• Study Resource
  • Explore
    • Arts & Humanities
    • Business
    • Engineering & Technology
    • Foreign Language
    • History
    • Math
    • Science
    • Social Science

    Top subcategories

    • Advanced Math
    • Algebra
    • Basic Math
    • Calculus
    • Geometry
    • Linear Algebra
    • Pre-Algebra
    • Pre-Calculus
    • Statistics And Probability
    • Trigonometry
    • other →

    Top subcategories

    • Astronomy
    • Astrophysics
    • Biology
    • Chemistry
    • Earth Science
    • Environmental Science
    • Health Science
    • Physics
    • other →

    Top subcategories

    • Anthropology
    • Law
    • Political Science
    • Psychology
    • Sociology
    • other →

    Top subcategories

    • Accounting
    • Economics
    • Finance
    • Management
    • other →

    Top subcategories

    • Aerospace Engineering
    • Bioengineering
    • Chemical Engineering
    • Civil Engineering
    • Computer Science
    • Electrical Engineering
    • Industrial Engineering
    • Mechanical Engineering
    • Web Design
    • other →

    Top subcategories

    • Architecture
    • Communications
    • English
    • Gender Studies
    • Music
    • Performing Arts
    • Philosophy
    • Religious Studies
    • Writing
    • other →

    Top subcategories

    • Ancient History
    • European History
    • US History
    • World History
    • other →

    Top subcategories

    • Croatian
    • Czech
    • Finnish
    • Greek
    • Hindi
    • Japanese
    • Korean
    • Persian
    • Swedish
    • Turkish
    • other →
 
Profile Documents Logout
Upload
KetlandSecondOrderLogic
KetlandSecondOrderLogic

Covering spaces
Covering spaces

Chapter 5: Congruent Triangles
Chapter 5: Congruent Triangles

Free full version - topo.auburn.edu
Free full version - topo.auburn.edu

2.6.2 Saccheri Quadrilaterals
2.6.2 Saccheri Quadrilaterals

... Euclid's Fifth Postulate. That, if a straight line falling on two straight lines make the interior angles on the same side less than two right angles, the two straight lines, if produced indefinitely, meet on that side on which are the angles less than the two right angles. Girolamo Saccheri (1667–1 ...
Section 3-2 pages 94-100
Section 3-2 pages 94-100

Normality on Topological Groups - Matemáticas UCM
Normality on Topological Groups - Matemáticas UCM

EBERLEIN–ŠMULYAN THEOREM FOR ABELIAN TOPOLOGICAL
EBERLEIN–ŠMULYAN THEOREM FOR ABELIAN TOPOLOGICAL

... fundamental tool, and the optimal situation is when it can be used in its sequential version. Unfortunately this is not always the case, and there is a strong need to look for classes of topological spaces where compactness is equivalent to sequential or countable compactness. It was known from the ...
Separation Axioms In Topological Spaces
Separation Axioms In Topological Spaces

Congruent Polygons
Congruent Polygons

Axioms of Incidence Geometry Incidence Axiom 1. There exist at
Axioms of Incidence Geometry Incidence Axiom 1. There exist at

... Lemma 3.3 (Ruler Sliding Lemma). Suppose ` is a line and f W ` ! R is a coordinate function for `. Given a real number c, define a new function f1 W ` ! R by f1 .X/ D f .X/ C c for all X 2 `. Then f1 is also a coordinate function for `. Lemma 3.4 (Ruler Flipping Lemma). Suppose ` is a line and f W ` ...
11.
11.

A Note on Local Compactness
A Note on Local Compactness

Ivan Lončar
Ivan Lončar

Topology Proceedings 34 (2009) pp. 307-
Topology Proceedings 34 (2009) pp. 307-

More about partitions
More about partitions

... Partitions: odd parts and distinct parts ...
Distinct distances between points and lines
Distinct distances between points and lines

Locally Convex Vector Spaces III: The Metric Point of View
Locally Convex Vector Spaces III: The Metric Point of View

14.1 Covering and Packing - Department of Statistics, Yale
14.1 Covering and Packing - Department of Statistics, Yale

... We next prove part (a) by contradiction. Suppose there exists a 2-packing {θ1 , ..., θM } and an -covering {x1 , ..., xN } such that M ≥ N + 1. Then by pigeonhole, we must have θi and θj belonging to the same -ball B(xk , ) for some i = 6 j and k. This means that the distance between θi and θj c ...
de Rham cohomology
de Rham cohomology

TOPOLOGY IN A CATEGORY: COMPACTNESS 0 – Introduction
TOPOLOGY IN A CATEGORY: COMPACTNESS 0 – Introduction

BASIC ALGEBRAIC TOPOLOGY: THE FUNDAMENTAL GROUP OF
BASIC ALGEBRAIC TOPOLOGY: THE FUNDAMENTAL GROUP OF

07b seminorms versus locally convexity
07b seminorms versus locally convexity

A class of angelic sequential non-Fréchet–Urysohn topological groups
A class of angelic sequential non-Fréchet–Urysohn topological groups

SUFFICIENT CONDITIONS FOR A GROUP TO BE A
SUFFICIENT CONDITIONS FOR A GROUP TO BE A

... A DIRECT SUM OF CYCLIC GROUPS1 PAUL H I L L ...
< 1 ... 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 ... 211 >

Brouwer fixed-point theorem



Brouwer's fixed-point theorem is a fixed-point theorem in topology, named after Luitzen Brouwer. It states that for any continuous function f mapping a compact convex set into itself there is a point x0 such that f(x0) = x0. The simplest forms of Brouwer's theorem are for continuous functions f from a closed interval I in the real numbers to itself or from a closed disk D to itself. A more general form than the latter is for continuous functions from a convex compact subset K of Euclidean space to itself.Among hundreds of fixed-point theorems, Brouwer's is particularly well known, due in part to its use across numerous fields of mathematics.In its original field, this result is one of the key theorems characterizing the topology of Euclidean spaces, along with the Jordan curve theorem, the hairy ball theorem and the Borsuk–Ulam theorem.This gives it a place among the fundamental theorems of topology. The theorem is also used for proving deep results about differential equations and is covered in most introductory courses on differential geometry.It appears in unlikely fields such as game theory. In economics, Brouwer's fixed-point theorem and its extension, the Kakutani fixed-point theorem, play a central role in the proof of existence of general equilibrium in market economies as developed in the 1950s by economics Nobel prize winners Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu.The theorem was first studied in view of work on differential equations by the French mathematicians around Poincaré and Picard.Proving results such as the Poincaré–Bendixson theorem requires the use of topological methods.This work at the end of the 19th century opened into several successive versions of the theorem. The general case was first proved in 1910 by Jacques Hadamard and by Luitzen Egbertus Jan Brouwer.
  • studyres.com © 2025
  • DMCA
  • Privacy
  • Terms
  • Report