equation (5), the value of good z produced in the home country is equal to p( z ) s( z )(q( z ) q * ( z )) s( z )b( z )(Y Y *) . By equation (11), the GDP of the home country is equal to E ( s )(Y Y *) . Thus the share of good z in home GDP is given by s( z )b( z ) / E ( z ) . Similarly, the share of good z in foreign GDP is given by (1 s( z ))b( z ) /(1 E ( z )) . The absolute value of the difference, summed (integrated) over all 10 goods, and divided by 2 is our specialization index SPEC. It is easy to show that this is equal to E[ s[ z] E(s) ] / 2E[s](1 E[s]) . From the linear approximation that we used to derive equation (16), equation (18) immediately follows. To calculate the total exports of the home country, we integrate x(z) in equation (12) over all goods. 1 X s( z )b( z )Y * dz E ( s)Y * 0 YY * . Y Y * (20) Thus GRAV is equal to 1.1 Now we can see that equation (16) is a special case of proposition 1. With the gravity coefficient fixed to unity, the Grubel-Lloyd index must be equal to one minus the specialization index, which in the Cournot-Ricardo model, is given by the difference in the industry distribution of labor productivity. We now turn to a well-known case. [Proposition 3] The world is composed of two countries i and j that produce two goods using capital K and labor L. Two countries have identical technologies and trade is costless. If trade equalizes factor prices, SPEC = c ki k j yi y j , (21) where ki K i / Li , yi Yi / Li and c is a constant that depends on the prices of two goods. K i and Li are capital and labor endowments of country i. The proof is in the appendix. Proposition 3 is interesting as it reveals the influential theory of intra-industry trade by Helpman and Krugman (1985) as a special case of proposition 1. From 1 This demonstrates that contrary to the popular belief, specialization is not necessary for the gravity equation to hold. In a different paper, we extend this observation and derive the general condition for the gravity equation. 11 the monopolistic competition framework, they derive the prediction that the share of intraindustry trade in bilateral trade volume increases as countries get more similar in their capitallabor ratios. To see the link with proposition 1, suppose that two goods produced in proposition 3 are product differentiated and subject to economies of scale as in the monopolistic competition model. Then we can easily show that the simple gravity condition holds and GRAV is equal to unity. By Proposition 1 IIT 1 yi y j c ki k j (22) As the difference in capital-labor ratio between trading partners decreases, IIT increases. Thus the inverse relationship between intra-industry trade and the difference in capital-labor ratio is a special case of proposition 1. In addition, we obtain the exact functional form for the relationship, which previous studies fail to provide. Furthermore, proposition 3 suggests an important control variable for this relationship: the product of per-capita incomes. Researchers on intra-industry trade repeatedly observed that intra-industry trade between low income countries is low even though they have similar capital-labor ratios. Thus they included the average level of development of trading partners in their regressions and found that this variable positively influences intra-industry trade.2 The product of per-capital incomes can be thought as a variable representing the average level of development. IV. Empirical Results In this section, we put our propositions to a test. We construct two regression equations. The first one is based on proposition 1. Taking the natural logarithm of equation (17) and adding 2 See Greeway and Milner (1986) 12 country and time subscripts and an error term, we obtain the following regression equation. log IITijt 0 1 log SPECijt 2 log GRAVijt ijt . (23) If all the conditions of proposition 1 are satisfied, regression equation (23) with 1 = and 2 = 1 will have a perfect fit. The error term arises because these conditions are violated in actual data. The most important violation is that we are living in a multi-country world and trade barriers exist among these countries. This will make country i trade more or less with country j than with other countries in the world, and proposition 1 will not hold exactly. Furthermore, preferences are neither identical nor homothetic, and there are heavy measurement errors in all these variables. What we would like to check is if proposition 1 still explain a significant part of the world despite all these violations. Our second regression equation comes from propositions 2 and 3. In the Cournot-Ricardo model, the degree of specialization is given by the difference in the industry distribution of labor productivity. To match with data, we use the following discrete version of the index. 1 k k* PRODIF E[ ], 2 E ( ) E ( * ) (24) where k denotes labor productivity in industry k. In the monopolistic competition model, the degree of specialization is determined by the difference in capital-labor ratio scaled by the product of per-capita incomes. KDIF ki k j yi y j . (25) We do not view two theories as mutually exclusive. Both the industry distribution of technology and relative factor endowments would influence the formation of specialization among countries. 13 So we let them compete in the following regression equation. log IITijt 0 1 log PRODIFijt 2 log KDIFijt 3 log GRAVijt ijt . (26) We do not force GRAV to take the value of unity as implied by the theory, because in the real world, trade barriers would be sure to reduce gravity. The data that we use come from Nicita and Olarreaga (2006). They provide data on outputs and the number of employees in 28 manufacturing industries (ISIC 3 digit level) for 100 countries. From the data, we can calculate output share and labor productivity by industry for each country, and hence SPEC and PRODIF for each country pair. They also report bilateral trade flows at ISIC 3digit level. The data well suit our purpose as they follow the same industry classification as productivity data. From these, we calculate the gravity and Grubel-Lloyd index for each country pair. Data on capital stock and GDP per worker are obtained from the Penn World Table version 6.2. We used the perpetual inventory method to create data on capital stock from investment flows. From this data set, we construct KDIF for each country pair. We will also use variables that are frequently used in the estimation of gravity equations: distance and dummies for common language, common border, island, landlock, colony and regional trade agreement. These variables come from Rose (2004). To construct SPEC and PRODIF, we should observe output shares and labor productivities in all industries of trading partners. Thus a large number of missing values in output data severely restrict the size of the panel. To lessen this restriction, we dropped four industries that seem to generate too many missing values. 3 The availability of data on capital stock puts a further 3 These industries are tobacco (314), other petro and coal products (354), petro refineries (353) and pottery, china, earthware (361). 14 restriction on the size of the panel. Due to these problems, almost all low incomes countries drop out of the sample. The data span years from 1976 to 2001, though observations are very thin at the front and rear end. Capital stock slowly changes over time and contains many measurement errors caused by inaccurate investment data and time-to-build. We have a similar problem with productivity data as technology slowly changes and labor hoarding over business cycles can contaminate productivity figures. For this reason, we focus on medium-term relationship between intraindustry and specialization, and use quadrennial observations. Dropping the thin ends, we choose years 1978, 1982, 1986, 1990, 1994 and 1998. Table 1: Means of Major Variables Trade Partners North-North North-South South-South Total GL 0.36 SPEC 0.27 GRAV 0.18 PRODIF 0.13 KDIF(104) 0.38 (0.18) (0.10) (0.31) (0.05) (0.40) 0.20 0.34 0.16 0.18 2.47 (0.12) (0.08) (0.33) (0.06) (1.37) 0.36 0.26 0.83 0.23 1.20 (0.16) (0.07) (0.81) (0.07) (1.18) 0.32 0.29 0.18 0.14 0.96 (0.18) (0.10) (0.33) (0.06) (1.22) Obs. 843 321 15 1,179 N = 428 T = 2.8 The numbers in the parentheses are standard deviations. Table 1 reports summary statistics for major variables. The total number of observations is 1,179. The number of country pairs included is 428 and the average number of observations per 15 country pair is 2.8. The panel is unbalanced. The table also divides observations into three income groups. Using the World Bank’s classification, we define a high or upper middle income country as a North country and a lower middle and low income country as a South country. 843 observations (72 %) are from North-North trade, and 321 (27 %) from North-South trade. Southsouth trade is almost ignored in the sample. The means of major variables are reported in the table. As expected, the Grubel-Lloyd index is higher in North-North trade than in North-South trade. The measures of specialization, SPEC, PRODIF and KDIF, are higher in North-South trade than in North-South trade. The gravity coefficient is slightly higher in North-North trade than in North-South trade. The numbers in the parentheses report standard deviations. We see a significant amount of variations in variables. However, most of them come from variations between trading partners. Despite using quadrennial data, time-series variations within trading partners are very limited, and more than 85 % of total variations come from between variations for all variables in the table. Combined with a small number of observations per country pair, this feature of data makes fixed effects estimation challenging. Table 2: Correlations log IIT 1.00 log SPEC log SPEC -0.53 1.00 log GRAV 0.30 0.12 1.00 log PRODIF -0.40 0.58 0.08 1.00 log KDIF -0.40 0.44 -0.04 0.40 log IIT log GRAV 16 log PRODIF log KDIF 1.00 Table 2 reports correlations among major variables. All variables now are logarithmic. In the first column, we can see that the correlation between IIT and SPEC is negative, and that between IIT and GRAV is positive, supporting proposition 1. In the second column, we observe that SPEC is positively correlated both with PRODIF and with KDIF, as implied by propositions 2 and 3. In the third and fourth column, we see that GRAV is not correlated with PRODIF or KDIF, but PRODIF and KDIF are positively correlated. 17 Table 3: Intra-industry Trade, Specialization and Gravity log IIT (1) (2) (3) OLS OLS Fixed Effects log SPEC log GRAV log Distance Language Border Island Landlock Colony 13 RTA dummies X O X R2 Obs. Year dummies are included in all regressions. Language(= 0, 1), Border= 0, 1), Island(= 0, 1, 2), Landlock(= 0, 1, 2) , Colony(=0, 1) are dummy variables. The numbers in the parentheses are tratios. The R2 of fixed effects regressions are from within regressions. T denotes the average number of observations per country pair. * : significant at 1%. ** : significant at 5%. 18 Table 4: Determinants of Intra-industry Trade: Productivity vs. Factor Proportion log IIT (4) (5) OLS (6) OLS Fixed Effects log KDIF log GRAV log Distance Language Border Island Landlock Colony 13 RTA dummies X O X R2 Obs. log PRODIF Year dummies are included in all regressions. Language(= 0, 1), Border= 0, 1), Island(= 0, 1, 2), Landlock(= 0, 1, 2) , Colony(=0, 1) are dummy variables. The numbers in the parentheses are tratios. The R2 of fixed effects regressions are from within regressions. T denotes the average number of observations per country pair. * : significant at 1%. ** : significant at 5%. 19 Table 3 reports the results of estimating equation (23). In all regressions, we included year dummies to control for time effects. In regression (1), we use an OLS estimation. The estimated coefficient on SPEC is which is greater than the theoretical value of , but is significant at 1%. The coefficient on GRAV is positive, but far smaller than unity implied by proposition 1. However, it still is significant at 1%. In regression (2), we replace GRAV with variables frequently used in estimating gravity equations. In regressing gravity equations, these variables are inserted as proxies for transportation costs and other trade barriers. It is well known that they are highly significant in explaining variations of GRAV across trading partners. For example, in a typical analysis, GRAV decreases as distance between trading partners increases, and increases when trading partners share a common language or a common border. It has also been noted by many researchers that one of these variables, distance between trading partners, has a significant negative effect on intra-industry trade. This observation is particularly important to us because the negative correlation between IIT and SPEC might have been driven by the common factor of distance, or some other variables. A shorter distance between trading partners may increase the intensity of intra-industry and decrease the difference in industry structure at the same time, because of more similar climate conditions or consumer tastes. So we control for these effects by adding gravity variables in the regression equation. Regression 2 reports the results. As expected, intra-industry trade decreases with distance and increases with a common language. However, the coefficient on SPEC still is significantly negative, though its absolute value has shrunk a little. However, there may be omitted variables other than these gravity variables whose variations across trading partners cause a spurious correlation between IIT and SPEC. To eliminate their 20 influence and extract a time-series relationship between IIT and SPEC, we estimate a fixed effects model in regression (3). As we can see, SPEC still has a significant negative effect on IIT. However, the coefficient on GRAV has a wrong sign, and is significant at 5% at that. This puzzling relationship between IIT and GRAV is observed in all fixed effects estimations below. Having found that the predictions of proposition 1, especially the negative correlation between intra-industry and specialization, are born out by production and trade data, we now turn to our main interests: propositions 2 and 3. In table 4, we put PRODIF and KDIF instead of SPEC, and let them compete in the same regression. Regression (4) reports an OLS estimation results. The estimation confirms both propositions 2 and 3. The estimation coefficient on PRODIF is negative and significant at 1%, as that on KDIF is. In regression (5), as in regression (2), we replace GRAV with gravity variables. As before, intra-industry trade decreases with distance, and increases with a common language. It is interesting to note that a common border enhances intraindustry trade, but having an island economy as a trading partner diminishes intra-industry trade. The coefficients on PRODIF and KDIF still are negative and significant at 1%. In regression (6), we estimate a fixed effects model. Here, the coefficient on PRODIF is not significant any more, and the coefficient on KDIF becomes zero. Measurement errors in calculating productivity and capital per worker might be the source of weak correlations. The lack of within variations combined with a small number of observations (less than 3 per country pair) might be another. To probe the matter further, in Table 5, we run fixed effects regressions in two subsamples: North-North trade and North-South trade. (The South-South sample is dropped because of a small number of observations.) In regression (7), we report estimation results for North-North trade (trade between high or upper middle income countries). The negative coefficient on 21 Table 5: Determinants of Intra-industry Trade in North-North and North-South Trade log IIT (7) (8) (9) Fixed Effects Fixed Effects Fixed Effects North-North North-South High Income log KDIF log GRAV R2 Obs. Sample log PRODIF Year dummies are included in all regressions. Language(= 0, 1), Border= 0, 1), Island(= 0, 1, 2), Landlock(= 0, 1, 2) , Colony(=0, 1) are dummy variables. The numbers in the parentheses are tratios. The R2 of fixed effects regressions are from within regressions. T denotes the average number of observations per country pair. * : significant at 1%. ** : significant at 5%. PRODIF now becomes significant at 5%. The coefficient on KDIF still is zero and insignificant. We have similar results when the sample is further restricted to country pairs with high income, as regression (9) reports. Regression (8) is for South-South trade. Now the coefficient for PRODIF becomes insignificant, while the coefficient on KDIF is negative and significant at 1 %. To summarize our fixed effects estimations, the difference in the industry structure of labor productivity has a significant negative effect on intra-industry trade in North-North trade. 22 However, the effect becomes insignificant in North-South trade, making the overall relationship between two variables unclear. The opposite results hold for the difference in capital-labor ratio. The difference in capital-labor ratio seems to have no effect on intra-industry trade in NorthNorth trade, while it shows a significant negative effect on intra-industry trade in North-South trade. Again, these discordant results make the overall relationship between intra-industry trade and the difference in capital-labor ratio unclear. V. Conclusion The model developed in this paper is highly stylized. The world is composed of two countries and they compete in a Cournot duopoly in every industry. However, we intend the simple model merely as an economical way of stating our basic intuition. If the mutual penetration of markets is a significant source of intra-industry trade, the industry structure of productivity would affect the degree of specialization, which would, in turn, influence the intensity of intra-industry trade. The intuition has a theoretical base. The share of intra-industry trade in bilateral trade volume decreases when the degree of specialization between trading partners increases. The well-known prediction of the monopolistic competition model, that the share of intra-industry trade is inversely related to the difference in capital-labor ratio, is one special case. As the difference in capital-labor ratio increases, it increases the degree of specialization, which is nothing but the Rybczynski effect. This increase in specialization reduces intra-industry trade. However, capitallabor ratio is just one of the factors that determine the industry structure of an economy. The industry distribution of productivity would be another, and it would affect intra-industry trade through its effect on specialization. 23 We confirm these conjectures in production and trade data. Both the difference in the industry distribution of productivity and the difference in capital-ratio are highly significant in explaining variations of the Grubel-Lloyd index across country pairs. However, their explanatory power over variations within a country pair is limited. In a future study, we should probe further as to what drives these contrasting results. 24 References Bernhofen, D. M., (1998), “Intra-industry Trade and Strategic Interaction: Theory and Evidence,” Journal of International Economics 45: 77-96. Brander, James A. (1981), “Intra-industry Trade in Identical Commodities,” Journal of International Economics 11: 1-14 Brander, James A. and Paul R. Krugman (1983), “A ‘Reciprocal Dumping’ Model of International Trade,” Journal of International Economics 15: 313-321. Davis, Donald R. (1995), “Intra-industry Trade: A Heckscher-Ohlin-Ricardo approach,” Journal of International Economics 39: 201-226. Dixit, A. K. and V. Norman (1980), Theory of International Trade (Cambridge University Press). Dornbusch, R., S. Fischer and P. Samuelson (1977), “Comparative Advantage, Trade and Payments in a Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Goods,” American Economic Review 67: 823-839. Greenaway, David and Chris Milner (1986), The Economics of Intra-Industry Trade, Oxford: Blackwell Grubel, H. G., and P. J. Lloyd (1975), Intra-industry Trade: The Theory and Measurement of International Trade in Differentiated Products (New York, Wiley). Haveman, Jon, International Trade Data, http://www.macalester.edu/research/economics/PAGE/ HAVEMAN/Trade.Resources/TradeData.html. Helpman, Elhanan (1987), “Imperfect Competition and International Trade: Evidence from fourteen Industrial Countries,” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies 1: 6281. 25 _________________(1999), “The Structure of Foreign Trade,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 13: 121-144. Helpman, Elhanan and Paul. R. Krugman (1985), Ch. 8 in Market Structure and Foreign Trade (MIT Press, Cambridge, MA). Heston, Alan, Robert Summers and Bettina Aten (2002), Penn World Table Version 6.2, Center for International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania (CICUP). Hummels, D. and J. Levinsohn (1995), “Monopolistic Competition and International Trade: Reconsidering the Evidence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, August: 799-836. Krugman, P. R. (1979), “Increasing Returns, Monopolistic Competition, and the Pattern of Trade,” Journal of International Economics 9: 469-479. Lancaster, K. J. (1979), Variety, Equity and Efficiency (Columbia University Press, New York). Loertscher, R. and F. Wolter (1980), “Determinants of Intra-industry Trade: Among Countries and Across Industries,” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 8: 280-93. Nicita, Alessandro and Marcelo Olarreaga (2006), Trade and Production 1976-2004, www.worldbank.org/trade. Rose, Andrew K. (2004), "Do We Really Know That the WTO Increases Trade?" American Economic Review 94: 98-114. 26 APPENDIX [Proof for Proposition 1] By the definition of ik , the following equation holds. X iik X ijk ik Yi . (A1) Under the assumptions made, the price of each good is identical in two countries and the expenditure share of good k is equal to k in both countries. Thus X iik X kji k Yi . (A2) X ijk X kji (ik k )Yi , (A3) ik Yi jk Y j k YW . (A4) From these two equations, A(4) implies that ik k (ik jk ) Yj . YW (A5) Plugging this equation into equation (A3), X ijk X kji ( ik jk ) YiY j Yw . (A6) Thus X ijk X kji ik jk k k or 27 YiY j Yw , X ijk X kji k 2 X ij 1 ik jk 2 . k YiY j X ij / Yw The left-hand side of the equation is the proportion of inter-industry trade in total trade, 1 GL. The right-hand side is equal to SPEC/GRAV. Thus 1 GRAV . 1 GL SPEC ■ [Proof for Proposition 3] Let PX and PZ be the prices of two goods X and Z in a trade equilibrium. Let W and R denote the wage and the rental rate of capital. Using X i and Zi to denote the production of X and Y in country i, we can express the full employment condition as a XK a XL aZK X i K i . aZL Z i Li (A7) akv denotes the input of factor v used to produce one unit of good k. With factor price equalization, two countries have identical a’s. Solving for the outputs of two good, Xi 1 (aZL K i azK Li ) , (A8) where aZK aZL aXLaZK . Using this equation, iX PX X i P a k azK X ZL i . RK i WLi Rk i W (A9) In a similar way, we can calculate jX and derive the following equation. 28 iX jX PX aZL ki azK aZL k j azK ( ). Rk i W Rk j W (A10) PX [( aZL ki azK )( Rk j W ) (aZL k j a zK )( Rk i W )] yi y j PX (ki k j )( aZK R aZLW ) yi y j PX PZ ki k j . yi y j The last equality used the zero profit condition that PZ aZK R aZLW . Finally, since iZ 1 iX , SPEC = P P ki k j 1 ik kj iX jX X Z 2 k X ,Z yi y j ■ 29 (A11)