
2.5: Conjectures That Lead to Theorems
... Which of the following statements demonstrates deductive reasoning? A. All crows are black, and all crows are birds; therefore, all birds are black. B. All dolphins have fins, and all fish have fins; therefore, all dolphins are fish. C. Edward is a human being, and all human beings are mortal; ther ...
... Which of the following statements demonstrates deductive reasoning? A. All crows are black, and all crows are birds; therefore, all birds are black. B. All dolphins have fins, and all fish have fins; therefore, all dolphins are fish. C. Edward is a human being, and all human beings are mortal; ther ...
AND PETER MICHAEL DOUBILET B.Sc., McGill University 1969)
... proof of the Fundamental Theorem of symmetric functions, and to study a new type of transitivity of group actions which is a generalization of both k-transitivity and k-set-transitivity. In Part II we take an entirely new approach to symmetric functions via distribution and occupancy, exploiting thi ...
... proof of the Fundamental Theorem of symmetric functions, and to study a new type of transitivity of group actions which is a generalization of both k-transitivity and k-set-transitivity. In Part II we take an entirely new approach to symmetric functions via distribution and occupancy, exploiting thi ...
Notes from the Prague Set Theory seminar
... 4.21 Definition. A submeasure µ on a Boolean algebra B is exhaustive if for each countable antichain {an : n < ω} ⊆ B and each ε > 0 the set {n : µ(an ) > ε} is finite. 4.22 Theorem (Kalton,Roberts). Let µ be a uniformly exhaustive submeasure on a Boolean algebra. Then there is a finitely additive m ...
... 4.21 Definition. A submeasure µ on a Boolean algebra B is exhaustive if for each countable antichain {an : n < ω} ⊆ B and each ε > 0 the set {n : µ(an ) > ε} is finite. 4.22 Theorem (Kalton,Roberts). Let µ be a uniformly exhaustive submeasure on a Boolean algebra. Then there is a finitely additive m ...
Brouwer fixed-point theorem

Brouwer's fixed-point theorem is a fixed-point theorem in topology, named after Luitzen Brouwer. It states that for any continuous function f mapping a compact convex set into itself there is a point x0 such that f(x0) = x0. The simplest forms of Brouwer's theorem are for continuous functions f from a closed interval I in the real numbers to itself or from a closed disk D to itself. A more general form than the latter is for continuous functions from a convex compact subset K of Euclidean space to itself.Among hundreds of fixed-point theorems, Brouwer's is particularly well known, due in part to its use across numerous fields of mathematics.In its original field, this result is one of the key theorems characterizing the topology of Euclidean spaces, along with the Jordan curve theorem, the hairy ball theorem and the Borsuk–Ulam theorem.This gives it a place among the fundamental theorems of topology. The theorem is also used for proving deep results about differential equations and is covered in most introductory courses on differential geometry.It appears in unlikely fields such as game theory. In economics, Brouwer's fixed-point theorem and its extension, the Kakutani fixed-point theorem, play a central role in the proof of existence of general equilibrium in market economies as developed in the 1950s by economics Nobel prize winners Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu.The theorem was first studied in view of work on differential equations by the French mathematicians around Poincaré and Picard.Proving results such as the Poincaré–Bendixson theorem requires the use of topological methods.This work at the end of the 19th century opened into several successive versions of the theorem. The general case was first proved in 1910 by Jacques Hadamard and by Luitzen Egbertus Jan Brouwer.