* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download DETERMINANTS OF HIGH INFLATION IN AN LDC:
Economic growth wikipedia , lookup
Nominal rigidity wikipedia , lookup
Modern Monetary Theory wikipedia , lookup
Edmund Phelps wikipedia , lookup
Fear of floating wikipedia , lookup
Full employment wikipedia , lookup
Real bills doctrine wikipedia , lookup
Quantitative easing wikipedia , lookup
Business cycle wikipedia , lookup
Post–World War II economic expansion wikipedia , lookup
Interest rate wikipedia , lookup
Monetary policy wikipedia , lookup
Money supply wikipedia , lookup
Phillips curve wikipedia , lookup
DETERMINANTS OF INFLATION AND ITS INSTABILITY A Case Study of a Less Developed Economy 1970-1994 by A-M.M. Abdel-Rahman* * Department of Economics, King Saud University, P.O.Box 2459; Riyadh 11451, Saudi Arabia. 2 Abstract . During the past three decades inflation in Sudan accelerated and was highly variable. Various factors contributed to this acceleration and variability. Predominant among these is the monetary financing of a persistent budget deficit in the country. Other real, expectational and structural factors also contributed to the incidence of this high inflation episode witnessed in the country. This paper investigates the sources of instability in both the mean and variance of inflation. Account of the shifting means is undertaken by shift dummies whereas account of the variable variance is undertaken via Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity(ARCH) and Error Correction(EC) estimation mechanisms. The analysis exploits recent results on cointegration given the obvious nonstationarity of the data within the high inflation context. In due process, we also trace the nominal, real, structural and expectational determinants of the Sudan inflation. 3 DETERMINANTS OF INFLATION AND ITS INSTABILITY A Case Study of a Less Developed Economy A-M. M. Abdel-Rahman Introduction: During the past three decades, the inflation rate accelerated considerably in Sudan. Conventionally, theoretical treatments of the determinants of inflation usually focus on the relevant monetary and real factors. To these, expectational effects are sometimes added. These are especially powerful during high inflation episodes and may even swamp other effects if the inflationary regime shifts into a hyper gear. Moreover, in Less Developed Countries(LDCs) structural factors may also add further impetus to the process. This paper attempts to study the inflation process in Sudan through the period 1970:1 to 1994:2. Section 1 of the paper discusses the variables, the data and the models. Section 2 starts a more intensive study on the problem by conducting firstly unit root tests on the individual series to determine the stationarity characteristics of the individual series. Section 3 then undertakes the analysis which begins with some preliminary estimates on some simplified conventional inflation functions. Instability is then explored and incorporated in the used functional formulations. This is done firstly via the inclusion of shift and interactive slope dummies to account for possible structural breaks in the means of the process within the framework of a ‘general to specific’ methodology and second via the allowance for Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity(ARCH) effects to model simultaneously the observed instability in the means and conditional variances. Section 4 then concentrates on short-run and long-run considerations using Error Correction(EC) and cointegration methodologies. A final section then concludes the study. 4 1. The Variables, Data and the Models: To gauge the issues we used data on money, prices and output. The consumer price index(CPI) was used for prices(P), M1 was used for money(M) and real Gross Domestic Product(GDP) was used for output(Y). The variables were initially measured in logarithmic form to obtain log prices(p), log money(m) and log output(y) respectively over the period 1970:1-1994:2. Annualized rates of growth were then computed to ) and output growth( y ). Annual data provide for the rate of inflation( p ), money growth( m on real output were obtained from the World Book and interpolated via a Lagrangian procedure to obtain quarterly figures1. Using data on the Consumer Price Index(CPI)2 we computed the inflation rate on an annual quarter-to-quarter basis. Data were obtained from the International Monetary Fund- International Financial Statistics(IMF-IFS). Inspection of the inflation data in the Sudan over the sample period reveals an obvious upward trend in the inflation rate as witnessed by Fig(1) below. There is also a noticeable drift in the rate and an increase in its volatility especially toward the latter parts of the sample period. 100 80 60 40 20 0 -20 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 Fig(1): Annualized inflation in Sudan; 1970:1 1994:2 1 Quarterly data are specially useful in the context of LDC inflations, since as noted by Ryan and Milne(1994) for example, often the structure of the economy in developing countries is characterized by price controls which are frequently adjusted by the government and the impact of depreciations, changes in commodity prices(Oil) can have important effects on the quarterly - as contrasted to the annual - pattern of inflation. 2 A shortcoming of the use of the CPI is that it doesnot show the extent of price controlled items in the index; see for example Domowitz and Elbadawi(1987). 5 To further examine the trend and variance instability of inflation we computed the bi-decadeal means, medians and standard deviations of the inflation rate over the sample period. These are shown in Table(1) below: Table(1) Mean Inflations and Variability 1971:1-1990:3 period Mean Median Standard Deviation 1971:1-1974:4 12.220 13.357 10.263 1975:1-1979:4 16.289 15.878 9.643 1980:1-1984:4 24.713 24.764 7.036 1985:1-1989:4 35.893 37.240 16.532 1990:1-1994:2 70.939 73.877 13.777 Again the obvious trend is noticeable from the bi-decadeal means and medians and the variability is noticeable from the fluctuating standard deviations. 2. Stationarity: In this section we investigate the time series properties of the variables by conducting unit root tests to gauge the orders of integration of the used variables and to resolve the issue of trend stationarity versus difference stationarity characterizations. Augmented Dickey-Fuller(DF) and Phillips-Perron(PP) tests were used on the various variables to test for the order of integration. Results for data in rates form are: Table(2) Stationarity of rates Test p m y ADF -1.999 -3.408 -2.642 PP -2.917 -2.751 -2.935 6 All variables are nonstationary, hence we proceeded to check for results in difference form. Table(3) shows results for the respective variables in log-difference growth rate form: Table(3) Stationarity of differences in rates Test p m y ADF -5.061 -6.218 -3.652 PP -8.955 -13.779 -5.421 The results show that at the 5% level all the rate series are I(1). Thus we arrive at the conclusion that the rates variables are nonstationary and I(1) whereas their firstdifference form are stationary and I(0). This reveals that the estimation should be undertaken with first differences not growth rates 3. Conventional Estimates, Stability and Structural Breaks: In this section we estimate the determinants of inflation and its variability. The model of inflation used for the analysis assumes variants of the Autoregressive Distributed Lag(ADL) form: t (L)y t (L)z t t (L)p t (L)m where (L), (L), (L) and (L) are appropriate lag polynomials, z is a vector of some exogenous determinants which may include structural variables besides the monetary, output and expectational explanatories. This is a more general formulation than that used, for example, by Bairam(1988,1990), Darrat(1985,1986) ... inter alia. The equation provides a suitable testing cite to discriminate between the Monetarists, Keynesian and Structuralists theories of inflation. As far as the monetary factor is concerned, in Keynesian models output responds to money variations whilst in monetarists interpretations the response to money is only transitory. The rational expectations(RE) school holds that only unanticipated changes in money can affect output and for the real 7 business cycle(RBC) theory money has no impact whatsoever on output. Most theories, however, agree that changes in the money supply affect the price level. To accept the Monetarist interpretation, the s, which measure the response of inflation to the state of the economy should be insignificant while the s which measure of the response of inflation to the monetary stimuli should be positive and significant. For the Keynesian interpretation to be valid, the reverse should hold true. The presence of y may also reflect supply side effects whereby the increased supply of goods serves to reduce inflationary pressures and in that case the s would be significant and negative. The s would be highly significant in the case of high and hyperinflationary situations where there is usually a strong inflationary inertia. The lagged dependent variables will also measure the effect of expectations in such an environment and in a simple adaptive formulation the s may measure the speed of inflation. For structuralists interpretations3 we expect the s to be significant. We also expect them to be positive for the case of adverse shocks and negative for the case of favorable shocks. We begin with a simple inflation function to investigate the role of the key determinants and to determine the sources of instability. Annualized nominal money ) and output growth( y ) were used in some preliminary regressions for the growth( m inflation rate( p ). A first regression was obtained as: t p t 2.668 0.730 y t 0.998 m ( 0.698 ) R 2 0.559 R 2 LM (1) 54.691 ( 0.000) ARCH (1) 23.455 ( 0.000) Chow F 8.879 79:4 ( 0.000) 3 0.549 ( 3.329 ) ( 9 .379 ) 15.960 LM (1 4 ) 56.545 ( 0.000) ARCH (1 4 ) 23.267 ( 0.000) Chow F 5.506 92:1 ( 0.001) F 57.675 ( 0.000) d 0.500 RESET F 1.249 ( 0.267) HESC 21.466 ( 0.001) AIC 5.572 SC 5.653 See for example, Kirkpatrick and Nixson(1976) and Johnson(1986). Structural factors, e.g. the effect of a major devaluation as was witnessed in 1979, 1982 and 1984 immediately increases the domestic prices of imports. Most Sudanese imports are intermediate and capital goods hence the effect was an increase in the final cost of home manufactured goods and increased prices plus an ensuing wage-price spiral. 8 where figures in parentheses beneath the estimated coefficients are the t-ratios. In addition to the conventional test statistics, we also report on various LM tests on serial correlation which are chi-square distributed with their p-values in parentheses. HESC is Breusch-Pagan LM test on heteroscedasticity. ARCH is Engle’s test for autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity, Chow F is Chow breakpoint test at the subscripted time period where the period 1979:4 for example heralded the onset of a major stabilization and structural adjustment program, AIC is Akaike Information Criterion and SC is Schwartz Criterion. R 2 and d were low which could be an indication of a possible misspecified relationship. There was ample evidence on serial correlation and ARCH effects. Apart from that, we could initially infer the expected results that nominal money contributed to positive inflations in an almost one-to-one basis whereas real output served to depress inflation in an indication of possible supply factors at work i.e. inflation is related in a negative way to growth. Adding inflationary inertia to the picture resulted in the following estimated equation: t 0.904 p t 1 p t 2.773 0.256 y t 0.055 m (1.490 ) R 2 0.898 R 2 LM (1) 0.838 ( 0.360) ARCH (1) 0.144 ( 0.703) Chow F 1.345 79:4 ( 0.260) ( 2 .358 ) 0.895 ( 0.734 ) 7.656 LM (1 4 ) 16.765 ( 0.002 ) ARCH (1 4 ) 3179 . ( 0.528) Chow F 2.579 92:1 ( 0.043) (17 .491) F 262.581 ( 0.000) d 1828 . RESET F 1.261 ( 0.264 ) HESC 15.895 ( 0.069 ) AIC 4.113 SC 4.222 The introduction of the lagged dependent variable which accounts for the inflationary momentum and perhaps the expectations feeding it swamped the effects of the other variables both theoretically and economically yielding higher R 2 and d statistics. It also removed the ARCH effect present in the static formulation. Comparing the two formulations, we note that the first simple equation gives importance to monetary influences whereas the second reflects the predominance of inflationary momentum and expectations. The sample period was a period of high and 9 persistent government budget deficits and an increasing tendency to finance these deficits has an obvious by resort to money creation - seigniorage. The rate of money growth m relationship with seigniorage and the evidence is thus consistent with the hypothesis that deficits - seigniorage - raises money and inflation and lowers rates of economic growth. To explain the significant ARCH effect we note that erratic exchange rates policies and monetary accommodation of exogenous shocks added considerable noise to the economic environment over the period by increasing the variance of money growth shocks. This in turn increased the variance of inflation - an ARCH effect - which generally has a significant negative relationship with economic growth. 3.1. Instability in Mean Inflation: Inspection of the stability or otherwise of inflation was done using the Cumulative Sum(CUSUM) of the residuals which revealed that a number of significant structural breaks may have occurred in the periods 1975:3, 1979:4, 1982:4, 1985:2, 1988:3 and 1992:1. The Chow breakpoint tests at these time periods were respectively 2.451, 6.245, 9.596, 4.889, 16.528 and 5.506 which were significant respectively at levels 0.070, 0.001, 0.000, 0.006, 0.000 and 0.002. In particular, the break in 1975:3 may have been due to the overheating of the economy because of massive capital inflows from the oil-rich Arab countries in the form of foreign direct investment and assistance. This same period coincided with the highest growth rate registered in the sample period. The break in 1979:4 could be attributed to the onset of the effects of the massive readjustment program adopted in the third quarter of 1979 which included sweeping trade and exchange rate liberalization and devaluation measures; that of 1985:2 could be traced to the intensification of the civil war in the southern part of the country and the collapse of the then ruling military regime. This precipitated a decline in the inflation rate probably due to expectational effects. The break in 1988:3 was due to wide scarcities because of massive famines and floodings throughout the country which occurred early August 1988. The break in 1992:1 signaled the start of another broad and wide-ranging economic liberalization program 10 To account for these breaks we accordingly defined a set of dummy variables to cater for shifts in means and slopes over these time periods thus representing the various structural factors which affected the Sudanese economy during the period of study and reestimated the basic regression in rates form. A reduction process similar in spirit to that of the “general to specific methodology” then ensued whereby shift dummies for 1979:4, 1982:4 and 1988:3 proved insignificant and were hence subsequently discarded. Results were: t 0.676 D82 m t p t 10.045 55.459 D85 0.529 y t 1040 . D85 y t 0.356 m ( 3.565) ( 4 .170 ) ( 6.730 ) ( 3.123) ( 3.354 ) ( 4 .599 ) t 1023 t 0.268 D92 m t 2.144 D85 m . D88 m ( 7 .272 ) R 2 0.893 (11.109 ) R 2 0.883 8.124 ( 3.246 ) F 88.933 d 0.882 ( 0.000 ) LM (1) 30.565 ( 0.000) ARCH (1 4 ) 22.536 ( 0.000) LM (1 4 ) 36.978 ( 0.000) HESC 53164 . ( 0.000) ARCH (1) 17.127 ( 0.000) AIC 4.280 SC 4.524 All coefficients were significant and showed the required responses except that for which was in the opposite direction to what was expected. the interactive D85 and m The overthrowal of the then ruling military regime resulted in a change of expectations and the subsequent transitory and civilian regimes showed a higher level of monetary discipline. The effect of that was a declining inflation rate. The other results again show a similar pattern to those previously obtained. Nominal money, output and the rest of the structural factors were significant determinants of inflation in the country over the period in reflection of the fact that both demand side and supply side factors were at work in the economy. However, a remaining deficiency of the equation is the low d and LM statistics plus the significant ARCH and HESC effects which could be an indication of still present misspecification. These are generally thought to be in non-regression directions as evidenced by the various statistics. 11 3.2. Variance instability and ARCH effects: Here we proceed to provide empirical measures of the uncertainty of inflation. This is done by investigating the variance of inflation through the employment of ARCH effects. Since the ARCH was significant in the above formulation that would be taken as an indication of an increase in inflation uncertainty. Hence we proceed next to incorporate the instability in the variance and the resulting inflation uncertainty, i.e. the ARCH effect into the estimation process and then to treat any possibly remaining nonstationarities via application of cointegration methodology. We analyze the annualized rate of inflation between 1970:1-1994:2 within an ARCH context. A first trial with an ARCH(1) process using a BHHH - outer product of the gradient procedure - resulted in the following results: t p t 10138 . 0.534 y t 0.348 m ( 4 .185) ( 4 .419 ) ( 4 .416 ) 27.034 1048 . 2t 1 2 t ( 2 .200 ) LM (1) 0.011 ( 0.915) ( 2 .823) LM (1 4) 0.783 ( 0.941) Q 36 29.239 The LM tests on autocorrelation now show the absence of the problem and the coefficient of the lagged squared errors being significant at level 0.006 in the ARCH process. Again a similar pattern to that obtained in the original static formulation was obtained. The output effect remained negative and significant whereas the nominal money effect was positive and significant but with a much reduced impact of 0.348 magnitude. To combine the mean and variance effects we reintroduced the shift dummies into the formulation where an ARCH model was also estimated for the dummy variables model and the results obtained were: 12 t 0.678 D82 m t p t 11367 . 54.130 D85 0.477 y t 2.070 D85 y t 0.288 m ( 5.755) ( 4 .941) ( 9 .402 ) ( 8.455) ( 3.922 ) ( 4 .642 ) t 1063 t 0.234 D92 m t 2.102 D85 m . D88 m ( 8.655) (14 .909 ) ( 3.345) 2t 18.519 0.767 2t 1 ( 2 .633) R 2 0.876 R 2 0.862 ( 2 .790 ) 8.846 F 58.871 d 0.852 ( 0.000 ) ARCH (1) 0.328 ( 0.567 ) Despite the overall significance of the equation and ARCH effect, there was still evidence of an autocorrelation problem as judged by the still low d statistics. To tackle that problem we proceeded to estimate the model in EC form in the next section. 4. Error Corrections: Since the variables are stationary, we proceeded to estimate a dynamic short-run ECM. The estimated ECM assumed the form: 0118 p 0.634 0.836 y 0135 . m . e 4 ( 0.802 ) R 2 0.115 SC 4.182 ( 3.539 ) 7.490 LM (1) 0.233 ( 0.629 ) ARCH (1 4) 0.948 ( 0.918) (1.504 ) F 4.838 ( 0.004 ) ( 2.168) d 2.096 LM (1 4) 22.788 ( 0.000) HESC 5.543 ( 0.785) AIC 4.071 ARCH (1) 0.0005 ( 0.983) RESET F 4.542 ( 0.036) Statistically, the ECM for inflation passes the usual tests for serial correlation and stability. The coefficient on the fourth order disequilibrium ECM is 0.118 in absolute value implying that 11.8% of any disequilibrium in any one year is compensated for during the following year. This reflects a stable ECM which eventually converges to its long-run path. The coefficient on the income growth variable was -0.836 and represents the short-run elasticity. The coefficient on the money growth variable was 0.135 and was significant at 13.6% level. It represents the short-run elasticity. The long-run elasticities could be derived from the disequilibrium ECM but we preferred to estimate it directly via the application of the Johansen cointegration procedure in the following sections. 13 All in all, the results show significant negative short-run effects of the income variable and some positive effects of money on inflation. The previous disequilibrium from the long-run relationships was also significant. To account for the structural factors in the ECM we estimated the following specification: t 0.858 D82 m t p t 0.869 0.603 y t 1107 . D85 y t 0.068 m (1.188 ) ( 2 .188 ) ( 2 .213) ( 0.395) ( 2 .121) t 0.723 D88 m t 0.277 e t 1 1295 . D85 m ( 2 .352 ) R 2 0.266 ( 2 .823) (1.673) R 2 0.204 7.103 F 4.252 d 2.120 ( 0.000 ) LM (1) 0.348 ( 0.555) ARCH (1) 0.171 ( 0.679 ) The results confirm the depressing effect output has on inflation throughout the estimation period and regardless of the incidence of breaks. Money, however, was insignificant before 1982 but its effect increased sharply since then as evidenced by the coefficients on the 1982 and 1988 breaks. The coefficients on money during the 1985 period was negative as obtained previously and similar considerations to those noted above would explain its negative behavior in that period. As far as the short-run disequilibrium is concerned, the results show that 22.7% of any disequilibrium will be removed within the time period. Adjustments to errors thus are large and rapid during the advent of high inflation. 5. Cointegration: This section sequentially tests for cointegration of the hypothesized relationships in order to address the issue of the presence of long-run equilibria between the variables. Allowing for a previously noted linear deterministic trend in the inflation data we proceed to undertake cointegration analysis via the application of a Vector Autoregression(VAR) of order 2. Results are presented in table(4) below: 14 Table(4) Johansen Cointegration* Eigenvalue LR 5% no. of CE(s). 0.216 35.633 29.68 None** 0.134 13.442 15.41 At most 1 0.003 0.314 3.76 At most 2 * LR is the Likelihood Ratio Test. no. of CE(s) is the number of cointegrating equations. ** denotes rejection of the hypothesis at 5% significance level. The result of the LR test again indicates the presence of one cointegrating equation at the specified significance level. The normalized cointegrating equation was estimated as: p 21734 . 0.246 y 1695 . m ( 0.494 ) ( 0.259 ) Loglikelihood 707.005 where figures in brackets are standard errors. According to these estimates, real output growth (supply) was not particularly significant since it possessed a t-value of 0.497 magnitude. The coefficient on the money growth variable was significantly different from zero but not significantly different from one at 5% level. This is an indication of the fact that over the long run the main determinant of inflation in Sudan was money growth, i.e. long-run homogeneity was holding. We also reestimated the extended function within a cointegration framework and results obtained firstly indicated the presence of one cointegrating vector as given in table(5) below: 15 Table(5) Johansen Cointegration* The Extended Function Eigenvalue LR 5% no. of CE(s). 0.576 155.363 124.24 None** 0.346 77.312 94.15 At most 1 0.159 38.707 68.52 At most 2 0.123 22.935 47.21 At most 3 0.091 10.969 29.68 At most 4 0.024 2.306 15.41 At most 5 0.001 0.125 3.76 At most 6 * LR is the Likelihood Ratio Test. no. of CE(s) is the number of cointegrating equations. ** denotes rejection of the hypothesis at 5% significance level. The result of the LR test again indicates the presence of one cointegrating equation at the specified significance level. The normalized cointegrating equation was estimated after some reduction procedures as: t 0100 t p t 12.813 0.333 y t 4.454 D85 y t 0.374 m . D82 m ( 0.146 ) ( 0.548 ) ( 0.118 ) ( 0.079 ) t 0198 t 0.474 D88 m . D92 m ( 0.090 ) ( 0.081) Loglikelihood 1434.495 where figures in brackets are standard errors. According to these estimates, real output growth (supply) was significant before and after its 1985 break. The coefficients on the money growth variable were also significantly different from zero before and after the successive monetary breaks. They were also not significantly different from one at 5% level after the conclusion of the breaks in 1992. This is an indication of the fact that over the long run the main determinant of inflation in Sudan has become money growth, i.e. long-run homogeneity was holding at the end of the inflationary era. 16 Conclusion: This paper attempted to study the determinants of the inflation process in Sudan during the past two decades. Inflation was high, accelerating and variable during that time period. These characteristics were incorporated in the estimation procedure via allowances for structural regime shifts and ARCH effects within some conventional formulations directed towards discrimination between alternative inflation theories within the context of a LDC. Results obtained generally validate the conjecture that the inflation witnessed in Sudan is really a hybrid of monetary demand, structural supply and expectational origins. While the problem was predominantly one of a fiscal deficit, other factors played significant roles e.g. inflationary inertia and the various structural factors which impacted the economy during the period of study. In particular, the widesweeping stabilization and structural adjustment programs of 1979 and after unleashed forces that thwarted the authorities ability to harness inflation. The budget deficits were not kept within limits the economy could absorb and in turn they ignited new inertia to the already existing inflationary forces. This coupled with the altogether different phenomenon which emerged since 1992 where inflationary finance through seigniorage became a formal policy tool of the government. The result is witnessed in the present quasi hyperinflation effecting the economy of Sudan. 17 References: Bairam, E. ‘The Variability of Inflation: A New Approach and Some New Empirical Evidence’ Economic Letters 28(1988)327-29. - ‘Money and Inflation: The case of Western Developed Countries 1960-1980’ Applied Economics 22(1990)863-70. Darrat, A. F. ‘The Monetarist versus the Neo-Keynesian Views on Inflation. Some Italian Evidence’ Economic Letters 19(1985)237-41. - ‘Money, Inflation and Causality in North Africa’ Journal of Macroeconomics 8(1986)87-103. Darrat, A. F. and A. C. Arize ‘Domestic and International Sources of Inflation in Developing Countries: Some Evidence from the Monetary Approach’ International Economic Journal 5(1990)55.69. Dhakal, D. and M. Kandil ‘The Inflationary Experiences of Six Developing Countries in Asia: An Investigation of Underlying Determinants’ Applied Economics 25(1993)413-25. Domowitz, I. and I. Elbadawi ‘An Error Correction Approach to Money Demand. The case of Sudan’ Journal of Development Economics 26(1987)257-75. Dornbusch, R. and S. Fischer ‘Stopping Hyperinflations, Past and Present’ Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv (1986)1-4. Johnson, O. E. G. ‘On Growth and Inflation in Developing Countries’ IMF Staff Papers 31(1984)636-60. Kirkpatrick, C. H. And F. I. Nixson ‘The Origins of Inflation in Less Developed Countries: A Selective Review’ in M. Parkin and G. Zis(eds.) “Inflation in Open Economies” Manchester University Press, Manchester, 1976. Montiel, P. ‘Empirical Analysis of High Inflation Episode in Argentina, Brazil and Israel’ IMF working papers 88/68(1988). Ryan, T. C. I. And W. J. Milne ‘Analyzing Inflation in Developing Countries: An Econometric Study with Application to Kenya’ Journal of Development Studies 31,1(1994)134-156. Saini, K. ‘The Monetarist Explanation of Inflation: The Experiences of Six Asian 18 Countries’ World Development 10(1982)871-84. Siklos, P. L. ‘The Money Growth-Inflation Relationship under Hyperinflation: An Illustration from Hungary’s Postwar Experience’ Applied Economics 23(1991)1453-60. Vogel, R. C. ‘The Dynamics of Inflation in Latin America, 1950-1969’ American Economic Review 64(1974)102-14.