
Chapter 2 Limits and continuity
... Example 2.28 (Limits of rational functions at infinity). Given a rational function, one can easily compute its limit as x → +∞. The main step is to divide both the numerator and the denominator by the highest power of x that appears downstairs. For instance, one has ...
... Example 2.28 (Limits of rational functions at infinity). Given a rational function, one can easily compute its limit as x → +∞. The main step is to divide both the numerator and the denominator by the highest power of x that appears downstairs. For instance, one has ...
on geometry of convex ideal polyhedra in hyperbolic
... To prove Condition 3, we will need a few subsidiary results. DEFINITION.Let y be a closed polygonal curve in H3, with vertices pt, p2, . . . , pk, pk = pl. Then define the turning z,(y) of y at the vertex pi be the exterior angle of the triangle Si = pi-Ipipi+I at pi, and dejine the total turning t( ...
... To prove Condition 3, we will need a few subsidiary results. DEFINITION.Let y be a closed polygonal curve in H3, with vertices pt, p2, . . . , pk, pk = pl. Then define the turning z,(y) of y at the vertex pi be the exterior angle of the triangle Si = pi-Ipipi+I at pi, and dejine the total turning t( ...
5-6 Inequalities in One Triangle
... Hinge Theorem: If two sides of one triangle are congruent to two sides of another triangle, and the included angles are not congruent, then the longer third side is opposite the larger included angle. ...
... Hinge Theorem: If two sides of one triangle are congruent to two sides of another triangle, and the included angles are not congruent, then the longer third side is opposite the larger included angle. ...
Brouwer fixed-point theorem

Brouwer's fixed-point theorem is a fixed-point theorem in topology, named after Luitzen Brouwer. It states that for any continuous function f mapping a compact convex set into itself there is a point x0 such that f(x0) = x0. The simplest forms of Brouwer's theorem are for continuous functions f from a closed interval I in the real numbers to itself or from a closed disk D to itself. A more general form than the latter is for continuous functions from a convex compact subset K of Euclidean space to itself.Among hundreds of fixed-point theorems, Brouwer's is particularly well known, due in part to its use across numerous fields of mathematics.In its original field, this result is one of the key theorems characterizing the topology of Euclidean spaces, along with the Jordan curve theorem, the hairy ball theorem and the Borsuk–Ulam theorem.This gives it a place among the fundamental theorems of topology. The theorem is also used for proving deep results about differential equations and is covered in most introductory courses on differential geometry.It appears in unlikely fields such as game theory. In economics, Brouwer's fixed-point theorem and its extension, the Kakutani fixed-point theorem, play a central role in the proof of existence of general equilibrium in market economies as developed in the 1950s by economics Nobel prize winners Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu.The theorem was first studied in view of work on differential equations by the French mathematicians around Poincaré and Picard.Proving results such as the Poincaré–Bendixson theorem requires the use of topological methods.This work at the end of the 19th century opened into several successive versions of the theorem. The general case was first proved in 1910 by Jacques Hadamard and by Luitzen Egbertus Jan Brouwer.