Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
1. Introduction Introduction The United Nations Millennium Declaration, adopted by the General Assembly at its fifty-fifth session, notes that the globalization of the world economy “offers great opportunities” but also states that “the central challenge that we face today is to ensure that globalization becomes a positive force for all the world’s people.” The declaration recognizes that “developing countries and countries with economies in transition face special difficulties in responding to this central challenge.” One important challenge for developing and transitional countries is the creation of effective tax systems that will allow them to mobilize their domestic resources for development purposes. The forces of globalization create new difficulties for these counties to overcome as resources are generated. The Millennium goals of sustainable development, broad-based economic growth, and poverty eradication will not be achieved easily or evenly. As the Declaration notes, a concerted effort must be made to formulate both national and global policies in order to ensure that all countries and all people gain from the emerging world economic structure. Concerted efforts on many fronts will be required to improve the economic conditions in developing and transitional countries. To achieve broad-based growth, these countries almost certainly will require the continuation and expansion of international flows of private capital. In some cases, the cancellation or reduction of official bilateral debts will be a practical necessity. Perhaps most importantly, these countries must join with the developed countries in promoting a higher degree of international cooperation on issues of importance to development, including cooperation on social, financial, fiscal, and tax policies. No matter how successful efforts may be to increase the international flow of capital and to improve its allocation, the adequate mobilization and 1 efficient and equitable use of domestic resources remains critical to the achievement of the Millennium goals in developing and transitional countries. As the Secretary-General noted in a recent report (“Road map towards the implementation of the United Nations Millennium Declaration”), “the mobilization of domestic resources is the foundation for self-sustaining development” because such resources in even the poorest countries almost invariably “play the main role in financing domestic investment and social programmes, which are essential for economic growth and making permanent gains in eradicating poverty.” As the Group of Experts on Public Administration and Finance recently noted, “effective democratic governance and efficient public administration are, arguably, among the most important elements in the promotion of a country’s national development agenda.” The SecretaryGeneral’s road-map report specifically singles out “sound fiscal policy” as one of “the elements of good governance that are crucial to economic and social development. The report goes on to note that one of the “strategies for moving forward” is “disciplined fiscal policy, including clear goals for the mobilization of tax revenues.” As was stated at a Side Event on Capacity Building for Effective Tax Revenue Collection held during the Monterrey International Conference on Financing for Development (2002), “the mobilization of domestic resources is the foundation for self-sustaining development.” That document went on to warn that “there are indications that globalization may reduce tax revenues due to increased tax competition among developing countries to attract foreign direct investment, exponential growth in electronic commerce, increased mobility of factors of production, and growing importance of off-shores and tax havens.” The passages quoted above set the stage for the present report, which focuses on strategies for domestic resource mobilization in developing and transitional countries in the context of globalization. By way of introduction to taxation in developing and transitional countries, Chapter 2 of the report presents a brief quantitative overview of the level and structure of taxation around the world, with special attention to recent trends. As this chapter 2 shows, the phrase “developing and transitional countries ” encompasses a very wide variety of countries that differ in level of development, command over resources, and degree of integration into the world economy. It is thus highly unlikely that precisely the same tax policy will be suitable for all countries. Chapter 3 of this report reviews several critical aspects of taxation and domestic resource mobilization in general terms. Some of that discussion is directed primarily at those developing and transitional countries that are still struggling to establish effective governance and have not yet developed the capacity to implement complex instruments of tax policy. Other parts of that chapter, however, have broad implications for most developing countries. Chapter 4 considers the implications of globalization for domestic tax policy in developing and transitional countries. Much of that chapter has more immediate relevance to those countries that are close to becoming full members of the global community. Chapter 5 addresses the need for improved international cooperation in tax matters. It suggests that the Millennium goals cannot be achieved without substantially greater international cooperation on tax matters than has seemed possible in the not too distant past. The various policy recommendation implicit in the report are set forth in chapter 6. A final cautionary note seems needed. Taxation is never a simple matter. Many of the issues discussed in this report are both complex and controversial. No short general discussion can cover all relevant circumstances and possibilities. The literature on the subject is huge and often conflicting. Although we have obviously drawn extensively on that literature in preparing this report, our aim is not to summarize the literature but rather to attempt to distil from our reading of it, tempered by our own experience, some lessons for developing and transitional countries. We have, therefore, not cited references except when specific facts or examples are offered. Similarly, our aim is not to set out a package of tax policies for any one country but rather to suggest the kinds of tax policies that all developing and transitional countries, or at least large subsets of such countries, should consider. To make our points as concrete as possible, we have occasionally 3 made reference to experiences in particular countries. We caution against generalizations from these experiences. Every country is different, and these differences matter with respect to tax policy as in other areas. These difference, nonetheless, do not eliminate all common ground. All countries today face certain common pressures and problems in designing and implementing an effective tax system that arise from the increasingly globalizing world. Many of the policies appropriate for dealing with those pressures and problems in one country will be appropriate in other countries as well. We present this report in the firm belief that some important prescriptions for good tax design, applied with appropriate caution, transcend the particular circumstances of particular countries. 4 Chapter 1 Taxation Around the World in Profile No single tax structure can possibly meet the requirements of every country in the world. The best system for each country must be determined on the basis of its economic structure, its capacity to administer taxes, its public service needs, and many other factors discussed later in this report. Nonetheless, to set the stage for that discussion, it is useful first to stand back and take a look at some broad patterns of taxation that exist around the world and how those patterns seem to have changed in recent years. For this purpose, a short time series of data on tax revenue was collected for 167 countries, representing every region of the world.1 How High Are Taxes? The tax ratios – taxes as a share of GDP– reported in data for the 167 countries range from well under 10 percent in a number of countries, most of which are small and low-income (such as Myanmar, Nepal, Guatemala, Haiti, Niger, Chad, and Central African Republic), to well over 40 percent in a number of countries, mostly in western Europe (Netherlands, Denmark, Italy, France, Sweden). Some lower-income countries, and particularly transitional countries, also had surprisingly high tax ratios. These include countries such as Algeria, Democratic Republic of Congo, Sudan, Ukraine, and Belarus. 1 GDP data were obtained from the IMF World Economic Outlook Database at www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2002/01/data/index.htm and the World Bank Group World Development Indicators 2002 CDROM. Revenue data were obtained from IMF Country Reports at www.imf.org/external/country/index.htm, the OECD Revenue Statistics CDROM, 1965-2000, 2001 and the World Bank Group Development Indicators 2002 CDROM. There are many problems in assembling such data. For example, since countries report their data in many different formats, it is not always possible to extract data for national taxes only: for 123 countries, the data cover the central government only, for 29 countries general government is covered, and for 16 countries it is not clear which governments are covered. In the discussion below, the data for each country is that for the most recent year available. In addition, the length of the time series used to investigate the changes in taxing patterns varies by country, depending on data availability. Since GDP data were not available for five countries, these countries are excluded from the examination of trends. The time series used for “trend” analysis has an average length of only 5.81 years, usually covering the mid-1990s. 5 Similarly, some higher-income countries (such as the United States) had notably lower tax ratios than others in this group, with Hong Kong being the extreme case in this respect. Excluding social insurance contributions– the importance of which varies greatly from country to country depending upon both the magnitude of the social insurance system and the extent to which it is financed from designated contributions2 – on average taxes accounted for a little less than one-fifth of GDP (18.8 percent) for the 167 countries in the sample.3 The median country in the sample has an even lower tax ratio (17.3 percent). If social insurance contributions are included, the average tax ratio rises to 23.0 percent of GDP, although the data may not include all social insurance payments for all countries. Of course, none of these figures adequately depicts the wide diversity in tax levels around the world. Taxes as a share of GDP vary significantly, with much of the divergence appearing to derive from differing levels of income and geographic locations, though of course many other factors may also affect both the need or desire for public services and the ability to collect taxes. Both opportunity and choice affect tax levels. For example, countries with access to rich natural resource revenue bases, such as United Arab Emirates, Venezuela, and Azerbaijan, tend to have higher tax ratios than otherwise comparable countries.4 Particularly in countries with higher income levels, tax levels seem also to reflect more choice than chance: some such countries (e.g. Sweden and the Netherlands) have very large and centralized governments, while others (such as Switzerland and the United States) have much smaller and more decentralized governments. To some extent, countries seem to have been influenced by the behaviour of their neighbours. Although such similarity may also reflect many 2 For example, traditionally some countries such as Australia and New Zealand financed social insurance from general taxation while others, such as many transitional countries, have relied heavily on wage taxes imposed as part of a social insurance system. 3 The figures cited are simple averages. As is common in such international comparisons in which the nation-state is the basic unit of analysis, each country is treated as a single observation, so that a small island such as St. Lucia receives the same weight as a large country such as the United States. 4 Of course, such revenues are often more volatile, reflecting changes in basic commodity prices. 6 other factors, such as a common colonial heritage or common cultural or economic factors, countries may to some extent follow their neighbours because of the demonstration effect -- they learn what possibilities exist in terms of services and taxes -- or because high taxes in one country may loosen the economic and political constraints on raising taxes in its neighbours. Taxes in Europe, and particularly northern Europe, are, for example, much higher than in other regions, while taxes in Asia are noticeably lower than in other continents (see Figure 1). Interestingly, tax levels are more diverse in Africa than in any other continent. Of the 47 African countries included in the sample, more than 25 percent are in the lowest one-third of all countries in terms of tax levels, with tax ratios of 14.6 or less (Chad, GuineaBissau, etc.) and more than 25 percent also in the top one-third, with tax ratios of 21.5 percent or more (Algeria, Botswana, etc.). Figure 1: Tax Revenue as a Percentage of GDP by Continent 23.98 25 20 19.44 18.82 17.5 18.78 16.28 14.67 15 10 5 0 Africa As ia E urope 7 N. Am erica Oceania S. Am erica Total Tax ratios also vary with income levels. The 164 countries in the sample for which GDP data were available were divided into three groups. Sixty-four countries with per capita GDP less than US$1,000 in 1999 were classified as “low-income”, 76 countries with per capita GDP between US$1,000 and US$17,000 were classified as “medium-income,” and the 24 countries with per capita GDP greater than $US17,000 were classified as “high-income”. As earlier studies (Tanzi, 1987) have shown, the data evidence a general tendency for taxes as a share of the economy to rise as per capita incomes rise (Figure 2). Figure 2: Tax Revenue as a Percentage of GDP by GDP per Capita Category 25 23.17 19.97 18.78 20 15.78 15 10 5 0 L ow M id High Total Several factors may explain why countries tend to collect relatively more taxes as their incomes grow. The demand for public services may rise faster than income (the income elasticity for services is greater than one), 8 particularly in countries where income levels are low. Relatively larger shares of income, for example, are directed through the public sector to activities such as education and health care as incomes rise. In addition, as a rule urbanization tends to increase along with income levels, and the demand for public services is generally higher in urban areas, which have greater needs for transportation, water and sewer services, and other governmental services. Fortunately, at the same time as rising incomes give rise to more demands on the public sector, the capacity to pay taxes out of income also obviously rises. Indeed, when countries spend wisely, investing in people and productive infrastructure, public expenditure itself may further expand taxable capacity. Moreover, the ability of countries to tap that capacity is also generally improved. It is, for example, easier as a rule to collect taxes in urbanized areas. Accounting and other information needed to administer modern taxes effectively is generally more prevalent and accessible in higher-income countries. Tax administrations have access to more highly skilled workers and better technology for collecting taxes. More detailed analysis confirms the broad picture shown in Figure 2: on average taxes rise with per capita income levels.5 The relationship between rising income levels and higher taxes is clearly significant within the group of lower-income countries. As average incomes rise in poor countries, the size of the public sector almost invariably expands in relative terms. After some point, however, this “income determinism” of tax levels declines, and in the group of higher-income countries, there is no longer any clear relation between income and tax levels. As noted earlier, the rich, it seems, have more choices, and some rich countries have chosen to levy much lower taxes than others. The most important conclusion emerging from statistical analysis of such data, however, is that there is at best a very weak relationship between 5 A simple regression of per capita taxes on per capita GDP has an elasticity of 1.13, indicating that taxes grow faster than income, this fits the picture seen when countries are sorted by income levels (as shown in Figure 1). A seemingly more appropriate quadratic regression on income shows that taxes tend to rise with income, but at a slower rate as income rises. Indeed, after income reaches high levels (about $22,000 per capita), taxes actually tend to fall as a share of GDP. Linear regressions were also estimated separately for low, median, and high-income countries. The coefficient on per capita GDP was only significant in the equation for low and middle-income countries. 9 economic development and the level of taxation.6 Even the poorest countries, while more constrained than the rich, evidently have considerable choice as to how much they raise in taxation. Who Taxes What? The tax structures used to generate revenues differ as widely around the world as do tax levels. The particular pattern of taxes found in any country, like the tax level, depends upon many factors, such as the tax structures found in neighbouring countries, the economic structure of the country, and its history. In addition, of course, different countries may place varying importance on such commonly accepted characteristics of a good tax system as fairness, revenues, economic effects, collection costs, and so on. Nonetheless, within limits, it can be instructive to look at world averages as one approach to understanding tax structures in countries with different characteristics. 6 A regression of taxes as a percent of GDP on per capita GDP has an R square of only 0.064, though it rises to 0.174 when the equation is run in double log form. The constant term is highly significant in the linear equation with a value of 16.7, which is only a little below the average share paid in taxes. 10 Figure 3: Tax Compone nts as a Pe rce ntage of Tax Revenue Figure 3: Tax Components as a Percentage of Tax Revenue Ex tractio n 6% M is c. 5% D ire ct 3 3% Int. T rade 18 % Co ns umptio n 3 8% As Figure 3 shows, for example, for our sample as a whole, consumption taxes (38.7 percent of the total) – including both excises and general sales taxes such as the value-added tax -- and direct taxes (33.2 percent) -- taxes on income and property taxes -- account for by far the largest share of tax collections. Taxes on imports and exports account for another 18.7 percent, with the balance largely consisting of “extraction taxes.”7 Within the consumption tax category, value-added taxes (VATs) account for 40 percent and excises for 38 percent of the total, and within the direct tax category, personal income taxes are by far the most important, accounting for 47 percent, compared to 36 percent for corporate taxes and 17 percent for property taxes. 7 Extraction taxes may alternatively be thought of equivalent to profits taxes levied on specific industries. If so, in total “income” taxes would then amount to 39.1 percent of all taxes on average. Thirty-eight countries report extraction taxes, with United Arab Emirates (90 percent) and Algeria (78 percent) reporting the highest share of revenues collected from extraction taxes. 11 Once again, the data suggest that a country’s revenue structure depends to some extent upon its location and economic structure. Small island countries such as the Bahamas and Saint Vincent and the Grenadines, for example, largely account for the surprisingly high share of taxes from international trade. More generally, and unsurprisingly, trade taxes tend as a rule to be more important in lower-income countries which, as a group, on average get 24.6 percent of their tax revenue from this source compared to only 2.6 percent in high-income countries (Figure 4). Taxes on international trade – mainly customs duties – seem almost always to decline as countries become more developed.8 An interesting exception is the transitional countries, which, although many of them fall into the low-income group as defined here, have traditionally relied relatively lightly on taxation of international trade (Martinez-Vazquez and McNabb, 2000). Figure 4: Tax Components by GDP per Capita Category 60 50 40 Low 30 M id 20 High 10 0 Direc t Co ns umptio n Int. Trade 8 M isc . E xtra ction The coefficient is negative and statistically significant in a regression of per capita GDP on international trade taxes as a share of GDP. 12 Several other consistent statistical relationships exist between per capita income and tax patterns.9 First, the higher the level of per capita income, the greater the reliance on direct taxes, especially those on personal income. Secondly, although the use of consumption taxes rises more slowly with respect to income than that of income taxes, developed countries on average also rely more heavily on consumption taxes than less developed countries. Thirdly, in contrast, trade taxes fall as both a share of GDP and of total taxes as income levels rise.10 As earlier studies have found, trade taxes clearly decline in importance as income rises (Burgess and Stern, 1993). The observed differences in tax structures in large part appear to reflect the characteristics of higher- as compared to lower-income countries. Direct taxes generally require a more effective tax administration and taxpayers who are more sophisticated, conditions that are more likely to exist in developed countries. Low-income countries tend to raise more revenues at the border, where relatively fewer collection points must be controlled. For similar reasons, consumption taxes in high-income countries are more likely to take the form of broad-based sales taxes, such as the VAT, while lowerincome countries are likely to rely more heavily on excise taxes on tobacco products, alcoholic beverages, and motor fuels—taxes which can again be collected from a relatively small number of vendors, and in some cases at the customs border. Has Much Changed Recently? Over the relatively short time period covered in our data – for most countries, five or six years in the 1990s – the level of taxation has risen only slightly on average, from 18.0 percent to 18.8 percent of GDP. Although taxes 9 Three types of regressions were estimated to quantify the relationship between income and tax structure more fully. Relationships between GDP per capita and each type of tax as a share of GDP, each type of tax as a share of total revenues, and taxes per capita were analyzed. The results in all cases were consistent. 10 The coefficient of international trade taxes as a share of GDP is negative, with an elasticity of -0.22. The income elasticity of international trade taxes is .78 compared to an income elasticity for direct taxes of 1.23 and for consumption taxes of 1.11. 13 appear to have gone up in most regions of the world, they actually declined slightly in Asia over this period. Taking a somewhat longer perspective, Tanzi (1987) reported for the end of the 1970s an average tax ratio of 17.8 percent for the 86 developing countries in his sample. The comparable ratio over a decade later for the 75 countries for which overlapping data are available was 18.6 percent, suggesting that tax levels have been rising gradually over time for the developing countries as a whole. Closer analysis of our sample confirms that taxes rose for each income category and most substantially for the middle-income category – by about 1.0 percent on average. (Figure 5). Figure 5: Change in Tax as a Percentage of GDP by GDP per Capita Category 25 20 Firs t Ye a r 15 L a s t Ye a r 10 5 0 Low M id H ig h T o ta l A useful way to summarize revenue growth over time is in terms of what is called “tax buoyancy,” which is the percent change in tax revenue divided by the percent change in GDP. A buoyancy greater than 1.0 means revenues are growing more rapidly than GDP; a buoyancy equal to1.0 means 14 revenues and GDP are growing at the same pace; and a buoyancy of less than 1.0 means revenues are growing more slowly than GDP. Since, as already noted, revenues on average have been growing more quickly than GDP, the average buoyancy for all countries in our sample period was 1.03. Although buoyancies were roughly equal in our three income categories, in general they tended to be lower in Africa and especially in Asia, than elsewhere. The relative importance of different taxes has changed in recent years. The most striking feature has been a pronounced increase in the share of revenues generated through consumption taxes. One reason for this increase has no doubt been the continued move to the adoption of broad-based valueadded taxes, which rose from 34.6 to 40.6 percent of all consumption taxes during the short period we studied. About 70 percent of the world’s population lives in the 123 or more countries that now levy VATs (Ebrill, et al., 2001). Interestingly, the share of revenues raised from direct taxes has also increased slightly, particularly taxes on personal income and property. In contrast, although the change is small, reliance on corporate taxation has fallen. Taxes on international trade have dropped much more dramatically, decreasing by 4.3 percent of total collections – a decline that has been more or less offset by the 4.1 percent increase in consumption taxes. The use of trade taxes has dropped even more over the longer term. In 1981, for example, trade taxes accounted for 30.6 percent of developing country revenues (Tanzi, 1987), compared to only 24.3 percent for our comparable countries in 1998. Conclusion The focus of the present report is on developing and transitional countries. A very wide variety of countries, with very disparate tax levels and structures, are obviously encompassed by this term. The transitional countries, particularly in central and Eastern Europe are clearly one group, diverse within itself but sharing certain common characteristics and to some extent common problems. The special tax problems facing such countries have been discussed in detail elsewhere (Martinez-Vazquez and McNabb, 2000) and are not, for the most part, rehearsed here in detail. 15 The all too many countries in sub-Saharan Africa and elsewhere that have not managed as yet to create effective basic governance structures constitute another important group. These countries generally need to develop much more effective and efficient tax systems than now exist if they are to be able both to provide for the needs of their people and to engage more effectively in the world economy. Chapter 3 is concerned essentially with setting out some of the conditions needed for more effective mobilization of domestic resources through taxation in those countries. A third distinct category consists of countries, like many in Latin America and Asia, that have progressed some distance – widely varying distances in different cases – towards development goals but still have some way to go. Such countries in particular are facing increasing problems in coping with some fiscal aspects of globalization, as discussed further in Chapter 4. Of course, even countries not so far down the development path may also face significant tax problems as a result of globalization, in particular because of their frequently heavy dependence on trade taxation, as highlighted in the present chapter. Countries closer to the cusp of development, however, also have to cope with potentially troublesome and important problems in the income tax area. 16 Chapter 2 Mobilizing Domestic Resources for Development A tax system, properly designed and utilized, generates sufficient revenue to finance public sector activities in a non-inflationary way. As indicated in chapter 2, different countries accomplish this task in very different ways. Exactly how countries choose to structure their tax systems depends upon the factors discussed there – the level of development, the need and desire for increased public services, and the capacity to levy taxes effectively. It also depends upon the weights that different countries attach to such public policy goals as attaining a desired distribution of income and wealth and increasing the rate of national (and perhaps regional) economic growth. Taxes influence every aspect of the economy -- the willingness to work in the formal sector, the extent to which people save, the way they hold their assets, the choice of business structures, the start-up and location of businesses, and so on. Levying taxes in a manner that fosters desired responses or at least that generates the least perverse reactions possible can be one important way to achieve policy goals. Although governments have policy instruments other than taxes to achieve their goals, the relative importance attached to different goals by those making policy decisions is an important determinant of tax policy. In some cases, measures intended to achieve one goal make the achievement of some other goal more difficult. The classic, although often overstated, example of conflicting goals is the choice between redistribution and growth. It is thus important to understand the real nature of such policy trade-offs if countries are to establish the best feasible tax system for their objectives and circumstances. No one likes to pay taxes. People often seek to avoid paying them, and governments are wary of the political fallout from imposing them. But taxes 17 are always and everywhere a necessary feature of good government. They are necessary both to finance desired public spending in a non-inflationary way and also to ensure that the burden of paying for such spending is fairly distributed. Despite their necessity and the benefits they provide, taxes almost always impose real costs on society. Minimizing those costs is thus as essential an element in good tax policy as meeting revenue needs fairly. The importance and meaning of the costs of taxation is discussed further in the next few sections, which summarize some of what researchers have learned about taxation from the extensive research and experience around the world over the last few decades, the allocation of resources, and economic growth. As already mentioned, however, tax policy is not just about economics. In every country, tax policy also reflects political factors, including concerns about fairness. A subsequent section of the present chapter, therefore, considers the surprisingly scanty evidence on the distributive effect of taxes and the issue of equity and fairness in taxation. Finally, since no matter what a particular country may want to do with its tax system, or, viewed from some perspective or other, what it should do with respect to taxation, what it can do is often constrained in reality, especially in the short run, by its administrative capacity. Developing countries face particular problems in administering a tax system effectively and in meeting some traditional fairness goals. As noted in chapter 2, such countries on the whole rely more heavily on excise and trade taxes, and correspondingly less heavily on income taxes, than do developed countries. Tax structures in developing countries differ in this way largely owing to differences in economic structure.11 In most developing countries, for example, the agricultural sector is relatively large and has low productivity. Even in the urban sector, the “informal” economy tends to be relatively much larger than in more developed countries.12 Since wage and other formal sector income is relatively less important and record-keeping is 11 A century ago, the now developed countries also relied heavily on excises and trade taxes, in part again reflecting the nature of their economies at that time. 12 The informal economy is also relatively large in a number of transitional countries (e.g. Ukraine) as well as in some relatively advanced developing countries (e.g. Argentina). 18 often of lower quality, income taxation in developing countries is on the whole both different and more difficult than in more developed countries. Even the formal urban sector in many countries consists largely of small firms, with the larger firms often being state-owned or owned in whole or part by foreigners. It is generally more costly and difficult to collect a given amount of taxes from many small firms than from a few large ones. On the other hand, larger firms may sometimes be more sophisticated in tax matters than the tax administration, particularly with respect to cross-border transactions. The first of these problems makes it important to keep tax structures affecting small firms relatively simple. The second problem, however, requires tax structures to cope with the complex transactions of large transnational firms. It is obviously difficult for countries with limited resources to cope with both problems at once. A later section of this chapter discusses further the critical question of the relation between tax administration and tax policy.13 Appropriate tax strategies for developing and transitional countries are, for the most part, discussed in this chapter without explicit attention to the important global developments discussed in detail in chapter 4 below. Although this division between domestic and global factors is somewhat artificial (and is not adhered to strictly, since some international factors are considered briefly even in the present chapter), it seems appropriate initially to consider national tax policies apart from the global context both to make the topic more manageable and also because, as pointed out in chapter 1, the primary role in achieving developmental goals such as those set out in the Millennium declaration is inevitably played by resources raised domestically. 13 In recent years, an additional factor that has become important in developing good tax policy in many developing and transitional countries has been decentralization, but discussion of this complex issue has been confined to Appendix A in order to keep the discussion in the present chapter more tightly focused. 19 The Costs of Taxation Economists are sometimes accused of over-emphasizing the costs of taxation and the importance of efficient resource allocation. The reality is, however, that taxes do, almost inevitably, impose such costs, and it is surely in the interests of poor countries in particular to minimize such “deadweight losses,” which typically reduce the resources available to achieve socially desired objectives. Countries in which, by definition, resources are scarce should be particularly concerned to use as efficiently as possible the resources that they have and hence to ensure that the taxes they impose are as efficient as possible. “Efficient resource allocation” may sound like a theoretical abstraction of interest only to economists, but it is clearly better than the alternative of, in effect, simply wasting scarce resources and hence making society as a whole worse off. The confusion apparent in some public discussion of these matters may arise from a misunderstanding what is meant by the “costs” of taxation. Most people probably think of such costs in terms of the taxes collected. In economic terms, however, taxes are simply a means of transferring resources from private to public use and are not themselves a cost in economic terms. Economic costs are incurred only when the total volume of resources available for society’s use, whether for public or private purposes, is reduced by taxes. Costs in this sense arise from the process of taxation for several reasons. First, and most obviously, taxes cost something to collect. On average in developed countries, perhaps 1 percent or so of tax revenues must be devoted to covering the budgetary costs of tax collection. The costs of tax administration may often be relatively higher in developing countries – a recent study in Guatemala, for example, estimated them at 2.5 percent of collections (Mann, 2002) – but the costs of administering the tax system are seldom a significant factor in shaping tax policy. Another real economic cost involved in collecting taxes are the “compliance costs” incurred by taxpayers in meeting their tax obligations, 20 over and above the actual payment of tax. Tax administration and tax compliance interact in many ways. Often, administration costs are reduced when compliance costs are increased, e.g., when taxpayers are required to provide more information thus increasing compliance costs, but making tax administration easier and less costly. There may not always be a tradeoff between administration and compliance costs, however. Compliance costs may increase along with administration costs when, for instance, a more sophisticated tax administration requires more information from taxpayers, undertakes more audits, and so forth. Conversely, administrative and compliance costs may fall if the tax laws are simplified or interpretive issues that have generated conflicts get resolved. Compliance costs are incurred not only by taxpayers but by all who are involved in the tax process – for example, employers withholding income taxes from employees and banks who collect and remit taxes to government. Such costs include the financial and time costs of complying with the tax law, such as acquiring the knowledge and information needed to do so, setting up required accounting systems, obtaining and transmitting the required data, payments to professional advisors and so on. The measurement of such costs is still in its infancy, but a number of studies of their magnitude and distribution have been carried out in several developed countries (Sandford, 1995). On average, compliance costs in developed countries are perhaps four to five times larger than the direct administrative costs incurred by governments. One of the very few studies of such costs in a developing country (India) suggests that they may in some instances be considerably higher than for the developed countries (Box 1). In terms of the costs borne by business, compliance costs are typically much higher with respect to taxes collected from smaller, formal market firms than from larger firms. 21 In terms of the costs borne by business, compliance costs are typically much higher with respect to taxes collected from smaller, formal market firms than from larger firms. Box 1 — Compliance Costs A recent careful study of compliance costs with respect to the personal income tax in India (Chattopay and Das Gupta, 2002) suggests that compliance costs in that country are especially high for non-salary earners, whose costs appeared to be up to 10 times higher than those for salaried employees (whose taxes are essentially withheld). Even for salary income, estimated compliance cost as a percentage of collections in this study was found to be up to ten times higher than in developed countries. The authors of the report characterize their findings as “preliminary and subject to error,” due to sampling issues. Notwithstanding this caveat, the study provides highly credible evidence of serious problems with India’s income tax. These results do not mean that compliance costs are always likely to be so high for the personal income tax in developing countries. But they do suggest that a tax like that in India is an inappropriate model for other developing countries to follow. As reported in the study, India’s personal income tax is exceptionally complex, is shot full of exemptions and concessions, has a highly progressive nominal rate schedule, and is administered in an apparently capricious and dishonest fashion. In brief, the tax is badly designed for the circumstances in which it must operate and cries out for major reform. Finally, and most importantly, taxes may give rise to what economists call “deadweight” or “distortion” costs. Almost every conceivable tax has the potential to alter decisions made by businesses and individuals as the relative prices they confront are changed.14 In some cases, these costs are the nearly 14 There are a few exceptions. Lump-sum taxes, where the tax burden is the same regardless of any behavioural responses by taxpayers, are one example, much favoured by theorists. More importantly in practice, to the extent that taxes fall on economic “rents” – payments to factors above those needed to induce them into the activity concerned -- they too may not affect economic activity. Well-designed taxes on natural resources and land, for example, may thus to some extent produce revenue without economic distortion. Finally, in certain instances, taxes – again, if properly designed – may even induce desirable behaviour rather than impede efficient, market-enhancing decisions. Certain environmental levies, for example, or even crude proxies such as taxes on fuel, may to some extent have such effects. Such instances of “good” taxes – those with no bad economic effects – should of course be exploited as fully as possible, just as well-designed charges should to the extent possible, given public policy objectives, be used to finance certain public sector activities that specifically benefit identifiable individuals. In the end, however, most of the taxes needed to finance government will have to come from other sources and will hence give rise to the efficiency costs discussed in the text. 22 inevitable result of pursuing particular tax policy goals. As a rule, nevertheless, the resulting changes in behaviour tend to reduce the efficiency with which resources are used, resulting in lower output and a decline in the potential well-being of the country as a whole. It is only sensible for a government to limit the negative impact of such changes in behaviour whenever feasible. Although the transfer of resources to the government through taxation may enhance national well-being, that benefit does not justify the use of inappropriate instruments of taxation. Decisions to work, for example, are affected by taxes on wages (personal income taxes, wage taxes, social security taxes, and so forth) that reduce the incentive to work. The higher the tax rate on wages in the formal sector, the less attractive it is to work in that sector and the more attractive untaxed informal sector activity becomes. Consumption taxes too may discourage work, because they raise the amount of time one must work to pay for goods and services through the market place. Since taxes are not imposed on leisure, it is not surprising that, at the margin, the effect of both income and consumption taxes is likely to discourage (taxed) work. Of course, taxes not only alter relative prices – in the case of a wage tax, the net (after-tax) wage – but also income. Since people who work will have less net income after a wage tax is imposed, they may choose to work more to offset the income loss. Indeed, in many cases, they may have to work more simply to keep themselves and their families alive. The net effect on work of any tax change reflects both this income effect and the effect of the change in relative prices (the substitution effect). Voluminous studies of the impact of taxes on work exist for many countries, with results varying from country to country depending upon the structure of taxes and the nature of the economy.15 The important point in the present context, however, is that, regardless of the income effect, the substitution effect – the change in relative prices – of taxation in itself leads people always and everywhere to reduce their work decisions and hence, if 15 For one such recent study, of Colombia, for example, see Alm and López-Castaño (2002). 23 those decisions had been economically efficient before the tax, reduces the potential output of the nation. Such substitution effects are the source of efficiency losses from taxation. They may be counterbalanced to greater or lesser degrees by non-fiscal factors or by putting the tax revenues to good use, but they nonetheless exist. An important concern in designing a good tax system is thus, to the extent consistent with other policy objectives, to minimize such effects and hence to minimize the efficiency costs of taxation. Almost all taxes may have such effects on resource decisions. Consumption taxes, such as the value added tax may discourage the consumption of taxed as opposed to untaxed goods (e.g. housing in some countries). Taxes on gasoline, alcohol, and cigarettes can reduce the consumption of these items.16 Income taxes, since they tax the return to savings, may alter the amount of savings or the form in which savings are held. For example, failure to tax capital gains until they are realized (taken in cash) encourages the holding of assets that implicitly retain the capital gains without realization in cash. Taxes may also affect investment, and such effects may be especially important when economies are more open to trade and investment. Firms may, for example, choose to locate their activities in any of a number of countries for many reasons -- the relative costs of production, access to markets, etc. – but taxes too may affect their choice of location. To the extent taxes lower the after-tax return on investments in a country or a region, the level of investment and hence growth may be lower than it would otherwise be (Box 2). Corporate income taxes may also affect how corporations structure their finances. For example, debt finance is encouraged over equity finance when interest on debt capital is deductible and dividends paid on equity capital are not. Box 2 — Effective Tax Rates Taxes are one of many factors affecting investment. To study the impact of taxes on capital allocation, one must first quantify that impact. There are two principal measures used to do so: the marginal effective tax rate 16 As noted earlier, not all such effects need be bad: for instance, if tobacco consumption falls, people may live longer, healthier and more productive lives. 24 (METR) and the average effective tax rate (AETC). METR is the ratio of the taxes imposed on an increment of investment to the total after-tax income generated by that incremental investment. In contrast, AETC is the ratio of the total taxes imposes on a taxpayer to its total income. “Income” in these formulas is defined broadly to include, respectively, all the benefits captured by the taxpayer from its marginal investment or its total investment. The principal differences between these two measures, and their significance, may be illustrated with an example. Consider a large wellestablished American manufacturing firm that intends to invest abroad. The potential investment location will be chosen from three small countries that are similar in all relevant attributes (including the effectiveness of tax administration) but the design features of their tax systems. Policy makers in these three countries need answers to two different questions. How “competitive” is their tax system compared to the other two? And how would the fiscal position of the countries be affected should they be chosen as the location for this foreign investment? The technical question facing policy analysts in these countries is essentially what tax measurement to employ, METR or AETR, in answering these questions. The short answer is that both are relevant. In general, METR should be used for estimating tax competitiveness, or the investment impact of the formal tax structure, and AETR should be used to estimate the fiscal position, or revenue impact, of the investment. According to economic principles, a rational investor will continue to invest until the marginal income from additional investment equals the marginal cost of earning that income. Consequently, the firm will favour the investment location where the marginal cost is lowest. In this example, the firm would not consider investing in any of the countries if its marginal cost of making the investment, determined without reference to taxes, is greater than the expected marginal revenue. If the investment makes sense without reference to taxes, however, then the METR comes into play. All else being equal, the country with the lowest METR would be the most “competitive” in attracting investment from the firm. The AETR generally would not be relevant to the firm in making its investment choice. However, for simplicity, this example ignores the possible impact of the American tax system on the firm’s investment decisions. If that impact is taken into account, then the AETC might be relevant to the firm’s investment decisions, due to the way the American foreign tax credit system operates. The AETR is the proper measure of the benefits to a country, in terms of additional tax revenues, from serving as the host for the investment by a foreign firm. A firm is taxed not only on the taxable income generated by 25 the last dollar invested but also on the income generated by every dollar invested. For example, if the American firm earned US$1,000 in one of the countries and the AETR in that country was 30 percent, the country would obtain tax revenues of US$300. Exactly how important such tax effects are is a matter of considerable debate among analysts even in developed countries,17 but the consensus is that they are almost certainly much more important than was thought thirty or forty years ago. The efficiency costs of taxation are certainly a considerable multiple of the administrative and compliance costs mentioned above. The lowest estimates for developed countries are perhaps 20-30 percent of revenues collected and much higher figures are not uncommon. Costs of this magnitude mean that one Euro shifted from the private to the public sector can cost the private economy 1.2 to 1.3 Euro plus the administrative and compliance costs. Thus it is conceivable that the loss for which there are no services in return is nearly one half as much as the value of revenues shifted to the public sector. To the extent such costs are an inevitable consequence of rational policy decisions (for example, to redistribute income through the fiscal system), they may of course be considered acceptable. But losses of this magnitude require a high payoff in benefits. Further, it is obviously critical to design taxes to minimize such possible adverse consequences in poor countries. This point is worth emphasis because, although effects such as those mentioned above are real, they are not directly visible. The efficiency cost of taxation arises because something does not happen: some activity did not occur or occurred in some other form. Output that is not produced, however, is still output – and potential welfare – lost. What you see is not what you could get if the taxes needed to achieve public policy objectives were better designed. Efficiency is no mean virtue anywhere, but it is surely especially important not to waste resources by taxing inefficiently in countries that have few resources to waste. Interaction between the global economy and domestic resource 17 For a recent survey of the effects of taxes on saving, for example, see Bernheim (2002). 26 mobilization is perhaps more clear in terms of the distortionary effects of taxes. Globalization, new technologies, digitization, and better transportation all conspire to increase the distortion from taxation by giving both consumers and producers more options for tax evasion and avoidance. Thus, a focus on the full cost of taxation is more essential today than it has ever been. Good tax policy thus requires minimizing unnecessary costs of taxation. To do this, experience and analysis suggests that, to the extent possible, three broad rules should be followed: First, tax bases should be as broad as possible. A broad-based consumption tax, for example, will still discourage work effort, but choices between taxable and non-taxable goods and services will not be altered if all are taxed.18 A few items, such as gasoline, tobacco products and alcohol, may be chosen for differentially higher taxation for regulatory reasons or because the demand for these products is relatively unresponsive to taxation so that at any given tax rate efficiency costs are relatively low and revenues relatively high. Income tax bases too should be as broad as possible, treating all incomes, no matter from what source and whether in-kind or in cash, as uniformly as possible. Second, from an efficiency perspective, tax rates should be as low as possible, consistent with the need to finance the appropriate functions of government. Of course, the broader the base, the lower the rate needed to generate a given amount of revenue. Lower rates are worthwhile, however, in their own right. The reason is simply because, as noted above, the efficiency cost of taxes arises from their effect on relative prices, and the size of this effect is directly related to the tax rate. In fact, the general rule is that the distortionary effect of taxes increases proportionally to the square of the tax rate, so that doubling the rate of a tax implies a fourfold increase in its efficiency costs. From an efficiency perspective, it is thus always better to 18 In theory, in order to minimize efficiency losses different tax rates should be imposed on each commodity, with higher rates imposed on those goods and services where the changes in behaviour are the smallest. To do so, however, requires much more information about how taxes alter behaviour than is available in most countries. Moreover, this approach does not take administrative and equity concerns into account. For these reasons, in practice it seems generally advisable to impose a uniform tax rate to the extent possible. 27 Income tax bases too should be as broad as possible, treating all incomes, no matter from what source and whether in-kind or in cash, as uniformly as possible. tax rates should be as low as possible, consistent with the need to finance the appropriate functions of government raise revenue by imposing a single rate on a broad base rather than dividing that base into segments and imposing differential rates on each segment. In practice, of course, as discussed further below, this consideration needs to be balanced against the equity argument for using a graduated rates schedule to impose heavier tax burdens on the well-off. Third, from an efficiency perspective, it is particularly important to impose taxes on production with care since such taxes directly affect the location of businesses, alter the ways in which production takes place, change the forms in which business is conducted, and so forth.19 Taxation at the point of production is nonetheless often essential in developing and transitional countries for a variety of reasons. For instance, it is often simpler in countries with limited administrative capacity to collect excise and even sales taxes at the point of manufacture. In addition, to the extent that taxes recover the costs of providing public services to businesses they should obviously be imposed directly on producers. Finally, as discussed further below, taxes need to be imposed on corporate income both to prevent tax avoidance by retaining earnings within a corporation and to collect taxes from foreign-owned firms. Tax Revenue A tax system that attains other goals but does not meet revenue needs is not viable. The need for sufficient revenue to prevent large budget deficits is obvious. Except in circumstances when some short-term fiscal stimulus may be considered appropriate for macroeconomic reasons, deficits generally have such undesirable macroeconomic consequences as crowding out private investment and causing inflation. Preventing deficits requires good control over both the expenditure and revenue sides of government but the focus here is only on the revenue side. Effective, accurate estimates of likely revenues should be developed as an essential component of the budget process. To do so, skilled analysts and the appropriate data are needed in the Ministry of Finance, and possibly also 19 The VAT is rebated on exports, for example, to prevent the tax from operating as a production levy in export markets. 28 in the legislature, to estimate revenues and more generally to investigate the revenue, distributional and other consequences of tax policy changes. Moreover, and importantly, the legislated budget must be structured each year to operate strictly within the revenue estimate. All these points may seem – indeed are – obvious. Nonetheless, even these initial conditions for good tax policy are unfortunately not satisfied in a number of countries. Within a sound budgetary framework, tax reforms should, as a rule be undertaken to achieve long-term rather than short-term objectives. 20 Tax structures should not normally be altered on a temporary basis to meet anticipated current year shortfalls. Frequent changes in tax laws increase compliance costs and, to the extent businesses make production and location decisions on the basis of a particular tax structure, they may impose efficiency costs as well. Of course, minor changes in the tax laws to clarify them or to plug loopholes are often required simply to preserve the original intent of those laws. Such minor repairs of the tax structure, like repairs of an earthen dam, are appropriate and often necessary. What is particularly unwise is to use annual tax changes to avoid the need for major structural tax reforms. Unless tax revenues grow sufficiently quickly to finance desired services over the long term, governments need either to reduce expenditures, to raise tax rates, or to alter other structural characteristics of the system. To provide a stable environment for economic activity, to the extent possible, a good tax system should yield an appropriate revenue growth path that equals the necessary trend of expenditures. Although of course the precise rate at which revenues should grow differs from country to country in the light of the demand for public services, a useful baseline is to expect that the growth rate should be at least the same as the overall economic growth rate, unless the country wants to increase (or reduce) the size of its government. 20 The immediate revenue effects of a tax policy change need not reflect its long-term effects, owing both to transitional aspects of the new structure and to the fact that taxpayers often change their behaviour temporarily to take advantage of higher or lower tax burdens in the years before or after the changes. 29 Tax policies enacted in such economically and politically difficult circumstances have often come up short in terms of resolving the underlying basic problem of inadequate revenue elasticity. The rate at which revenues increase over time can differ dramatically depending on the tax structure, the quality of tax administration, and the type of economic growth. When revenues consistently grow more slowly than the demand for public services, tax reform is usually required with a goal of raising revenue growth. The “income elasticity” of a tax system measures how fast revenues grow relative to the economy.21 Tax elasticity is defined as the percentage change in tax revenues divided by the percentage change in GDP (or potential tax base, such as personal income). An elasticity equal to one, for example, means that tax revenues grow at the same rate as the economy (meaning tax revenues will remain a constant share of GDP without the need to enact policy changes), while an elasticity greater than one indicates that tax revenues grow more rapidly than income. In principle, revenues should grow at the same rate as desired expenditures (that is, the income-elasticity for revenues and expenditures should be the same). In practice, however, many developing and transitional countries have had great difficulty in achieving this target, leading to frequent tax “reforms” aimed primarily at closing short-term revenue gaps. Tax policies enacted in such economically and politically difficult circumstances have often come up short in terms of resolving the underlying basic problem of inadequate revenue elasticity. The likelihood is that the reforms are shortterm patches that make the tax system more complicated and less coherent. Moreover, as noted above, frequent rate or base changes entail additional administrative and compliance costs as well as, in many cases, efficiency costs. Tax changes are costly, and an important consideration in changing taxes should thus be to avoid future changes to the extent possible. Close attention should thus be paid to the long-term implications of tax reforms on revenue elasticity. The overall elasticity of any tax structure is simply the average of the Tax “elasticity” refers to revenue growth in the absence of any tax policy changes, while tax “buoyancy” refers to growth including the effects of such changes. In principle, elasticity is a better of measure of the growth potential of the tax structure. In practice, however, as in chapter 2, data limitations often force analysts to rely on tax buoyancies. 21 30 elasticity of individual taxes, weighted by the percentage of total taxes raised by the tax. The elasticity of a tax depends on the specific characteristics of its structure. In general, the elasticity of personal income taxes reflects the progressivity of their rate structure and, most importantly, the level of the personal exemptions (or zero bracket) relative to average income levels. Consumption taxes that cover more rapidly growing goods and services and not just more slowly expanding traditional goods are more elastic, especially if levied as a percentage of the price (like a VAT) rather than on the specific number of units purchased (as with many excises). Property tax revenue obviously rises more rapidly when reappraisals occur on a regular basis and when property is fully valued, when on average it is rising in value, and so forth. Unsurprisingly, revenue growth generally slows during recessions and accelerates during expansions. Revenue elasticity also tends to rise in expansions and fall in recessions, thus exacerbating the volatility of revenue flows. The elasticity of the corporate income tax is often particularly volatile because in a recession corporate profits fall much more precipitously than overall economic growth. Countries that depend heavily on taxation of natural resources such as oil or minerals are especially vulnerable to cyclical swings, with wide swings in prices shifting tax revenues dramatically and making the stable provision of government services difficult. Other things being equal, reliance on a balanced set of tax instruments rather than on a single revenue source will reduce tax revenue volatility, just as an individual investor can reduce the volatility of his or her investment portfolio by balancing different investment categories. Taxation and Fiscal Adjustment Chapter 4 considers in detail some of the implications of globalization for taxation in emerging economies, but one important aspect of taxation in relation to globalization - the role of taxation in adjustment policy - is considered briefly here, because in practice in many countries macroeconomic concerns often tend to dominate all other factors in determining the appropriate level and structure of taxation. 31 The existing revenue systems of many countries are inelastic, meaning revenue growth is slow relative to economic growth and often even slower compared with the desired growth in public expenditures. As just discussed, in many ways the most important macroeconomic lesson for fiscal design suggested by experience in recent decades is that many developing and transitional countries need to improve the elasticity of their tax systems, that is, to make them more responsive to changes in real and nominal income. The existing revenue systems of many countries are inelastic, meaning revenue growth is slow relative to economic growth and often even slower compared with the desired growth in public expenditures.22 Continued tax reforms - reforms that all too often amount to little more than ad hoc changes in tax structure and tax administration intended simply to bring in more money to deal with immediate fiscal needs - are required simply to maintain the current level of government spending (relative to the economy). In such an environment of repeated fiscal crises, the changes made to generate additional revenues are almost inevitably those that are most politically expedient, with relatively little attention being paid to good tax policy. Over time the result of this process is likely to be a tax system that resembles a patchwork quilt and that deviates substantially from the system that would best achieve the country’s policy goals. Observers of fiscal changes in countries such as Colombia and Mexico, for example, have sometimes referred to the “fiscal constant,” by which they mean the observed fact that, despite frequent tax changes, the government’s share of national income has on the whole remained remarkably constant for decades. In some transition countries, such as Ukraine, despite frequent reforms, the tax ratio (share of the economy paid in taxes) has even decreased substantially. Such tax structure instability may not increase the tax ratio, but it inevitably creates uncertainty and, as noted earlier, tends to reduce private investment. Furthermore, the haphazard tax structure that tends to result from this process generally increases economic distortions, often in ways not fully perceived by policy-makers. 22 Chapter 2 showed that such countries on the whole had tax systems in which buoyancy was slightly greater than one, but of course in many instances the underlying elasticity of the system is lower and often less than unity. 32 Even countries experiencing economic growth may encounter problems of declining tax revenues relative to GDP. Sustained growth usually requires additional investment in infrastructure and human capital. Increased public expenditure is often needed to maintain and sustain productivity increases. With relatively inelastic tax systems, however, unless tax rates or bases are increased, decreased public spending, with detrimental effects on growth (and perhaps also on political stability) or increased budget deficits with similar dire consequences are likely to result. Since deficits are, in the circumstances of developing and transition countries, usually financed by monetary expansion, leading to inflationary increases in price levels that are likely in turn to lead to demands for more expenditures just to maintain service levels. Since revenues have not expanded in step with nominal income increases, this vicious cycle may continue until a country’s domestic and international credibility vanishes with its rising indebtedness, and a serious macroeconomic adjustment is required. Matters may be even worse when, as is often the case, a vicious cycle is initiated not by a burst of real economic growth but by unsustainable monetary expansion. Even in those fortunate countries that have been able to achieve sustained growth for some period, buoyed by commodity demand or some other factor, a day of cyclical reckoning usually comes. For example, if expenditures rise quickly when revenues from trade or natural resource taxes increase, experience suggests that they are most unlikely to be contracted equally quickly when revenues decline, thus launching the fiscal system once again on a downward spiral. To a considerable extent, such swings are cushioned in developed countries by the higher overall elasticity of their revenue systems. Less fortunate countries, often subject to much stronger swings, would also seem well advised to pay more attention in designing taxes to the likelihood of such cyclical problems than generally seems to be the case. (Box 3). 33 Box 3 — The Case for More Elastic Taxes Not everyone would agree with the argument that a tax system that is more responsive to growth and inflation is an essential ingredient of a sound tax strategy in an emerging economy. There are three key issues with respect to which ideas and interests may differ widely — the appropriate size of government, the appropriate structure of expenditures, and the effects of taxation on growth. If one thinks that the best government is that which governs least, then tax policies that will, over time, tend to maintain or increase the size of government obviously will not be welcome. One might also oppose an elastic tax structure if one believes that public expenditures, in practice, are sufficiently wasteful that cuts in the relative size of the government are desirable, notwithstanding the theoretical benefits of maintaining or increasing the size of the government. Finally, even if one considers both the level and the structure of expenditures to be acceptable, one might still oppose an elastic tax system because such a system necessarily will tax the faster-growing sectors more heavily than the slower growing sectors, with possible negative effects on overall growth. Each of these concerns may be legitimate to varying degrees in different countries at different times under different philosophies of the role of government in society. Broad generalizations about the desirability of improving the income-elasticity of tax systems are as suspect as most other generalizations in this diverse world. Nonetheless, barring very extreme cases where one or more of these three concerns dominates all other considerations, it is not possible to find any good argument in favour of the present predominantly inelastic nature of the tax systems of most developing and transitional countries. Consequently, measures to improve the tax system and increase revenue elasticity almost invariably constitute an essential part of any adjustment package in such countries. The tax policy question facing governments in most developing and transitional countries is generally not whether revenues should be increased, but how they can be increased. The problem facing many countries is all too often not whether to increase revenues but how to do so. Essentially, there are only three possibilities: raise rates, expand bases, and improve administration. Simply increasing tax rates within the existing system is the most obvious and often most politically acceptable approach, but it is often the least desirable. Raising rates in a fundamentally weak tax system in a country in which traditional tax bases are declining and substantial structural change is taking place may not 34 increase revenue much. Even if it does, the country must be prepared to keep increasing rates because the relationship between revenue growth and economic growth is probably slowed by the rate increases. Further, the result may be to make taxes both more inequitable and more inefficient. Inequity increases because only those few unfortunates trapped within the tax system will bear the burden, and (since the distortions associated with taxation increase with the square of the tax rate) inefficiency will also go up sharply with rate increases. Such problems are often exacerbated because it is often politically expedient to increase taxes most on the politically weaker segments of society or perhaps, in some cases, on the most economically mobile sector, foreign investors. Higher tax rates do not solve the problems arising from low revenue elasticity. High rates may increase revenues if they can be effectively enforced, but elasticity depends on the relative growth rate of revenues and not on the level of revenues. The elasticity is, however, a function of the tax structure. When higher tax rates do not elicit behavioural changes aimed at avoiding a tax by reducing taxable activity and taxes are administered effectively, progressive income tax rates may in principle increase elasticity. On the other hand, if the higher rates discourage taxable activity excessively or make it more difficult to administer the tax elasticity may fall even in this case. Keeping tax rates lower thereby reduces the perverse effects of taxation. Properly designed base expansions, through such measures as reducing exemptions and increased efforts to bring non-payers into the tax net, generally have more desirable effects, but they may also require more political support to enact. Those who pay higher taxes when their exemptions are eliminated are usually very vocal in their opposition to the reform, while those who benefit because the elimination of exemptions available to others results in a fairer, more efficient, and perhaps more elastic tax structure - and also because their own tax rates are not raised - seldom voice their support in an active manner. The small additional revenues that must be paid by each taxpayer when rates are increased seem, as a rule, to give rise to fewer politically significant objections than those raised by the more focused, and 35 Higher tax rates do not solve the problems arising from low revenue elasticity. High rates may increase revenues if they can be effectively enforced, but elasticity depends on the relative growth rate of revenues and not on the level of revenues. therefore larger, increases on a smaller number of taxpayers that occur when exemptions are eliminated. But it is important, when possible, to expand the base to include faster growing components of the economy in the tax net. ...whenever possible, it is much better to respond to short-term fiscal pressures by moving existing taxes, such as VAT or income taxes, towards as broad a base as possible by reducing base exclusions, deductions, and exemptions. Raising revenues through base expansion also generally requires better tax administration. New taxpayers must be identified and brought into the tax net, new collection techniques must be developed and so forth. Such changes take time, often considerable time, to implement. The goal of increasing revenues through better enforcement is often espoused, as it was regularly in Russia during the 1990s, but often, the government has no explicit plan to achieve this goal. Raising new revenues through base broadening is thus not as easy or as quick a means of generating additional revenue as simply raising tax rates. On balance, perhaps the best response to pressures for fiscal adjustment in the form of additional revenue is, where possible, a basebroadening reform that eliminates tax incentives or exemptions without significantly increasing the number of taxpayers, thus simplifying rather than complicating administration. Short-term measures adopted in crisis conditions should of course be consistent with long-term objectives. This is easier said than done, however, in countries in which the only quick way to increase revenue may often be to increase, say, the rates of taxes on trade or excise taxes on particular commodities. Nonetheless, whenever possible, it is much better to respond to short-term fiscal pressures by moving existing taxes, such as VAT or income taxes, towards as broad a base as possible by reducing base exclusions, deductions, and exemptions. Only in this way can developing and transitional countries move towards a sounder long-term tax structure -- one that both reduces the likelihood of fiscal crises and provides a better basis for any discretionary rate adjustments that may be required in the future. Broader tax bases are also of course a more effective means of meeting other goals of taxation, such as growth and fairness. Maximizing Growth Consider a country that is concerned only with economic growth and 36 wishes to design a tax system that is as “pro-growth” as possible without concern for fairness or other traditional goals of taxation. What might such a system look like? The simple answer is that no one really knows for sure because the impact of taxes on growth are difficult to determine in theory and even more difficult to determine in practice. We suggest, nevertheless, that a tax system designed only to promote growth probably would have the following four features: It would avoid excessive burdens on business profits so as to avoid discouraging entrepreneurial activity and risk taking. It would place major fiscal reliance in most cases on a broad-based consumption tax and would be cautious in imposing taxes on saved income in order to avoid discouraging savings and promoting capital flight. It would impose taxes, to the extent feasible, on the inefficient, non-monetized sectors of the economy, such as the traditional agricultural sector and the underground economy in order to encourage some migration of the resources utilized in those sectors to more efficient uses. It would avoid imposing burdens on low-income workers that might threaten their ability to work productively. As a preliminary matter, we note that we are not recommending that developing and transitional countries pursue a growth-only strategy. In our view, a tax system should pursue all of the traditional goals of tax policy — efficiency (growth), fairness (tax equity) and administrative economy (low costs of collection and of compliance). When those goals conflict, we believe that a government needs to make sensible tradeoffs. For example, we do not believe that a country should substantially complicate its tax system for small gains in efficiency or fairness or that it should pursue a growth-only agenda or a fairness-only agenda and forsake other legitimate objectives. In addition, we believe that policy makers often can avoid making tradeoffs among the competing objectives of taxation through good tax design. When tradeoffs must be made, we recognize that some differences of opinion are inevitable, even among ourselves. Before tradeoffs among competing tax policy goals can be made in an 37 intelligent manner, it is necessary to understand the nature of the tradeoffs being proposed. For that reason, it is important to understand, within the limits of current knowledge, what types of measures are likely to promote a growthonly agenda. It is also useful to know why some measures that might seem to promote growth are unlikely to do so in practice. Taxation of Business Profits. Some commentators have suggested that a pro-growth strategy calls for the abolition of all taxes on business profits. The basic intuition is that a tax on profits is a tax on the rewards of risk-taking and entrepreneurial activities, that a tax on those rewards is likely to discourage people from engaging in these activities, and that both of these activities are essential elements of sustainable economic growth in most countries. Subject to several important caveats, we believe this basic intuition is unassailable. Our caveats are important, however, and lead us to conclude that a moderate level of tax on business profits is consistent even with the growth-only agenda. One important caveat is that a tax on abnormally high profits, above the amount needed to reward entrepreneurial activities and risk taking, is a highly efficient form of taxation that should be included, to the extent feasible, in a pro-growth strategy. Economists refer to these supra-normal profits as economic rents. In principle, therefore, a country following a growth-only agenda should exempt normal profits and tax abnormal profits. In practice, the distinction between normal and abnormal profits is difficult to make. Profits arising from monopoly practices or from extraction of natural resources are likely to be economic rents, whereas profits earned in highly competitive markets are likely to be normal profits. Even this broad generalization must be tempered by the tax-planning opportunities typically available to business enterprises. For example, a business enterprise may be able to avoid most of the tax on the normal return on its tangible property by financing the acquisition of that property with debt and deducting its interest payments on that debt. Similarly, a business enterprise might reduce substantially the taxes due from its intangible property by acquiring that 38 property in a transaction that required it to pay out most of the expected profits as a deductible royalty. The reality is that most successful business enterprises earn some normal profits and some abnormal profits, and the mix depends upon the nature of the business and the particular economic conditions under which it operates. A second caveat is that the elimination of a tax on business profits will advance the growth-only agenda only if the substitute tax is superior from an efficiency perspective. As noted above, all taxes are likely to have some inefficiencies in practice, and the higher the tax rates, the more significant those inefficiencies become. In most developing and transitional countries, the administrative limitations of the tax department are probably sufficient to introduce inefficiencies into even the best designed taxes, and political constraints may add additional inefficiencies. If a country replaces the revenues from a profits tax by increasing the rates on an inefficient alternative tax, it may not have advanced its growth-only agenda at all, or at least not by very much. A third caveat is that an exemption for business profits jeopardizes the personal income tax, or, indeed, any type of personal tax. Providing an exemption for business profits within the context of a personal income tax is difficult, due to the serious practical difficulties that arise in distinguishing business profits from other types of income. If income labelled “business profits” is exempt from tax and other forms of income are taxable, it can be expected that tax planners will arrange for a large portion of the personal income tax base to fit the criteria for “business profits.” That definitional problem might be avoided by limiting the exemption to profits earned in corporate form. That approach, however, also creates serious problems because taxpayers liable for tax under the personal income tax would have a strong incentive to avoid that tax by placing their income-producing assets in a corporation under their control. Finally, a profits tax is probably the only feasible mechanism available to developing and transitional countries for obtaining a reasonable share of the 39 profits earned by foreign investors. Obtaining taxes from that source will be efficient for the host country, to the extent that the tax can be exported to foreign investors. As discussed above, analysts are unclear on the way the burden of the corporate tax is shifted, although most would agree that the extent of the shifting depends at least in part on the facts and circumstances of particular cases. Given this uncertainty, the promoters of a growth-only strategy should be exceedingly cautious in recommending the abandonment of a profits tax on the income earned by foreign investors. Exempting only domestic earners and taxing foreigners, however, is not a practical option, due to the competitive problems that such a policy would create. Our conclusion is that a high tax on business profits is unlikely to form part of a growth-oriented tax strategy. We do suggest, however, that a stable, broad-based profits tax imposed at rates that are moderate by international standards is defensible even in the context of that strategy. Many countries impose a profits tax at rates of 30 percent or below. If the growth-only agenda is relaxed somewhat to include other considerations, such as fairness, we believe that the case for some form of profits tax is strong. As the survey presented in section 2 shows, most developed and developing countries utilize some form of profits tax.23 Not all of those taxes are likely to be consistent with a growth-only agenda, due to their design features and rates. In our view, the general direction of reform in these countries should be to improve the design of their profits taxes rather than to abolish them. The role of tax incentives for investment, for savings, for exports, for employment, for regional development, and so on must be considered in a discussion of business profits taxes (Shah, 1995). For the most part, such incentives are redundant and ineffective, giving up revenue and complicating the fiscal system without achieving their stated objectives. Even to the extent that incentives may be effective in inducing investors to behave differently than they would have done in response to market signals, the result is often distorting and inefficient, diverting scarce resources into less than optimal 23 Low-income countries generate 11.2 percent of their revenues (1.77 percent of GDP) from corporate profits taxes; moderate-income countries generate 7.8 percent (1.56 percent of GDP) and high-income countries raise 8.4 percent (1.95 percent of GDP). 40 uses. Essentially, incentives improve economic performance only to the extent that government officials are better able to decide the best types and means of production than are private investors. Incentives also result in very uneven tax burdens, with domestic companies often continuing to be subject to the full tax burden, while other firms, particularly multinationals, are subject to much lower effective tax rates because of the incentives. Despite such strictures, many developing and transitional countries continue to introduce and extend a variety of special tax incentives, partly in competition with one another for increased capital flows from abroad. Kyrgyzstan (along with many other countries), for example, which developed a relatively good tax code in the 1990s, has aggressively looked to enterprise zones, tax concessions, and accelerated depreciation with the hopes of generating economic stimulus. Much experience, however, suggests that more important to investment in general are such factors as a sound macroeconomic policy and a stable governance system. Although there may sometimes be a limited role for certain simple incentives as part of a growth-oriented fiscal policy, as some East Asian experience suggests (Bird and Chen, 1998), in general, incentives can never make up for the absence of such critical factors. Should a country decide to introduce a few limited incentives for whatever purpose, it is obviously critical that they should be well-designed, properly implemented, and periodically evaluated if they are to do more good than harm (Box 4). On the whole, however, a better strategy to encourage growth is generally to impose taxes on as broad a base as possible and at the lowest rates possible. Box 4 — Tax Incentives As a rule, disinterested tax analysts, and especially public finance economists, do not favour tax incentives. The effectiveness of tax concessions, tax holidays, and the like is difficult to assess, and even welldesigned incentives may be perverted to benefit existing special interests. For tax incentives to have even a reasonable possibility of serving good public policy, the country offering the incentives must have a stable macroeconomic environment and a stable political and administrative system. Nonetheless, many countries that do not satisfy these conditions 41 continue to have recourse to fiscal incentives for investment. To maximize the possibilities of beneficial results and to reduce the damage that poorlydesigned and implemented incentives may cause, we suggest the following rules for countries that feel compelled, by political or other considerations to adopt tax incentives: 1. Keep it Simple. Complex fiscal incentives are unlikely to produce desirable results at reasonable cost and are likely to be conducive to evasion and corruption. Tax incentives, therefore, should be few in number and simple in structure. Detailed, costly, and complex attempts to divert private investment into pre-selected channels should be avoided. 2. Keep Records. No matter what incentives are created, clear records should be kept as to who receives them, for how long, at what cost in revenue forgone, and with what results in terms of investment, employment, and so on. Clear procedures need to be in place to follow up the results of any incentives granted. 3. Evaluate the Results. At regular intervals — say, annually or at most every three or five years — a country should analyse the data to assess whether the incentive is worthwhile and, if it is not, to eliminate it. A country that is unwilling, or unable, to put incentives to this test probably should not have any incentives. On the whole, however, a better strategy to encourage growth is generally to impose taxes on as broad a base as possible and at the lowest rates possible. Taxation of Savings. A developing or transitional country that is pursuing purely a growth-oriented strategy generally should avoid taxes that tend to reduce national savings and should favour taxes that tend to increase national savings. This basic policy proscription follows from the generally accepted view that domestic savings are essential for financing the investment needed for rapid economic growth. What types of tax policies would encourage savings is a matter of some debate. Economists generally agree that an income tax creates a bias in favour of current consumption over future consumption. Because “future consumption” is largely synonymous with savings, it would seem to follow that a tax that did not contain that bias would be preferable on efficiency grounds to an income tax. As a practical matter, the alternative to an income 42 tax — for those developing and transitional countries capable of administering an income tax — is some form of consumption tax, either a VAT or an income tax with a deduction for savings. The argument summarized above for favouring a consumption tax over an income tax as part of a growth-only agenda is subject to some important caveats. One important caveat is that it focuses only on the substitution effect of the income tax and ignores the income effect. As noted above, a tax that causes taxpayers to shift from one use of their money to another is generally inefficient, absent some special reason for favouring such a shift. To the extent that an income tax causes taxpayers to substitute current consumption for future consumption, it can fairly be said to be inefficient. In determining the impact of an income tax on national savings, however, it is not enough to look only at the substitution effect. Another possible effect of an income tax is that it would cause taxpayers seeking to achieve some definite savings goal to increase their savings. As an illustration of this income effect, assume that a taxpayer has determined that he must save US$800 per year to be able to finance his basic subsistence needs upon retirement. The government now imposes a tax of 20 percent on his income. As a result, he must increase his before-tax savings to US$1,000 in order to achieve his savings goal. As economists have long recognized, the substitution effect and the income effect have opposite impacts on national savings (for those who are net savers rather than net borrowers), and the relative importance of each is a matter for empirical research. As a result, it is possible in theory that an income tax would reduce, increase, or have no net effect at all on national savings. The fact that these two effects tend to be offsetting, however, does not mean that the inefficiency of the tax is reduced. On the contrary, a tax that caused some taxpayers to decrease their savings and caused others to increase their savings would be more inefficient, according to standard economic theory, than a tax that had only one of these effects. The point is that efficiency is measured by economists in terms of lost welfare to individuals, 43 and individuals suffer what economists call a deadweight loss whenever they are induced to change their behaviour on account of a tax. These deadweight losses do not necessarily indicate, however, that the tax system is having an adverse impact on aggregate national savings. A second caveat to the claim that consumption taxes advance a progrowth agenda is that an exemption for the savings component of income generally requires an increase in the tax rate on the consumption component of income if the tax is to raise the same revenue as a normal income tax. Income tax rates can be lower if the base is very broad, a difficulty for many countries that have failed to tax many forms of private sector earnings. All taxes, including consumption taxes, have some inefficiencies in practice, no matter how well they may be designed. An increase in the tax rate on consumption will increase those inefficiencies, perhaps considerably. Whether the increase in inefficiencies will offset the efficiency gains from forgoing the tax on savings is an empirical issue. It depends, firstly, on the actual impact that a tax preference for savings will have on the national savings rate and, secondly, on the actual impact on efficiency of the higher rates on consumed income. That latter effect is likely to depend primarily on the quality of the consumption tax — the worse the consumption tax, the greater the inefficiencies caused by the higher tax rates. A third caveat is that an exclusion for savings in the context of a normal income tax is not easy to achieve from an administrative perspective. If the goal is to increase national savings, then the preference for saved income must be limited to net savings, not gross savings. That is, the tax system must prevent taxpayers from deducting their saved gross income and also deducting the costs of earning that income from their taxable amount. In particular, the tax system needs to prevent taxpayers from taking an interest deduction that is properly treated as a cost of earning saved income (McIntyre, 1997). Experience in many countries that have offered various savings incentives strongly suggests that limiting deductions to the costs of earning consumed income is exceedingly difficult. This point is not relevant, of course, to countries that are choosing between a VAT and a normal income 44 tax. It applies only if the choice is between a normal income tax and an income tax with a deduction for savings. Finally, a country pursuing a growth-only strategy has already determined that it needs to mobilize resources for development notwithstanding the preferences its residents may have for current consumption over future consumption. In effect, a political decision has been made to give some preference to future generations over the current generation — to impose current hardships in the hope of a better life for the children and grandchildren of the current generation. Given this policy framework, a country may not want to put great emphasis on the welfare losses of the current generation due to their time preferences for consumption. The important issue for a growth-only strategy of mobilizing local capital is how best to achieve the goal of increasing aggregate national savings. In this respect, a lower-rate income tax may have the advantage because it can raise the needed revenue with fewer distortions (other than its impact on time preferences for consumption) than a higher-rate consumption tax. The tax revenue, once collected, can then be used to finance investment by the government or, if private investment is preferred, to increase the pool of private investment capital by paying down some of the national debt (assuming, realistically, that such debt exists). For many developing and transitional countries, including most of the least developed countries, the debate over the relative merits of income and consumption taxes is not a significant policy issue. They do not have the administrative capacity to operate a significant income tax, and they have great difficulties in operating efficient consumption taxes. Their main hope of increasing national savings is to impose taxes as best they can and devote whatever portion of those taxes they can afford to investment. The countries where the debate over income and consumption taxes is most relevant are those that have already achieved a significant level of economic development. These countries are the ones that are least likely to adopt a tax policy focussing exclusively on economic growth. 45 Taxation of Non-Monetized Sectors. A growth-oriented tax system in the many developing countries with a large non-monetized traditional sector should reach as far as possible into that sector in order to encourage its incorporation into the monetary (modern) sector. In many developing countries, that sector is traditional agriculture. In some developing and transitional countries, it is the underground economy. Imposing higher taxes on traditional agriculture may be difficult politically and administratively, and it may be inequitable as well. Such taxation, however, is generally conducive to growth. The growth potential of traditional agriculture is limited; especially in light of the way agriculture is subsidized in many developed countries. In addition, the existing social structures in most developing countries make the introduction of modern farming methods exceedingly difficult. From the perspective of promoting growth, therefore, a tax that draws resources out of the traditional sector is likely to be beneficial. At a minimum, the tax system should not discourage growth by taxing resources away from the growth sectors and leaving the traditional sectors untouched by taxation. Taxing the non-monetized sectors is no easy task. An income tax is not a practical alternative for a variety of obvious reasons. A VAT can be imposed on the non-monetized sectors and the underground economy only to the extent that people living or working in those sectors purchase goods and services in the monetized sectors. In some countries, especially some of the transitional countries, those purchases are substantial, whereas in other countries they are negligible. In this regard, the VAT offers a significant advantage because nonregistered taxpayers cannot claim credits for taxes paid at earlier stages of the production process. Choosing not to zero rate agricultural inputs can help ensure that the tax is imposed unless the farmers are registered VAT taxpayers. In many cases, the only practical taxes are taxes on agricultural land and presumptive income taxes (Box 5). 46 Box 5 — Presumptive Taxes Presumptive taxes are taxes that “presume” a certain taxable capacity based on objective (measurable, visible) indicators of production or consumption such as land, electricity used, employees, machines, vehicles, and so on. Such taxes, in many different forms, have a long history in many countries. They seldom produce much revenue and often suffer from many defects of design and administration. Nonetheless, despite such problems, presumptive taxes may in principle play two vitally important roles in developing countries. First, such taxes are often the only levies effectively imposed on the often large, non-modern (or at least “non-official”) sector of the economy. The government may not have the resources or capacity to be able to assess the income or consumption of farmers or small traders effectively, but it is more likely to be capable of measuring land and the floor area of buildings or of counting machines and employees, and so on. Presumptive taxes serve the double function of both securing some revenue from this hard-to-tax sector while at the same time encouraging people to become more productive in order to pay the taxes (which are, if well-designed, “lump-sum” in nature, that is, with income but no substitution effects and, hence, no efficiency cost). Secondly, presumptive taxes can sometimes serve as a backstop for “normal” taxes in the formal sector. For example, Mexico imposes a minimum tax on the gross assets of a business. If the profits reported for tax purposes by a business exceed a certain minimum rate of return on the assets, the profits tax is applied as usual, but if the reported profits are below the minimal return, the business is, in effect, taxed on the presumed income generated by its gross assets. When presumptive taxes, rather than the regular tax structure, are imposed on small traders in order to keep administrative and compliance costs reasonable, care must be taken to ensure that what appears to be a simplification does not in fact entail additional compliance costs. For example, legislation to simplify taxes on small businesses in both Russia and Krygyzstan once required small businesses to calculate tax liabilities using the methodology imposed on larger corporations and also to calculate taxes using the new small business structure. The net result was that small firms were required to calculate taxes using two rather than one approach, thereby raising rather than lowering compliance costs. 47 Excessive Taxation of Working Poor. Even in the most growthoriented tax system, in which those who make tax policy decisions do not care at all about the well-being of the existing population, taxes should kept be as low as possible on the poorest people simply because they must consume to be productive. Just as some so-called “investment” — for example, in luxury homes or elaborate office buildings — is not conducive to productivity, so also some “consumption” is productive. If people do not have enough to eat, if they are too ill to work, or if they are insufficiently protected from the elements in terms of clothing and shelter, or if they are not sufficiently educated to do the work at hand, they are unlikely to be as economically productive as they would be if they were treated more humanely by their government. A tax system, in and of itself, cannot provide for the basic subsistence needs of poor workers. In can raise revenue from other sources that could be used to finance public welfare programs and public education. More fundamentally, it often can avoid imposing taxes that make the poor even poorer. As a result, tax equity (in the sense of not taxing the poor) and growth (in the sense of enhancing the productivity of the labour force) are quite compatible objectives up to some point. A value-added tax might serve both a growth-only agenda and a fairness agenda if it provided an exemption for certain specific items that constituted a significant fraction of the consumption of poor people. For example, a study of the VAT in Jamaica found that exempting only five narrowly-defined items would cut in half the VAT burden imposed on individuals falling within the lowest 40 percent of the income range (Bird and Miller, 1991). Similarly, exemptions for the poor under an income tax would serve both the growth-only agenda and a fairness agenda. We note that serious problems arise under a VAT in limiting the benefits of exemptions to the poor. As the Jamaica example presented above indicates, it may be possible in some cases to mitigate the burdens of the VAT 48 on the poor by exempting a limited number of essential consumption items. In general, however, most exemptions from a VAT are not easily targeted on the poor, and they complicate tax administration. In providing exemptions for the poor under a VAT, therefore, some tradeoff is inevitable between growth and fairness, on the one hand, and administrative economy on the other hand. Concluding Note. The discussion above of a growth-only agenda assumed that the policy choices were being made in a stable political environment and that the basic political structure of the country would not be affected by the steps taken to implement that agenda. In reality, tax policy and tax politics are often intertwined. As a simple example, consider the salt tax. From an efficiency perspective, that tax gets high marks because the demand for salt is quite inelastic and a tax on salt is unlikely to affect consumption choices significantly. Yet the salt tax was a contributing factor in the French Revolution and was a rally cry in India’s quest for independence from Great Britain. Presumably these major political upheavals resulted in some costs in efficiency, at least from the perspective of the ruling parties. Many developing countries have governments that have a fragile hold on power. In such circumstances, an evaluation of the efficiency of the tax should at least consider the potential of the tax for increasing political instability. A tax measure that might get high marks for promoting growth might be decidedly unattractive even under a growth-only agenda if it was likely to destabilize the government. For example, if one region of a country is experiencing most of the economic growth, a tax policy that tended to reduce regional rivalries might be desirable even if that policy might not get the highest marks under a narrow concept of efficiency. Ultimately, the efficiency of a tax needs to be tested by reference to its contribution to the achievement of the goals of the society and not simply on abstract economic theory. 49 From the perspective of social and economic inequality, what matters in the end is the overall impact of the budgetary system on the distribution of wealth and income. Taxation and Equity In reality, of course, fairness or equity is always a central issue in taxation. Indeed, from one perspective, the principal rationale for taxes in the first place may be thought of as an attempt to secure equity. After all, strictly speaking, national governments do not need taxes to secure money because they print the money in the first place. The role of the tax system is instead to take money away from the private sector in as efficient, equitable, and administratively inexpensive way as possible. Equity, with efficiency and administration, is thus one of the three principal factors shaping any tax system. Of course, what any particular person exactly considers equitable or fair may differ from the conceptions held by others. In the end, only through its political institutions can any country define and implement its view of what is an acceptably fair tax system. The Report of the Secretary-General to the Preparatory Committee for the High-level International Intergovernmental Event on Financing for Development, dated 12-23 February 2001, set forth the following more specific goals for developing countries in the design of their tax systems: Countries should strive to develop progressive taxation systems and should endeavour to ensure that the process of adopting taxes is equitable and participatory through, inter alia, the following policies and measures: Taking measures to ensure that the incidence of taxation falls justly on different income classes and different categories of income, such as wages, profits and rents; Extending the tax base to cover incomes from activities that are not currently taxed; Expanding indirect taxes and making them more equitable by targeting the growing modern service sector and socially and environmentally undesirable activities. This section considers in particular the first of these goals. The issue of fairness in taxation may be approached in various ways. For example, one may consider the specific tax burdens (from the income tax, excise taxes, 50 VAT, etc.) imposed on taxpayers who are thought to be in the same or in different economic circumstances. Alternatively, one may instead focus on the overall effects of taxation on income and level of well-being, looking at the burden of the entire tax system. The policy implications of these two approaches may be quite different. The first approach focuses on the implications that details of individual taxes have on the distribution of tax burdens across categories of people. Thus, one examines how exemptions, deductions, tax coverage and other tax characteristics affect tax fairness. Unfortunately, although proposals to reform taxes based on such analysis may indeed improve particular measures of horizontal and vertical equity within the limited group actually subject to the full legal burden of the tax in question, these same features may also have implications for others that may in some instance make the system as a whole less fair. From the perspective of social and economic inequality, what matters in the end is the overall impact of the budgetary system on the distribution of wealth and income. Both expenditures and taxes should therefore be taken into account in considering how government policy affects the distribution of income, as well as the overall equity implications of any tax change. Consider, for example, the case of a transitional country like the Russian Federation, in which the big “untaxed sector is not traditional agriculture (as in many low-income countries) but rather the relatively large shadow economy. The existence of such a sector may have important implications for the effects of particular tax policy. For example, to the extent the VAT functions properly, it will to some extent serve essentially the same function as a presumptive tax on the informal sector (since credits are only available for firms that are registered as taxpayers and those earning income in the shadow sector are taxed when they purchase commodities through the formal sector). On the other hand, if many high-income recipients operate through the shadow economy, the effects on equity of increasing the progressivity of the personal income tax are not always obvious. Government employees and employees of large, formal market firms may be the primary personal income taxpayers and hence bear the brunt of such changes. In such circumstances, it is not inconceivable that indirect taxes such as a VAT and especially certain 51 In short, it is important in thinking about taxation and equity to focus not on preconceived notions about labels – for example, that anything called a personal income tax is, by definition, progressive, while anything called a VAT is, by definition, regressive – but rather on the reality of how taxes work in practice. excises in “higher-income” consumption goods, such as motor vehicles, may be more progressive than a personal income tax that in reality falls largely on a limited group of wage earners.24 In short, it is important in thinking about taxation and equity to focus not on preconceived notions about labels – for example, that anything called a personal income tax is, by definition, progressive, while anything called a VAT is, by definition, regressive – but rather on the reality of how taxes work in practice. Such arguments do not, of course, mean that there is not an important role for both corporate and personal income taxes in developing and transitional countries. As noted in Chapter 2, such taxes are the largest tax source for high-income countries, and the same is likely to be true in other countries as their economies develop, more businesses and individuals become part of the formal economy, and information and tax administration improves. Right now, however, particularly in the least developed countries, revenue systems rely heavily on consumption taxes and are likely to continue to do so for some years to come. All taxes, whether on income or consumption, may affect equity in many and complex ways. They may treat people who are in essentially the same economic position differently (horizontal equity). For example, taxes may fall more heavily on those who consume alcohol than on those who consume housing, or on those who get their income in the form of wages rather than from farms or dividends. Taxes may also differ in their effects on income distribution (vertical equity). They may tax the rich relatively more (progressivity) or less (regressivity) than the poor. Some countries may wish to favour cities; others, rural areas. Some may choose to favour rich savers in the name of growth, others the poor, in the name of redistribution. Like most policy instruments, tax policy can play many tunes. What is critical from an 24 A tax is considered progressive when the tax burden as a percent of income is greater for higher income households than for lower income households, proportional if the percentage of income paid in taxes stays constant as income rises, and regressive if the percentage paid in taxes falls as income rises. A higher income taxpayer will normally bear a larger absolute tax liability than a lower income taxpayer, regardless of whether the tax is progressive, proportional or regressive, so the difference between the three concepts is how rapidly taxes rise with income, not whether taxes rise with income. 52 equity perspective is, first, to be aware of the equity implications of tax reforms for different groups, and, second, to ensure that the actual outcome of such reforms is consistent with the intended outcome. Taxation, for example, may not on its own be able to make the poor richer, but it can certainly make them poorer. Some developed countries such as Canada and the United States use their tax systems to provide income support to certain low-income people. Such systems, however, require both that the tax administration is efficient and that most people file tax returns. Neither condition is satisfied in most developing and transitional countries. In such countries, any fiscal attempts at poverty alleviation must therefore be undertaken primarily on the expenditure side of the budget. Nonetheless, it is important not to make the poor even poorer through taxes. As mentioned earlier, it may therefore be desirable for this reason to exempt certain “basic needs’ items from even the broadest-based consumption tax. Certainly, special heavy taxes on items that constitute a significant consumption expenditure for poor people should generally be avoided (Box 6). 53 Box 6 — Tobacco Taxes An important recent international study (Chaloupa, 2000) has advocated that all countries should consider much higher tobacco taxes than they now have, essentially because of the externalities associated with smoking and because some empirical evidence indicates that those most deterred by higher prices are younger smokers. Governments around the world, many of which already tax tobacco fairly heavily — essentially because they can collect a lot of money from some trapped (addicted) consumers — may seize on such arguments to justify levying still higher taxes on those who smoke. Unfortunately, there are three offsetting arguments to what may seem to be an overwhelmingly attractive case, on both health and revenue grounds, for taxing tobacco more heavily. First, tobacco taxes are perhaps the most consistently regressive of all taxes. Lower income people in all countries are those who are most heavily burdened by such taxes. There is no way for most developing countries to overcome this regressivity by offsetting transfer policies. Second, smuggling creates a severe constraint on the tolerable height of tobacco taxes. Again, this problem is especially serious in developing and transitional countries where the underground economy is already relatively large and enforcement is weak. Finally, the externality arguments used to justify high tobacco taxation (public health costs, smoker-caused fires, etc.) do not, in many cases, support taxes as high as those that are already imposed and are especially unlikely to do so in countries that do not have large publicly-funded health care services Striking the right balance between these various considerations is not easy in any country. It seems fair to say, however, that there is unlikely to be an unexploited revenue bonanza for anyone in increased tobacco taxation. At the other end of the income distribution scale, taxation is one of the few ways in which the wealthy may be made less wealthy, short of outright confiscation. Although past attempts to redistribute income through taxation have not been very effective in most developing and transitional countries 54 (Chu et al., 2001), it may nonetheless be important in political terms visibly to tax those who gain the most from economic development – bearing in mind, of course, the need at the same time to minimize the efficiency costs of unduly high tax rates. Sustainable tax policy needs to be accepted as fair by those affected. Even in the poorest countries, for example, automobiles and other luxury products are more visible than income, so that it should be feasible to collect progressive taxes on these items, and most people would consider it fair to do so.25 Striking the right balance in such matters is what good tax policy is all about. In considering the equity of tax policy, it is important to understand the economic incidence of taxation. The law may say, for example, that firms must pay VAT to the government, but the general expectation is that the real economic incidence of the VAT is on the ultimate consumer. Similarly, motor fuel taxes are almost always collected high in the distribution chain (for example, at import or from major distributors) but again it is generally expected that consumers will pay the tax. On the other hand, the economic incidence of property taxes may be borne either by the owners of land and capital (who also bear the legal incidence) or by the users or renters of the In considering the equity of tax policy, it is important to understand the economic incidence of taxation. property, depending upon market conditions. Indeed, as a general rule, the economic incidence of a tax (at least in the long run) is determined by market conditions, and not by whether the tax is legally imposed on the buyer or the seller. It is often difficult to figure out just who does pay certain taxes in the end (in the economically relevant sense of having lower real incomes as the result of the imposition of the tax). Businesses, for example, attempt to pass on (shift) taxes whenever they can to someone else -- to consumers through higher product prices, to workers through lower wages, to owners of land through lower land prices. The incidence of a corporate income tax thus depends on such factors as the 25 As Hughes (1987) notes, taxing fuel correctly can be especially difficult in countries like Indonesia in which petroleum products (in this case, kerosene) are an essential consumption item for the poorest people. Bosnia seeks to impose differential rates on fuel for home heating versus for other purposes (such as transportation), but this has proven to be very difficult to enforce and is subject to significant evasion. 55 Indeed, as a general rule, the economic incidence of a tax (at least in the long run) is determined by market conditions, and not by whether the tax is legally imposed on the buyer or the seller. openness of the overall economy in terms of the inflows and outflows of capital investment, as well as on the extent to which capital moves between the corporate and unincorporated sectors, the relative capital-intensity of corporations, and the elasticity of demand for goods produced by corporations and other businesses. None of these factors is easy to measure, and neither is the incidence of the corporate income tax. Further, since differing economic conditions in different countries mean that taxes that have the same legal incidence may have a quite different economic incidence (Shah and Whalley, 1990), the specific characteristics of each country need to be taken into account when evaluating the economic incidence of each tax. Taking all these factors into account, what can be said about the role of income taxes in developing and transitional countries? First, as already noted, even if the only objective of such a country is economic growth, there is a clear case for a tax on corporate income, if only to collect a fair share of the revenue that multinational and large domestic businesses derive from economic activities in that country. It is of course true that by taxing corporations differently, and usually more heavily than other forms of business, governments tend to discourage, at least in principle, the operation of businesses in corporate form. Still, the fact that most major businesses all over the world operate in corporate form, despite the prevalence of corporate income taxes suggests that the corporation remains in general the best available vehicle for mobilizing large amounts of capital for business purposes. Since corporations are the engine of development in all modern societies, a tax on corporations is in effect a tax on the modern, growing sector of the economy.26 Countries need to tax that sector both to secure the revenue they need to meet expanding expenditure demands and also to ensure that those who benefit most from development pay their fair share. 27 But they must also ensure that corporate taxes are not so high as to discourage growth. In general, the best approach for developing or transitional countries is thus to 26 In many developing countries, the corporate sector may be quite small to begin with. Nonetheless, corporate taxes may have an importance beyond the revenue they yield. To the extent a corporate tax falls on foreign-based corporations, for example, it may provide a useful window to the way business is conducted in developed countries. 27 For example, Sudan is able to collect nearly five times more revenue from its corporate taxes than from its personal income tax. 56 impose a moderate, stable tax on all corporations. As for personal income taxes (as distinguished from general wage levies such as those imposed in many countries for social security purposes), their principal objective is presumably largely to mitigate at least to a moderate degree the inequalities in income and wealth that almost invariably accompany growth.28 As noted earlier, the recent report of the SecretaryGeneral correctly noted the desirability of expanding the base of consumption tax to encompass more services in part to reduce regressivity. Unfortunately, it has often proved exceedingly difficult to include many services, especially those consumed disproportionately by the rich, in the base of taxes such as the VAT, so some degree of progressivity in the personal income tax may also provide a useful offset to the likely regressive impact of the consumption taxes on which the revenue systems in most lower and middle-income countries depend. In such countries, for the most part personal income taxation should likely have a “threshold” – the level of income at which the tax begins to apply – well above average income levels.29 Moreover, to check tax avoidance, it would likely also be wise to keep the top marginal rate of the personal income tax fairly close to the rate of the corporate income tax. Both corporate and personal income taxes thus have a role to play in developing and transitional countries. In general, however, given the current economic context in most such countries, the most important revenue source in most transitional and developing countries is likely to be a broad-based value-added tax, as argued earlier. For these countries, income taxes are complementary taxes, to raise revenue from large business enterprises, especially foreign enterprises, and perhaps to place some check on the growth of income inequality. They cannot be expected to replace the revenue generated by a VAT. Indeed, some developing and transitional countries currently lack the administrative capacity to even attempt the implementation 28 Low-income countries collect 10.9 percent of revenues (17.1 percent of GDP) from a personal income tax; moderate-income countries raise 12.2 percent (2.44 percent of GDP), and high-income countries generate 31.3 percent (7.26 percent of GDP). 29 Sudan allows an annual threshold of USD864 per year, exceeding the earnings of many public sector employees. 57 But they must also ensure that corporate taxes are not so high as to discourage growth. In general, the best approach for developing or transitional countries is thus to impose a moderate, stable tax on all corporations of income taxes. More generally, it is important to pay close attention to the details of precisely how particular tax instruments work in particular environments. Some taxes that on the surface appear to be anti-growth and pro-redistribution (such as personal income taxes with highly progressive nominal rate structures) may, at times, have neither of these characteristics, whereas other taxes, such as the VAT, that may seem regressive may, compared to the alternatives, actually be mildly progressive (at least between lower and middle income groups). One cannot judge the effects of a tax by its name but only by close examination of the details of its design, by the way in which it is actually implemented, and by the characteristics of the country concerned. Thus, improving tax administration is central to the choice of tax structures and to improving taxation in developing and transitional countries. Tax Administration The best tax policy in the world is worth little if it cannot be implemented effectively. Tax policy design in developing and transitional countries must take the administrative dimension of taxation carefully into account. What can be done may to a considerable extent determines what is done in any country. In many developing countries, for example, there is a large traditional agricultural sector that is not easily taxed. In most transitional and developing countries, there is a significant informal (shadow) economy that also is largely outside the formal tax structure. The potentially reachable tax base thus constitutes a smaller portion of total economic activity than in developed countries. The extent of this untaxed economy is, of course, in part a function of tax policy itself. For example, the high social insurance tax rates levied in transition countries such as Croatia create an incentive for a large informal economy by discouraging employers from reporting the extent of employment and encouraging the under-reporting of wage levels.30 The resulting lower tax revenues often lead governments to raise tax rates, further exacerbating incentives to evade taxes. Unfortunately, all too often when a 30 A number of agencies in addition to the tax administration, such as social security administration and the customs administration and in some countries the financial police (for example, in the countries of the former Yugoslavia), are often involved in revenue administration. In Bosnia, for example, two-thirds of the revenue of the Entities (the main governmental level) is collected by the customs administration. 58 country’s real tax base is small, so, almost by definition, is the administrative capacity to reach it effectively. Thus, improving tax administration is central to the choice of tax structures and to improving taxation in developing and transitional countries. As noted earlier, the resources used in administering and complying with taxes - or, for that matter, evading them - imply real costs, in terms of the ability of the economy to provide goods and services. An essential aspect of good tax policy is to keep such costs as low as possible while at that the same time achieving revenue, economic growth, and distributional goals as effectively as possible. This is no small task. What needs to be done to improve tax administration is generally obvious, but seems seldom to be acted upon. In particular, three ingredients seem essential to effective tax administration: the political will to implement the tax system effectively, a clear strategy for achieving this goal and adequate resources for the task. It helps, of course, if the tax system is well designed, appropriate for the country in question, and relatively simple, but even the best designed tax system will not be properly implemented unless the three conditions just mentioned are fulfilled. Much attention is frequently and correctly paid to the resource problem - the need to have sufficient trained officials, adequate information technology and so on. In the absence of a sound implementation strategy, however, even adequate resources will not ensure success. And in the absence of sufficient political support, even the best strategy cannot be effectively implemented. As with tax policy, so also with tax administration: the most important two ingredients for successful reform are clear recognition at the highest political levels of the importance of the task and willingness to support reform. Unfortunately, very few developing or transitional countries have so far proved able to clear these initial hurdles with respect tax administration reform. More frequently, urged by international agencies or simply desperate for revenues, countries have launched frantic efforts to corral defaulters or to reach new taxpayers without hurting politically powerful interests and without providing the time, resources and consistent long term political support 59 In particular, three ingredients seem essential to effective tax administration: the political will to implement the tax system effectively, a clear strategy for achieving this goal and adequate resources for the task needed for effective tax administration. The widespread reluctance to collect taxes efficiently and effectively without fear or favour is understandable in countries which are often somewhat fragile politically. But there is no way to obtain a viable long-term tax system without major changes in this respect. If the political will exists, the techniques needed for effective tax administration are not a secret. The tax administration must be given an appropriate institutional form, which in some instances may mean a separate revenue authority. It must be adequately staffed with trained officials. It should be properly organized, which in most countries means on a functional rather than tax-by-tax basis.31 Computerization and appropriate use of modern information technology can help a lot, but technology alone cannot do the job and must in any case be carefully integrated into the tax administration. New computer systems have often developed parallel to the existing structure (in the Philippines, for example), but little gain can be derived from a system that does not recognize the skills and needs of tax officials. Only well-trained people, with adequate political support, can administer taxes effectively. Adequate provision must thus be made for training and retraining staff as needed. The information needed for effective administration must be collected from taxpayers, relevant third parties, and other government agencies; it must be stored in an accessible and useful fashion; and, most importantly, it must then be used to ensure that those who should be on the tax rolls, are, that those who should file returns, do, that those who should pay on time, do, and that those who do not comply are identified, prosecuted and punished as appropriate. None of this is easy, and little of it is simple, but it is not an impossible task. Countries such as Singapore are models of what can and should be done, and such models should be studied closely and, once adapted as necessary, implemented. The first task of any tax administration is to facilitate compliance, that is, to make sure that those who should be in the system are in the system and 31 Alternatively, organization by client groups may sometimes be sensible. But what is never sensible is to assign specific taxpayers to specific officials for prolonged periods of time, a practice still common in some countries. 60 that they comply with the rules. First, taxpayers must be found. They may be required to register: if so, registration must be made easy, and systems must be in place to identify those who do not register voluntarily. An appropriate unique taxpayer identification system must be established. Secondly, where appropriate, tax liabilities must be determined. This may be done administratively (as with most property taxes) or by some self-assessment procedure as with most income taxes and VATs).32 Thirdly, the taxes due must be collected. In many countries, this is best done through the banking system. It is seldom appropriate for tax administrations themselves to handle any money directly. Lastly, adequate service in the form of information, pamphlets, forms, advice agencies, payment facilities, telephone and electronic filing, and so on must be provided to taxpayers to make taxpayer compliance with the system as easy as possible. Underlying this approach is the view that in some sense the taxpayer is a client - not necessarily a willing one of course! - to be served, and not a thief to be caught. Unfortunately, the latter attitude seems to prevail in all too many developing and transitional economies. Of course, in no country are all taxpayers honest, and in some most may not be, so the second important task of any tax administration is to catch tax cheats. To do so, ideally the administration should have a good idea of the extent and nature of the potential tax base, for example, by estimating what is sometimes called the “tax gap.” At least a rough idea of the number and nature of those not caught by the tax system is needed in order to work out how best to bring them into the net. In some instances, the major problem may be that the authorities simply do not know many potential taxpayers. In others, 32 Globalization confronts tax administrations with some special problems, as discussed in chapter 4. For example, tax administrations must ensure that revenues and expenses are properly calculated in determining taxable profits for the corporate income tax, and that export credits and refunds are properly handled under the VAT. A number of transition countries (e.g. Ukraine) have failed to provide the rebates provided by the VAT legislation for exported goods. Taxpayers cannot be expected to respect tax laws when the government does not. 61 it may be that many taxpayers who are in the system are substantially underreporting their tax base. In still others (and perhaps most), both problems are important. Without some knowledge of the unreported base, and its determinants, no administration can properly allocate its resources to improving fiscal outcomes - whether through “sweeps” to find unregistered taxpayers or the generally more productive, if technically much more demanding, route of auditing. In addition to exploring the nature of the tax gap and undertaking the often difficult tasks involved in extending the reach of the tax system into the informal economy to the extent feasible, close attention must also be paid to the simple task of ensuring that those who are in the system file on time and pay the amounts due. Immediate follow-up of non-filers and those whose payments do not match their liabilities is an obvious but too often neglected aspect of good tax administration. Adequate interest charges must be imposed on late payments to ensure that non-payment of taxes does not become a cheap source of finance. Similarly, an adequate penalty structure is needed to ensure that those who should register do so, that those who should file do so, and that those who under-report their tax bases are sufficiently penalized to make the gamble of being caught too risky for most of them. As with much good advice, most of what has just been said is not only sensible but obvious. Nonetheless, it is worth saying again, since failure to follow such advice is astoundingly common. Enforcing a tax system is neither an easy nor a static task in any country. It is especially difficult in the changing conditions of developing and transitional countries. Unless this task is tackled with seriousness and consistency, however, even the best-designed tax system is unlikely to produce good results. No government can expect taxpayers to comply willingly if they consider the tax structure unfair or are unconvinced that the revenue collected is put to good use, but even a sound tax structure and sound expenditure policy can be vitiated by capricious and corrupt administration. A third major task is to keep the tax administration itself honest. No government can expect taxpayers to comply willingly if they consider the tax structure unfair or are unconvinced that the revenue collected is put to good use, but even a sound tax structure and sound expenditure policy can be vitiated by capricious and corrupt administration. It took the developed 62 countries centuries to develop and implement sound tax administration practices aimed at preventing dishonest tax officials from succumbing to obvious temptations. Unfortunately, most developing and transitional countries are currently attempting to sustain much larger governmental structures on precarious fiscal bases and do not have the luxury of centuries to solve such problems. They must do so now, if they are to survive. Tax officials must therefore be adequately compensated, so that they do not need to steal to live. They should be professionally trained, promoted on the basis of merit, and judged by their adherence to the strictest standards of legality and morality. They should have relatively little direct contact with taxpayers and even less discretion in deciding how to treat them. These statements are all clichés, no doubt, but they are clichés because they are true – and, unfortunately, still all too relevant in many developing and transitional countries. Improved domestic resource mobilization is an essential element of the stronger policy framework developing and transition countries need to have in place in order to be able to benefit from the opportunities afforded by globalization, rather than passively suffering the vicissitudes that may otherwise be inflicted on countries with weak governance and policy structures. Money alone will not ensure good governance; but it is necessary if that goal is to be attained. Similarly, good tax administration is not sufficient in itself, but it is necessary for effective and efficient domestic resource mobilization, and hence deserves the highest priority in any serious reform effort. The failure to develop good tax administration and good tax policy together has been a particular problem in some transitional countries. In Russia, for example, there were both serious problems with the structure of the VAT and with the lack of administrative experience and capacity. A simple example is that under the initial VAT legislation, no tax liability was due when loans were made from one business to another. Thus, a buyer would claim to have made a loan that was never repaid (and was in fact payment for 63 goods) to a supplier and no tax was due. The result was a significant loss of revenue. A more capable administration would have foiled this simple evasion technique, but better legislation was also needed. Even if policies are good, the way in which they are administered can yield very different outcomes than those intended. Administration that is seen as unfair and capricious may bring the tax system as a whole into disrepute. The initial failure of transitional countries to develop their tax administrations when introducing new tax structures resulted in very uneven tax imposition, lower than anticipated revenue, and widespread tax evasion. Similarly, in some developing countries, in practice corporate tax liabilities are often negotiated rather than calculated as set out in the law. Bribery is sometimes so common that it is considered a regular part of the compensation of tax officials. Such corruption undermines confidence in the tax system, negatively affects willingness to pay taxes, and reduces a country’s capacity to finance government expenditures. Finally, some have argued that improved tax administration alone can generate the revenues required to balance the budget or to meet guidelines set by the International Monetary Fund, or to finance tax policy changes that will narrow the tax base through concessions or lower tax rates. Although better tax administration will indeed generally enhance tax collection, increased revenue is not necessarily the only goal of improved administration, which is needed also to improve fairness, for example. Moreover, since improving administration takes time, any additional revenues may only accrue over a number of years. Cutting tax rates or granting additional concessions in the pious hope that improved administration will quickly make up any revenue losses is never a good idea. 64 Tax Reform No simple prescription for tax reform emerges from this brief and general review of some important issues in developing adequate systems for mobilizing domestic resources in developing and transitional countries. The precise nature and design of any reform will obviously differ from country to country, depending upon the relative importance of different policy goals, the characteristics of the economy, and the existing tax structure and administration. Whatever the country, however, tax reforms may take one of two general forms. These types of reform differ only in degree, but the distinction may be of some importance in understanding the political will necessary to undertake the reforms. First, reforms may be intended to correct design flaws in the tax structure. For example, profits may not be properly measured for the purpose of levying the corporate income tax, or taxable income for the personal income tax may exclude fringe benefits. Changes may be needed to correct such flaws or to deal with administrative difficulties. Such changes may be very technical in nature and not very visible to many taxpayers, but may nonetheless be important in achieving public policy goals. Second, much more basic reforms may be attempted – for example, a major change in the choice of taxes. For example, until recently many countries levied turnover sales taxes, under which every transaction was taxed. Such taxes may sometimes produce considerable revenue at relatively low rates, but they also have some undesirable effects in economic terms.33 They affect both production and consumption choices, often in unintended ways. They encourage firms to integrate vertically solely to reduce taxes, and they lead to very differential burdens on final products, depending upon how many stages of production (tax points) they pass through. For these reasons, among others, many countries have chosen to shift from turnover taxes to value added taxes. Countries make such basic reforms only infrequently, however, and often only after considerable economic and sometimes political 33 General taxes on financial transactions, such as that in Brazil, have similarly undesirable characteristics. 65 Cutting tax rates or granting additional concessions in the pious hope that improved administration will quickly make up any revenue losses is never a good idea. difficulties.34 Of course, even major reforms can sometimes be done gradually. For example, Colombia adopted a sales tax with a value-added feature in 1966 and then moved to a full VAT in 1974. Alternatively, reform can be done all at once, in what has been called the “big bang” approach. Which approach to take was much discussed during the 1990s in the transitional countries of eastern and central Europe, which had inherited a tax system suitable only for a tightly centrally-planned economy. The “big bang” approach was essentially to adopt immediately a tax system similar to those used in many marketoriented, highly developed countries, notably those of the European Union. The “gradual” approach was to develop a reform plan tailored specifically for the country in question, and to move slowly from the existing structure to the desired system. A major problem with the big bang approach is that the necessary institutional structures to operate a modern tax system effectively may not be in place. Two obvious problems in most transitional countries, for example, were the inadequacy of accounting systems and the weakness of tax administration. A more gradual approach allows time for the accounting infrastructure of modern taxation and the tax administration to be developed. On the other hand, a gradual approach often presents significant political problems. The long time lapse between conceptualization of the tax structure and its final implementation gives reform opponents continuing opportunities to prevent the entire set of reforms from ever being undertaken. Also, a gradual approach entails continued uncertainty for taxpayers, and, as noted above, such uncertainty raise costs and reduces the willingness to invest. In the end, most transitional countries adopted more or less a full package of modern tax laws such as corporate and personal income taxes and value-added taxes. Some, such as Kazakhstan, adopted a complete new tax code. In others, like Ukraine, such a code was developed but never 34 For a useful discussion of major reforms in a number of developing countries, see Thirsk (1997). 66 implemented. Whether codified or not, most of the new tax laws adopted in transitional countries were, by normal standards, relatively sound in design. In many cases, however, political pressures that led to a proliferation of tax concessions soon weakened these laws. In others, continuing administrative problems significantly weakened the implementation of the new laws. Although the jury is still out on whether a gradual or a big bang approach to major tax reform is best, two lessons about the reform process may perhaps be drawn from both this recent experience in the transitional countries and more generally from experience with major reforms in developing countries generally. The first lesson is simply that, with respect to how to do it as well as what to do, each country faces its own unique problems and hence in the end will have to find its own unique solutions. The second, and more useful, lesson is that the dichotomy between doing reform “all at once” or in gradual stages is to a considerable extent a false dichotomy. In reality, tax reform is not an issue that can ever be resolved at once. Circumstances and ideas change, and policies change with them, so that to some extent, particularly in developing and transitional countries increasingly open to world influences, tax reform is likely to prove to be a continuous process, requiring constant vigilance and effort in order to ensure that fiscal instruments are used as effectively and efficiently as possible to achieve public policy objectives. A critical ingredient of a sound tax policy for any developing or transitional country is thus to develop some systemic and continuing institutional capacity to develop and adapt tax systems appropriately as the world changes. As emphasized in Chapter 5, this is one area in which improved international support and assistance may be of great use to many countries. 67 Circumstances and ideas change, and policies change with them, so that to some extent, particularly in developing and transitional countries increasingly open to world influences, tax reform is likely to prove to be a continuous process, requiring constant vigilance and effort in order to ensure that fiscal instruments are used as effectively and efficiently as possible to achieve public policy objectives. A critical ingredient of a sound tax policy for any developing or transitional country is thus to develop some systemic and continuing institutional capacity to develop and adapt tax systems appropriately as the world changes. Chapter 3 The Global Context The key problem is that globalization makes it more difficult for all countries, including developing and transitional countries, to pursue some of the traditional goals of tax policy because globalization potentially limits some choices available to countries. Every country today has to design its tax policy recognizing that it is a participant, willingly or unwillingly, in a global economy. The global economy provides important opportunities for increasing national wealth. However, it also makes countries vulnerable to international economic forces that are not always benign. This chapter discusses some of the risks and rewards of globalization, with respect to tax policy in developing and transitional countries. The key problem is that globalization makes it more difficult for all countries, including developing and transitional countries, to pursue some of the traditional goals of tax policy because globalization potentially limits some choices available to countries. The key solution is that, at least in principle, a country can regain some or all of the sovereign power to tax through mutual cooperation with other governments. Globalization and National Tax Sovereignty Taxation is one of the most important aspects of sovereignty. A government that cannot tax cannot function. A government that is limited in the way it can tax may be precluded from pursuing some societal goals. For example, if the wealthy cannot be effectively taxed because of their ability to avoid the tax through cross-border activities, a country’s ability to mitigate inequalities in wealth and income is obviously constrained. Globalization – the extension throughout the world of an economic system based on free markets for goods, services, and capital – tends to undermine a country’s power to tax. A tax is an involuntary exaction, paid only because the taxpayer is under a legal obligation that it cannot avoid. Cross-border trade and investment tend to increase the opportunities for taxpayers to avoid taxes, legally and illegally. In some instances, the increasing concentration of economic and political power in private (and 68 sometimes foreign) hands associated with globalization may also increasingly challenge the authority of national governments. Globalization has also brought many benefits to many countries. Over the past half-century, the market economy has shown itself to be vastly superior to alternative economic systems in satisfying material needs. The market economies in developed countries are far from the laissez faire capitalism of the nineteenth century, however. Western democracies, for example, typically regulate mergers, protect the rights of workers to organize into labor unions, and provide an economic safety net that protects citizens against the hardships of an economic recession. Some developing countries were initially slow to embrace globalization and the market economy that drives it, fearing some of the important social, political, environmental, and cultural changes that typically accompany globalization or that their economies were too weak to compete effectively in world markets. Nonetheless, recent events have pushed many developing countries towards globalization notwithstanding such fears. Many developing countries that embraced globalization experienced high levels of growth in the 1990s. On the other hand, the economic performance of those that eschewed the market was disappointing. Moreover, the dynamism of globalization at the end of the century was such that developing countries were being buffeted by market forces whatever their chosen development model. In significant measure, countries that had not freed markets to some extent were suffering the downside of globalization without enjoying the upside. One of the benefits that developing countries and economies in transition hope to obtain from participation in the global economy is an increase in foreign investment. Various resolutions of the General Assembly and the Economic and Social Council have asserted that foreign private capital flows and investment can play an important complementary role in the economic development process. The traditional benefits that a developing or 69 transitional country might obtained from direct foreign investment include the following: A transfer to the country of managerial and administrative expertise, technology, and other resources. The expansion of productive capacity and employment in the country The establishment of export markets for goods and services produced in the country. The development of local businesses to serve the needs of the foreign investor or to exploit the markets created by the foreign investor. The collection of tax revenue from the profits earned by the foreign investor from activities in the country. The creation by the foreign investor of an infrastructure that may promote further economic activities. Other possible benefits from joining the global economy are that the efficiency of domestic industries may improve in response to foreign competition, competition from foreign producers may lower domestic prices, consumers may enjoy a higher quality of goods and services, and the corruption that has too often accompanied public monopolies may be mitigated. Globalization thus brings with it many potential rewards. But it also entails risks, particularly because it imposes limits on the scope for independent national monetary policy (as investors can more freely move funds in and out of the country), and to some extent perhaps also on the ability (or the willingness) of governments to prevent anti-competitive mergers, to prevent the degradation of the environment, and to protect worker rights to unionize. Most relevantly in the present context, of course, globalization may impose constraints on tax policy, and particularly on tax policy intended in part to offset the concentration of income and power that often accompanies globalization. 70 Developing and transitional countries may feel, for example, that they must compete for investment capital by offering more and more generous tax incentives. However, any competitive advantage that a country gets from offering tax concessions will be short lived. Competing countries are likely soon to offer a comparable package of tax concessions. The result may be harmful tax competition among countries that ultimately may work to their collective disadvantage. In the end, the result may simply be that all countries in effect will lose the ability to tax the income generated from foreign investment – one of the “benefits” of such investment, as noted above -without experiencing any significant increase in investment flows. Not all tax competition need be harmful, of course. To the extent that international competition induces countries to impose better-designed and more stable tax structures, to administer them more honestly and uniformly, and to ensure that the revenues are more effectively utilized, it may be beneficial. Still, it is undeniable that tax competition may to some extent undermine attempts to impose redistributive taxes, because such taxes may result in increased capital outflows. Even some consumption tax policies – for example, high taxes on luxury goods – may be vitiated if people can easily purchase goods outside the country free of tax or subject to lower tax rates. In the end, the only way to deal with such undesired effects of tax competition is through some degree of increased international cooperation on tax matters. Such cooperation among countries on tax matters is certainly difficult, as the history summarized in Appendix B shows, but it is also, as shown there, not impossible, as discussed further in chapter 5. Developing and transitional countries have been both the practitioners and the victims of tax competition. In some cases, such countries have attempted to attract foreign investment by offering rich tax incentives to foreign corporations. In response, corporations have sometimes encouraged developing and transitional countries to engage in “incentive bidding wars.” Some developed countries have encouraged tax competition by offering taxsparing credits in their tax treaties, thereby making the incentives offered by 71 the OECD actions have already shown that concerted efforts by the major countries of the world can be effective in curtailing the use of offshore tax havens. developing countries more valuable. A few developing countries have adopted strict bank secrecy laws and other legal rules that facilitate international tax avoidance and evasion, and hence in effect invited the use of their country as a vehicle for international tax evasion. Recently, the OECD has begun a major initiative at curtailing the use of such offshore tax havens for evading taxes (OECD, 1998). This initiative has been controversial and has encountered organized opposition from some governments as well as from those in the business of promoting tax evasion and avoidance. While it remains unclear whether the international community is prepared to act on a sustained basis to control international tax evasion, the OECD actions have already shown that concerted efforts by the major countries of the world can be effective in curtailing the use of offshore tax havens. Most developing and transitional countries would benefit from effective international restraints on tax evasion, although a few such countries may lose. For such efforts to be truly beneficial, however, there should be no exceptions for certain types of cross-border tax evasion that are now facilitated by policies in some developed countries. It may also be necessary to provide some appropriate transitional assistance to permit existing “tax haven” countries to move their economies in new, more productive directions. Both theory and practice suggest, however, that in a market-driven economy any jobs and profits lost to imports in one business are more than made up for through expansion in other businesses, and any gains in jobs and profits derived from an artificial increase in exports are lost in other areas of the domestic economy Trade Taxes Freer trade is a central aspect of globalization and the market economy, and rightly so. As the Monterrey Consensus states (p. 7): A universal, rule-based, open, non-discriminatory and equitable multilateral trading system, as well as meaningful trade liberalization, can substantially stimulate development worldwide, benefiting countries at all stages of development. Opponents of free trade often contend that a relaxation of tariff barriers will make local businesses more vulnerable to foreign competition, resulting in lower domestic profits and fewer domestic jobs. The argument is essentially that national wealth is enhanced by policies that discourage imports and encourage exports. This mercantilist view has long been 72 discredited. It rests on the belief that jobs and profits lost to imports are permanent losses and that export subsidies produce permanent gains to an economy. Both theory and practice suggest, however, that in a market-driven economy any jobs and profits lost to imports in one business are more than made up for through expansion in other businesses, and any gains in jobs and profits derived from an artificial increase in exports are lost in other areas of the domestic economy. The market generally tends to direct labor and capital to their most efficient uses, so that free trade tends to make a country as whole richer, not poorer. Nonetheless, a cold dash of free trade can have negative short-term effects on a weak economy in which the necessary economic adjustments occur slowly. Many of the developing countries exposed to free trade in recent decades, after decades of protectionism, suffered badly in the short run. The likelihood that free trade will ultimately work for the economic betterment of the country may be little consolation to those suffering severe economic hardship in the short run or to political leaders who are thrown out of office as a result of popular discontent with the effects of their trade policies. As the Monterrey Consensus recognized, a country may be able to mitigate the adverse short-term effects of a relaxation of its barriers to imports by negotiating a reciprocal relaxation by other countries in their barriers to its exports. Many developing countries have some established export industries that could expand their production of goods and services significantly if foreign countries would eliminate their tariffs, quotas, and other trade barriers to the importation of those goods and services. Unfortunately, reciprocal trade agreements may be of limited utility to some least-developed countries that have no established export businesses other than the export of natural resources. For this reason, the Monterrey Consensus calls upon the developed countries to open their markets to the least-developed countries without requiring trade or other concessions in return. Generally, however, experience over more than a century has shown that purely bilateral trade arrangements are unsatisfactory, largely because 73 Generally, however, experience over more than a century has shown that purely bilateral trade arrangements are unsatisfactory, largely because cross-border trade is not purely bilateral. It is for that reason that the Monterrey consensus calls for an “equitable multilateral trading system.” cross-border trade is not purely bilateral. It is for that reason that the Monterrey consensus calls for an “equitable multilateral trading system.” The basic international system in place today is the trading regime managed by the World Trade Organization (WTO). The WTO has many virtues. Some have, however, characterized it as having functioned to date as essentially a trading club established by and managed largely for the benefit of developed countries. From the perspective of developing countries, it has largely treated their needs and interests as a secondary concern and excluded them from a meaningful say in its decision-making processes. In the words of the Zedillo Report (p.6): Despite its youth, WTO is in urgent need of reform and support in certain critical aspects. The necessary changes are unlikely to be achieved from within. What may be needed is a bigger political impulse, stemming from the construction of global economic governance. In that endeavour, at least the following aspects of WTO should be addressed: Its decision-making system, which many developing countries perceive, with reason, as selective and exclusionary; Its capacity to provide technical assistance to developing countries so they can participate more effectively in multilateral trade negotiations, trade opportunities and the dispute settlement mechanism; Attached to the latter, the evident underfunding and understaffing of WTO. Although the broader aspects of international trade policy are beyond the scope of this report, it is important to emphasize that one clear effect of the lower tariffs resulting from the WTO has been to lower tax revenues. Taxes on trade are particularly important in the poorest countries. A change in trade policy does not reduce the need for revenues in those countries. A critical problem of trade liberalization in many countries has thus been how to recoup from other sources the tax revenues lost from tariff reform. 74 In addition to the revenue lost directly from a reduction in tariffs, a developing country may also lose revenue indirectly, at least in the short run, depending on the impact of the cut in tariffs on domestic economic activity. On one hand, previously protected producers may lose market share to imports, thus reducing profits and profits taxes. On the other hand, domestic businesses may increase their exports, with potentially offsetting effects on revenues. Such effects are likely to be miniscule, however, compared with the direct impact on revenues of decreased trade taxes. As a rule, the options available in the most affected countries for increasing tax revenues are limited, due to administrative constraints, political constraints, or both. Import tariffs tend to be relatively easy for most developing countries to administer, and the administrative machinery to do so is already in place In general, the only viable solution is usually to impose a broad-based value-added tax, encompassing both imports and domestic products, or, if such a tax already exists, to increase its rates. Tax Treatment of Capital Flows The case for free trade in goods and services is strong under almost all economic conditions. Only countries that are incapable of participating effectively in the world economy are likely to benefit in the long run from restrictive trade policies. The benefits of freeing capital flows are not quite so clear, however, and the risks appear to be considerably greater. In particular, there can be serious risks associated with unrestricted movements of portfolio capital, as the global financial crisis of the late 1990s made clear. Developing countries are particularly susceptible to such risks. If a country such as Argentina loses the confidence of international money managers for some reason, it may find itself in a financial crisis, much like a bank that faces default as customers seek to withdraw their deposits all at the same time. Reflecting the new awareness of the risks accompanying unrestricted capital flows, the Monterrey Consensus (p. 6) states: “Measures that mitigate the impact of excessive volatility of short-term capital flows are important and 75 In general, efforts at restricting capital flows tend to be counterproductive because investors who believe they may lose access to their money in a crisis are likely to be particularly nervous whenever they fear that a crisis is brewing. must be considered.” The Zedillo Report is more explicit. It states: Without these flows [of portfolio capital], governments and the local private sector would not be able to reduce their cost of capital by tapping private foreign savings. It is for this reason that progressively more developing countries have been liberalizing their capital account in recent years. But this has proved to be a mixed blessing. Although the infusion of capital in good years was quite substantial, in all too many cases the boom years soon gave way to a bust, marked by currency or banking crises, or both. Countries with large foreign debts, particularly short-term debts and private sector debts denominated in foreign currencies, proved vulnerable to crises, as herds of investors fled in panic. As a result of this experience, considerable attention has been devoted to designing appropriate safeguards to ensure that the opening of capital markets in the developing countries is beneficial. It is not easy to do so. In general, efforts at restricting capital flows tend to be counterproductive because investors who believe they may lose access to their money in a crisis are likely to be particularly nervous whenever they fear that a crisis is brewing. The tried and true method for reassuring nervous investors is to make clear to them that their money is available whenever they want it. Unfortunately, the volume of highly mobile capital in some countries is so large that the pool of rescue capital needed to reassure the money managers may exceed the amounts available even to the IMF. What can developing countries do themselves to cope with these problems? In addition to more appropriate macroeconomic policies, more careful phasing in of financial liberalization, and better systems of regulating financial markets, the Zedillo Report (p. 47) suggests that: There may be occasions during capital surges when the introduction of temporary capital inflow taxes proves to be part of the least-bad policy mix. Chile, for example, avoided much of the economic turmoil that rocked More generally, a lesson from the financial crises of the late 1990s is that a country is less likely to be vulnerable to capital flight if its domestic tax system is functioning properly. Latin America, at least in part because of its policy of requiring domestic pension funds to invest much of their capital locally and its policy of taxing foreigners on the income earned in Chile on short-term bonds. More generally, a lesson from the financial crises of the late 1990s is that a country is less likely to be vulnerable to capital flight if its domestic tax system is functioning properly. Borrowing to pay the current expenses of 76 operating the government may be appropriate on occasion for short periods. As Russia and Argentina learned, however, recurrent recourse to this practice is generally a prescription for financial instability. A tax system that raises the money needed for current expanses obviously reduces this risk of instability. Moreover, the perceived ability of a government to raise and collect additional taxes in a crisis situation provides additional reassurance to nervous investors and makes it less likely that such additional taxes will be needed. In addition, given the risks associated with portfolio investment, it seems unwise for a developing country to attempt to stimulate such investment by offering tax incentives to foreign lenders. At the same time, however, there is no reason for tax policy explicitly to discourage such investment. In general, therefore, developing countries should attempt to tax income from portfolio investments, whether earned by foreigners or domestic investors at reasonable tax rates. Countries that tax income from portfolio investments invariably utilize a withholding tax mechanism. Withholding is facilitated if it is applicable without distinction to both domestic and foreign investors. In contrast to portfolio investment, as noted earlier, many think that foreign direct investment (FDI) is largely beneficial. During the 1990s, the amount of FDI going to developing and emerging countries increased markedly, as shown in the table below. It has declined some at the start of the new century, presumably due primarily to an economic slowdown in many countries, including some of the largest economies. Increases in FDI were substantial until the financial crises of the late 1990s and seem to have rebounded well after the recovery (see Table 1). Short-term capital flows dropped sharply in the late 1990s, and their failure to recover probably reflects investor caution after the substantial losses that some investors suffered. [insert Text Table 1] 77 Table 1: Taxes as a Share of GDP With and Without Social Insurance Payments With Without With Social Social Social Social Insurance Insurance Insurance Insurance Payments Payments Payments Payments Africa Without Africa Algeria 39.0 39.0 Kenya 23.3 23.3 Benin 12.7 12.7 Lesotho 27.8 27.8 Botswana 32.5 32.5 Liberia n.a. n.a. Burkina Faso 14.1 14.1 Madagascar 11.3 11.3 Burundi 16.9 15.8 Malawi 14.2 14.2 Cameron 14.5 14.5 Mali 12.9 12.9 Cape Verde 18.7 18.7 Mauritania 15.7 15.7 Central African Rep. 6.1 6.1 Mauritius 17.9 16.9 Chad 6.5 6.5 Morocco 21.5 21.5 Comoros 10.4 10.4 Mozambique 11.4 11.2 .Congo (Dem. Rep.) 42.1 42.1 Nambia 27.6 27.6 Congo (Rep. Of) 26.3 26.3 Niger Cote d'Ivoire 18.0 16.4 Nigeria Djibouti 24.5 24.5 Rwanda 9.3 9.3 Equatorial Guinea 16.3 16.3 Sao Tome & Pri 13.0 13.0 Eritrea 19.5 19.5 Senegal 16.0 16.0 Ethiopia 12.9 12.9 Seychelles 35.8 28.2 Gabon 32.8 32.8 South Africa 22.3 21.8 Gambia 15.9 15.9 Sudan 57.2 57.2 Ghana 15.8 15.8 Swaziland 26.3 26.3 Guinea 10.5 10.5 Tanzania 9.6 9.6 9.3 9.3 Guinea-Bissau 7.9 7.9 15.2 15.2 With Without With Social Social Social Social Insurance Insurance Insurance Insurance Payments Payments Payments Payments Europe Without Europe Albania 19.3 15.6 Latvia 25.0 13.6 Austria 37.5 20.4 Lithuania 30.6 21.3 Belarus 40.9 31.9 Luxembourg 42.1 30.4 Belgium 31.0 16.5 Macedonia 32.1 21.7 Bosnia 29.7 29.7 Malta 27.2 20.8 Bulgaria 26.9 19.3 Moldova 22.1 16.4 Croatia 29.3 29.3 Netherlands 63.1 48.9 Czech Republic 31.7 17.3 Norway 34.5 25.0 78 Denmark 49.8 48.3 Poland 29.9 19.4 Estonia 35.4 23.2 Portugal 32.5 21.4 Finland 35.4 22.1 Romania 30.4 21.7 France 45.2 26.8 San Marino Georgia 11.8 11.8 Germany 26.3 Greece 36.9 Hungary Iceland n.a. n.a. Slovak 32.1 19.7 11.0 Slovenia 39.4 25.8 25.8 Spain 33.5 21.8 35.6 22.0 Sweden 51.2 51.2 25.7 25.7 Switzerland 22.0 9.5 Ireland 30.6 26.5 Ukraine 34.3 34.3 Italy 44.2 29.4 United King. 32.9 26.9 With Without With Social Social Social Social Insurance Insurance Insurance Insurance Payments Payments Payments Payments Asia Without Asia Armenia 14.3 14.3 Singapore 14.2 14.2 Azerbaijan Rep. 15.5 12.9 Sri Lanka 15.0 15.0 7.0 7.0 Tajikistan 12.5 11.0 Thailand 14.4 14.1 Turkey 24.8 20.6 Turkmenistan 16.2 11.1 United Arab Em. 24.3 24.3 Bangladesh Bhutan 6.8 6.8 Brunei 19.5 19.5 8.3 8.3 25.7 21.1 Hong Kong 9.2 9.2 Uzbekistan 29.4 29.4 India 8.1 8.1 Vietnam 14.9 14.9 Indonesia 13.3 12.9 Yemen 25.8 25.8 Iran 11.8 9.7 Israel 35.8 29.9 Japan 27.9 17.6 Oceania Kazakhstan 20.2 16.4 Australia 23 23 Korea 17.6 15.3 Fiji 21.4 21.4 Kyrgyz Rep. 12.3 12.3 Marshall Is. 19.7 19.7 7.2 7.2 Micronesia 3.7 3.7 Macao 14.6 14.6 New Zealand 31.2 31.2 Malaysia 16.0 16.0 Palau 14.7 14.7 Mongolia 18.9 15.7 Papua N. Guinea 20.9 20.9 Myannar 2.1 2.1 Samoa 22.2 22.2 Nepal 8.7 8.7 Solomon 18.1 18.1 Pakistan 12.2 12.2 Tonga 17.6 17.6 Philippines 15.6 15.6 Vanuatu 21.5 21.5 Russian Fed. 27.9 19.7 Cambodia Cyprus Lao 79 With Without With Social Social Social Social Insurance Insurance Insurance Insurance Payments Payments Payments Payments North America Without South America Antigua & Barbuda 17.2 17.2 Argentina 17.5 17.5 Aruba 17.7 17.7 Bolivia 21.2 18.9 Bahamas 17.7 17.7 Brazil 19.6 14.5 Barbados 30.3 29.3 Chile 15.9 15.9 Belize 18.9 18.9 Colombia 17.4 17.4 Canada 20.3 15.3 Ecuador 20.1 15 Costa Rica 17.4 12.1 Guyana 27.2 27.2 Dominica 24.8 24.8 Paraguay 13 13 Dominican Rep. 15.3 14.7 Peru 12.5 12.5 El Salvador 10.3 10.3 Uruguay 16.7 16.7 Grenada 23.2 23.2 Venezuela 17.3 17.3 8.8 8.8 Guatemala Haiti Honduras 7 7 15.8 15.8 The surprising numbers in Table 1 are those on capital outflows. While the estimation of these numbers is particularly difficult, it appears that outflows from developing countries grew so dramatically throughout the 1990s that by 2000 outflows actually exceeded inflows. One depressing explanation of this marked trend may be (as the World Bank has noted) an increase in tax fraud, as some owners of capital resident in a developing country export their capital and then repatriate it in order to benefit from tax incentives supposedly reserved for foreign investment. Some such “roundtrip” investment may be registered as an inflow but is not registered as an outflow, appearing as an error or omission instead. Despite such problems, most developing and transitional countries remain eager to attract more FDI. In the past, some developing countries were quite selective in the types of FDI they sought to attract. Investors were required to seek the approval of an investment authority, which was disinclined to give approval unless the proposed investment fit within the country’s development plans. A proposed investment might be rejected for a variety of reasons, including that it threatened local control over natural 80 resources, that it was likely to promote frivolous consumption, that it was expected to draw local capital from projects that were considered more important. This planning approach to FDI is now out of favor, for two good reasons. It rarely worked well, and it often bred corruption. The current approach of most countries is instead to let market forces determine what is or is not a good investment, subject only to limitations for criminal or socially undesirable investments. This market approach is inevitable if countries wish to participate fully in the global economy in which firms, not countries, make investment decisions. The Zedillo Report suggests that countries should treat foreign investors as well as they treat their domestic investors, giving them what is commonly called “national treatment.” They should not, however, be given special treatment. According to the report, “foreign investors should not be exempted from domestic laws governing corporate and individual behaviour, nor should the authority of domestic courts, tribunals, and regulatory authorities over foreign investors and their enterprises be curtailed.” More importantly, foreign investors should be required to pay their fair share of the tax burden. As the Zedillo report says, the wrong way to attract FDI “is to hand out tax concessions or erode domestic social or environmental standards in a race to the bottom.” Emerging Issues in Cross-Border Taxation The discussion to this point suggests that globalization has several general implications for tax policy in developing and transitional countries. First, trade tax revenues clearly need to be replaced, generally by some form of broad-based tax on domestic consumption. Second, the importance of having in place an adequate and sustainable system to mobilize resources for public purposes is accentuated by the increased need to deal with adjustments in production structure resulting from trade liberalization. Third, the increased inequality in income and wealth often accompanying globalization may similarly accentuate the political and social need for some degree of fiscal correction – a task, however, that may prove increasingly difficult in the 81 The current approach of most countries is instead to let market forces determine what is not a good investment. absence of increased international cooperation to check cross-border evasion. Fourth, there may perhaps be a (minor) role for some form of tax (or tax-like) restriction on the volatility of short-term capital flows, and in any case countries should impose similar withholding taxes on payments from firms to portfolio investors, whether at home or abroad. Fifth, countries should in general not give special tax concessions to foreign investors. And finally, countries will increasingly need to develop policies and administrative skills to deal with complex international investment transactions – again, a task that may in many instances require international cooperation and support, as discussed in chapter 5. In addition, developing and transitional countries, like all countries, face several new and troublesome problems in enforcing taxes in a world in which national borders represent little barrier to commerce. Two such problems are discussed briefly in this section – the taxation of electronic commerce and the taxation of new financial instruments. Taxing electronic commerce Electronic commerce, or e-commerce, is commerce conducted over the Internet, a loose network of computers and computer networks that spans the globe. Such commerce gives rise to problems for both sales and income taxes, but only the latter is discussed here. As a rule, most countries tax foreigners on income derived from e-commerce under the same rules applicable to income derived from other types of activities. Every country requires a foreign taxpayer to have some minimum link to it before it imposes its income tax. In taxing the income of a foreign person from e-commerce, a country must therefore decide whether that person’s electronic presence is sufficient to establish the minimum link required for taxation. Most countries also have tax treaties that limit their ability to tax the residents of their treaty partners. In general, business income, including income from e-commerce, is taxable only if the foreign taxpayer entitled to treaty benefits has a permanent establishment (PE) in the taxing country. To constitute a PE, a taxpayer must have an office or other fixed place of 82 business in that country, and the activities of that fixed place of business must go beyond certain exploratory or auxiliary activities that enjoy exempt status under the typical tax treaty. Issues arise as to whether various e-commerce activities in a country constitute a fixed place of business for treaty purposes and, if they do, whether they are within the scope of the exemptions for auxiliary activities. Those issues have been addressed by the OECD with respect to the following activities: Engaging in e-commerce through a web site. Using computer equipment, such as a server, to store or provide access to electronic files or otherwise to assist a taxpayer in conducting its business operations. Using an agent, such as an independent service provider (ISP), to obtain access to the Internet or to host a web site. The nature of the problem, and the way in which countries are approaching it can be illustrated by considering briefly the first of these – the web site issue. Under tax treaties based on the UN or OECD model (see Appendix B), a foreign taxpayer having a PE in a country is taxable on that portion of its business income that is attributable to the PE. If a taxpayer’s web site is treated as a PE, then the sales income derived from sales made through that web site would by attributable to the PE. If a taxpayer’s server or other computer equipment is held to constitute a PE, then that portion of the profits attributable to the operations of the server would be taxable. A web site that appears on computer screens located in a country allows a foreign enterprise to interact with customers in ways that are strongly analogous to the interactions that typically occur through a bricks-and-mortar office. Indeed, a fully-functioning web site is sometimes referred to as a “virtual office.” The tax question is whether such a virtual office constitutes an office or other fixed place of business for purposes of the PE rule in a tax treaty. Potential customers can log onto the remote seller's web site, select products 83 for purchase from an online catalogue, and consummate the sale online by filling out a form and charging the purchase to their personal credit card. If these electronic sales are viewed as made through a PE, the electronic sales are taxable in the source country. If a virtual office is not treated as an "office or other fixed place of business," however, the income derived from the electronic sales will escape taxation in the source country (and may, for that matter, escape taxation elsewhere as well). The OECD (Commentary on Article 5 of the model treaty, as amended in 2000) takes the position that a web site cannot constitute a PE since a PE requires a “physical presence” in a country and a web site is intangible and not physical.1. Along the same line, the OECD’s view is that the computer equipment must be “fixed” at some location to constitute a PE, and that the hosting of the web site typically would not cause the ISP to be a PE of its principal. With minor exceptions, the OECD approach to e-commerce is to assign jurisdiction to tax to the residence country and to deny the source country the right to tax. This position is inimical to the interests of developing and transitional countries, because those countries are much more likely to be the source country than the residence country with respect to e-commerce. In the short term, the income taxation of e-commerce is not an issue of great revenue significance for most developing or transitional countries (although the situation in some of the latter may change soon with their impending accession to the European Union). As yet, few such countries have much ecommerce. The e-commerce that exists, however, is mostly business to business (B2B) commerce, which is far easier to tax than business to consumer (B2C) e-commerce, partly because businesses typically keep books of account and partly because the number of businesses is small relative to the number of consumers. In the longer term, e-commerce is quite possibly going to be an important revenue matter for many developing and transitional countries. The growth of e-commerce over the past decade in some developed 1 Two OECD countries, Portugal and Spain, have registered their disagreement with this physical presence requirement. 84 countries has been impressive and seems likely to extend to additional countries in the near future. Obviously, developing appropriate rules for taxing e-commerce is no easy task. The appeal of residence taxation is that taxation at source is difficult, due to the lack of a traditional place of business in the source state. Residence taxation is also hard, however. Some mix of source and residence taxation is probably the best approach from the perspective of tax enforcement. As with taxing cross-border transactions more generally, in the long run it will be important not only for developing and transitional countries to develop the capacity to deal with such problems but, equally or more important, as discussed in Chapter 5, the ability to take a full part in developing international approaches to such universal issues. New Financial Instruments Beginning in the 1980s, financial institutions developed and marketed a wide array of what are popularly referred to as "new financial instruments." Many of these instruments were developed to manage risk and to generate fees for their makers. Over time, however, they have come to be used for a wide variety of additional purposes, including international tax avoidance. Hundreds of different types of new financial instruments are now traded regularly on various over-the-counter markets. Many others have been tailored to achieve specific objectives of particular customers. The annual sales of new financial instruments in the over-the-counter markets are measured in trillions of US dollars. Estimates of the worldwide volume of sales of all types of new financial instruments are unreliable because many of the sales are private and unreported. It is safe to say, however, that the volume of sales is very large and has been growing very rapidly for over a decade. One important category of new financial instruments is the derivative instrument. In very general terms, a derivative instrument is a contract that grants the holder certain rights and imposes certain obligations, with those rights and obligations determined by reference to the features of some other 85 asset (or collection of assets), such as corn, or a price index, or any other reference item, such as average rainfall, that can be quantified and is likely to change over time. The term "derivative" is used because typically the value of the instrument is derived from a change over time in the value of the other asset or the amount of the other reference item. More generally, the derivative instrument increases in value if the rights provided under the contract become more valuable over the term of the contract than the obligations imposed by that contract. An important, though relatively simple, type of derivative is the futures contract. A futures contract is a financial instrument that is traded on an organized futures exchange. Performance under the contract is guaranteed by the exchange. The London International Financial Futures and Options Exchange (LIFFE) and the Chicago Mercantile Exchange (CME) are two prominent exchanges that manage the market for a wide variety of futures contracts. The volume of trades on these exchanges is large and growing. For example, more than 411 million contracts were traded on the CME in 2001, up by over 78 percent from the CME's previous record year of 2000. The underlying value of transactions on the CME in 2001 represented US $294 trillion. On the LIFFE, a record 216 million contracts with an underlying value of UK £154 trillion were traded in 2001. As a point of comparison, the gross domestic product of the United States for 2000 was around US $10 trillion. The typical commodity futures contract entitles the holder to receive some specified asset, such as corn or gold, on a specified future date in exchange for a cash payment. That contract is entered into under procedures established by the commodity futures exchange, and the exchange guarantees performance of the contract. The person offering to deliver the specified asset on the delivery date is characterized as the seller of the futures contract. The person agreeing to make the cash payment in exchange for the promise of delivery is characterized as the buyer of the futures contract. A person buying or selling a futures contract on an exchange is required to pay a fee to the exchange for its services. In general, transactions costs on futures exchanges 86 are relatively low (Box 7). Box 7 — Futures Contracts For a highly stylized example of the operation of a futures market, assume that WCo, a gold watch producer, wishes to protect itself against a rise in the price of gold. In May, it opens an account with a gold futures exchange and gives its account manager instructions to acquire a contract giving it the right to receive 100 troy ounces of gold in December of the current year at the current market price for gold (the spot price) adjusted for any applicable financing charges. Another participant in the gold futures market is GCo. GCo is a producer of gold and is concerned that the price of gold will decline before it is able to extract the gold from its mine and bring it to market in December. It is anxious, therefore, to enter into a contract agreeing to deliver gold in December that would lock in at the current market price for gold. GCo opens an account at the gold futures exchange and instructs its account manager to arrange a contract to sell 100 troy ounces of gold for delivery in December. Both of the account managers do as instructed, and WCo ends up with a contract that entitles it to receive the gold and GCo ends up with a contract entitling it to receive the agreed payment. Under these circumstances, GCo is said to have sold a gold futures contract and WCo is said to have purchased a gold futures contract. Most persons obligated by a futures contracts to make delivery of the asset covered by the contract do not actually make that delivery. Instead, they make a cash settlement, paying an amount equal to their financial loss on their futures contract or receiving an amount equal to their financial gain. The settlement typically would reflect the difference between the spot price for the asset at the time the contract was made and the market price for that asset at the time of settlement. On the typical commodity futures exchange, over 95 percent of participants make cash settlements of their futures contract rather than take or make delivery of the asset covered by the contract. Derivatives and other new financial instruments are important mechanisms for managing risk. Managing risk is an economically useful activity and should not be discouraged by inappropriate tax policies. Nonetheless, the increasingly widespread use of such instruments has 87 potentially serious tax implications. It has proven very difficult in developed countries to develop tax rules that can adequately cope with the enormous flexibility of forms that transactions using financial instruments can take. In many ways, the simplest approach – though still one with many conceptual and practical difficulties -- is a “mark-to-market” approach with consistent timing, treating gains and losses on derivatives as realized in the year they accrued, but this system is obviously hard to use in developing and transitional countries with few or no organized trading exchanges. The alternative approach of reporting gains and losses on a realization basis is simpler in many ways, but it is also more open to abuse. Unless prevented, astute tax planners can use wellstructured financial instruments to hollow out an income tax completely – for example, to shift ownership rights, to convert dividends into deductible interest payments, to change the source of income, to move gains offshore, and to bring losses onshore. Unless prevented, astute tax planners can use well-structured financial instruments to hollow out an income tax completely – for example, to shift ownership rights, to convert dividends into deductible interest payments, to change the source of income, to move gains offshore, and to bring losses onshore. The problem is how to retain the obvious benefits in terms of better risk management while at the same time defending the tax base. One possible approach may perhaps be to require taxpayers to identify the purpose of financial instruments at the time they are entered into, thus providing certainty and the opportunity for fully hedging risks while at the same time eliminating many forms of potential abuse (through so-called “tax straddles” such as those listed above, which essentially turn one thing in reality into another thing on paper). Although this approach is not without its problems (and costs), it may perhaps offer a way in which developing and transitional countries can reap some of the benefits of financial innovation while escaping at least the more egregious fiscal costs. 88 Chapter 4 The Need for International Cooperation Over the past century, international cooperation on income tax matters has occurred primarily through the process of developing model tax conventions (see Appendix B). Tax treaties, however, are just one of many possible ways that countries can cooperate on tax matters. Indeed, much of the useful work of the OECD over the past two decades has been in devising technical solutions to international tax problems outside the treaty context. Its work on tax treaties was its entrée into the realm of international taxation. It has become a policy forum to discuss, agree on, and promote various proposals relating to international taxation. Unfortunately, it is a forum that is inevitably largely driven by the agendas of the developed countries. Developing and transitional countries have an important interest in promoting cooperation among the countries of the world on international tax matters. Such cooperation provides them with an important way to offset some of the loss of sovereign power to tax that accompanies globalization. It may also provide them with a better chance to deal more effectively with problems such as international tax evasion, transfer price abuses, and capital flight. To promote cooperative action, the developing countries need the support of an international institution that is responsive to their concerns. The Report of the Secretary-General to the Preparatory Committee for the High-level International Intergovernmental Event on Financing for Development, dated 12-23 February 2001, recommended the establishment of a global tax organization. The relevant portion of that report is set forth below: There is a growing need to improve arrangements for cooperation between national tax authorities. Increasing international economic and financial interdependence is 89 constraining national capacity to set and enforce various tax instruments. Governments are increasingly limited by international competition in both the forms of tax and the tax rates they can apply. Improved international cooperation between taxing authorities would serve, inter alia, to reduce opportunities for tax evasion and avoidance, contribute to mitigating the capital-flow instability to which developing countries are sometimes subject, and deploy tax incentives and disincentives in support of public goods, such as avoiding depletion of the global commons. The achievement of these goals requires major improvements in international cooperation on taxation matters. Forums exist in limited membership organizations to treat these issues from the viewpoints of their members, in particular OECD. In addition, taxation is addressed at the level of experts in United Nations forums, notably the Ad Hoc Group of Experts on International Cooperation in Tax Matters and certain expert groups on accounting and other related matters that are convened by UNCTAD. But, although OECD, for instance, has undertaken a number of outreach activities with non-member countries, there is today no global intergovernmental forum that considers tax questions on an ongoing basis or that can adequately put the tax debate in a wider — including a developmental — context. To fill this gap, an international organization for cooperation in tax matters could merge the various international tax-related efforts into a single entity. Such a broad-based international organization could provide a global forum for the discussion of and cooperation in tax matters, including the sharing of national taxation experiences; the development of definitions, standards and norms for tax policy, administration and related matters; the identification of national tax trends and problems; tax reporting; and the provision of technical assistance to national tax authorities, particularly those of developing and transition economy countries. Other less ambitious proposals have also been put forward, including the strengthening of the Ad Hoc Group of Experts on International Cooperation in Tax Matters. Subsequently, the High-level Panel on Financing for Development (the “Zedillo Report”) recommended that the international community consider the 90 establishment of a world tax organization that would perform various functions of importance to developing countries. According to the Zedillo Report, such a new international tax body should “take a lead role in restraining the tax competition designed to attract multinationals — competition that . . . often results in the lion’s share of the benefits of [foreign direct investment] accruing to the foreign investor.” Another long-term task for the new body would be to develop a system of “unitary taxation of multinationals” as a replacement for the arm’s length-separate entity approach favored by the OECD. In contrast, the Monterrey Consensus document, published at the conclusion of the International Conference on Financing for Development, put forth only the following recommendation for action: Strengthen international tax cooperation, through enhanced dialogue among national tax authorities and greater coordination of the work of the concerned multinational bodies and relevant regional organizations, giving special attention to the needs of developing countries and countries with economies in transition. The idea of any sort of comprehensive international tax organization (ITO) thus seems to be off the agenda for the time being. Nonetheless, the Zedillo Report is certainly correct in its assertion that the existing institutional arrangements for dealing with international tax matters are unsatisfactory from the perspective of the developing and transitional countries. So the question seems to be, what can be done short of an ITO? At the minimum, to be able to cope with the great fiscal pressures facing them both domestically and in the global context, developing and transitional countries appear to need some sort of center on international taxation that had competent and adequate staffing and that is responsive to their agendas. A possibly promising approach may be to build upon the existing program already in place in the United Nations, namely the Ad Hoc Group of Experts on International Cooperation in Tax Matters. That body has done important work over the past two decades in developing and promoting the UN model convention. It has also conducted a few workshops to assist in 91 At the minimum, to be able to cope with the great fiscal pressures facing them both domestically and in the global context, developing and transitional countries appear to need some sort of center on international taxation that had competent and adequate staffing and that is responsive to their agendas. the training of tax officials in developing countries. It is woefully underfunded, however, and does not have the institutional structure necessary to project and defend its work adequately in the international context. Significant restructuring would be needed for it to serve the needs of developing and transitional countries for assistance on international tax matters. Should a revitalized UN center for international taxation be created, it should have a small staff of full-time tax professionals, ideally drawn from the accounting, economics, and legal professions. It should also have adequate support staff to allow it to do its job properly and to stage conferences and workshops, as well as an adequate travel budget for meetings of representatives of developing countries and to permit center professionals to represent the developing countries at conferences and other activities sponsored by the OECD and other international organizations involved in international tax matters. The center need not be large. A half dozen tax professionals plus a support staff and a director should be enough. What is important is competence, not size. The main focus of the Ad Hoc Group has been on tax treaties. The suggested center should expand the focus, just as the OECD has expanded its focus over the past decade beyond the treaty area. The center should of course cooperate with other international tax organizations whenever possible. The OECD, the World Bank, and the International Monetary Fund are not enemies of the developing and emerging countries. Within the limits of their tasks and institutional structure, they have sought to advance various goals of importance to many developing and emerging countries and have done much to help such countries to deal with the serious fiscal problems they confront. Nonetheless, these organizations do not necessarily always focus on the problems of greatest concern to developing and transitional countries in the international tax area. As currently constituted, the Ad Hoc Group of Experts on International Cooperation in Tax Matters has 10 members from developed 92 countries and 15 members from developing and emerging countries. The developed countries were initially included in the Ad Hoc Group to provide some technical assistance and to ensure that recommendations of the group would have some realistic hope of being incorporated into tax treaties between developed and developing countries. For purposes of drafting the initial UN model convention, this arrangement appears to have worked quite well. In recent years, however, the arrangement has become less satisfactory. Many developed countries have appointed members to the Ad Hoc Group who also serve as representatives to the OECD. Understandably, perhaps, such representatives are sometimes inclined to promote the position of the OECD within the Ad Hoc Group, even when that position seems inimical to the interests of the developing countries. One way to reduce such problems might be to give representatives from developed countries the status of observers. Another might be to adopt some alternative system for selecting representatives from developed countries. For example, the representative might be appointed by the United Nations rather than by the developed countries themselves. Such institutional matters will obviously require much more thought, and discussion, before they can be resolved. But what seems undeniable is that if the developing and transitional countries as a group are to be able to mobilize domestic resources effectively in the world in which we now live, their voice will have to be more effectively heard in international tax matters than it now is. 93 Chapter 5 Recommendations for Good Tax Policy in Today’s Global Economy Globalization limits the sovereign power of countries to tax as it opens national borders to greater flows of goods, services, and financial capital. Recent technological advances, including digitization, high speed computers, the Internet and others, have facilitated globalization and created an additional set of limitations on government by lowering transaction and transportation costs and making it more difficult to track economic, financial, and legal behaviours. Nonetheless, the effects of globalization and technological changes have not been to alter the basic parameters of good taxation, which are much as they have been. These forces, however, have raised the penalties for bad tax policy and have increased the rewards for good policy. The reason is simple — the incentives created by taxation cause stronger and more rapid responses than ever before, as these same forces allow taxpayers, investors, and businesses to react to tax differentials and other incentives at lower cost and with greater flexibility. Cooperative arrangements among countries, including greater harmonization of taxes and greater assistance is assessment and collection, can lessen these incentives and can limit the capacity of taxpayers to avoid and evade taxes. Nevertheless, inducements for a small number of countries to cheat or not participate in such cooperative arrangements are always present and are rising with globalization and with the introduction of new technologies for international communication. As is abundantly clear from the discussion throughout the prior chapters, no single tax structure can serve the needs of every country. Globalization has not changed this basic fact of life. The appropriate tax system for every country depends, among other factors, on its economic structure, capacity to administer taxes, public service needs, government 94 structure and, perhaps most of all, to the weights attached to the different goals of taxation. Thus, differences should be anticipated in the specific elements of each nation’s tax structure. Countries also can be expected to vary their level of taxation – data analysis provided here suggests that a lower bound exists in the tax ratio used by countries if they are to finance the most essential public services. Beyond this minimum, most countries have considerable capacity to alter the level of taxation to meet differing local demands for public services and desires for redistribution, as illustrated by the wide variation in actual tax practices among countries at comparable levels of development. Countries must accommodate their differing goals and views towards taxation within a series of guidelines and general principles that arise from economic forces, legal constraints, globalization, and other factors if the undesirably, sometimes perverse, consequences of taxation are to be kept to a minimum and if government is to be adequately financed. Specific conclusions on the best forms of taxation are summarized in the remainder of this chapter. Further discussion on each of these points can be found in the prior chapters. Consumption tax bases, including the value added tax base, should be structured as broadly as possible, while recognizing that factors such as administrative capacity impose certain limitations on what can be taxed. Broader tax structures limit the distorting effects of taxation on choices (such as what and how much to purchase and whether to work) and the incentives on where and what to produce. Broader tax bases permit tax rates to be held lower for any given amount of tax revenue that is to be generated, and lower rates further lessen the perverse incentives created by taxation. Other benefits resulting from broader tax bases include that they normally result in a higher revenue growth rate and usually allow for less regressive consumption tax structures. Countries must set tax policy in light of limitations on their ability to administer taxes on certain segments of the economy. However, many of the 95 constraints on the use of broader-based taxes can be modified by the government (endogenous factors). For example, the government can engage in better fiscal planning, it can improved the quality of its tax legislation, and it can take constructive steps to development the tax administration. Excise taxes frequently serve as an important source of tax revenue for the least developed countries — a revenue source that is not easily replaced. As with all narrow-based taxes, those taxes create some inefficiencies and fairness problems. The inefficiencies can be mitigated if the excise taxes are levied on small set of commodities that are relatively unresponsive to tax rates. Fairness is enhanced by avoiding the imposition of substantial excise taxes on items essential to the subsistence needs of the poor. Administrative costs can be mitigated by imposing the excise taxes on commodities produced or distributed by a small number of vendors. Broader based tax regimes should become increasingly more important as a country matures. Excise taxes continue to raise significant revenues in developing and transitional countries even as their development increases, although their relative importance generally is reduced as they are able to administer broader tax bases. Trade taxation should be reduced in the context of bilateral and multilateral agreements to lower the barriers on trade. Revenues lost from reduced trade taxes generally should be replaced with higher indirect taxes. A shift from trade taxes to broad-based consumption taxes allows countries to replace differential, high-rate levies on imports with lower-rate, neutral taxation of domestic and imported commodities. The result will be more neutral taxation and a more open economy in which inefficient businesses are not protected and which should improve the capacity of the country to produce, consume, and 96 export. Whenever feasible from an administrative perspective, personal income taxation should be one component of nearly every country’s tax structure. A personal income tax has the potential for achieving some redistribution of income through the tax system, and it has the administrative advantage of providing for the collect of revenues at the source. The revenue potential from income taxation is relatively low for the least developed countries, but their capacity to collect revenues from that source should expand as the country develops. Corporate income taxation should be a component of the tax system of almost every developing and transitional country, to allow, among other things, for taxation of foreign earnings at the source and to prevent individuals from avoiding taxes under the personal income tax by hiding assets within a corporation. Corporate taxes should be broadly based, evenly levied on domestic and foreign corporations, and imposed at modest rates (which are in line with personal income tax rates). Tax concessions should be used very sparingly and only as part of very targeted economic growth strategies. In particular, countries should avoid negotiated tax concessions that are not open and transparent. Tax rates must be kept moderate. To raise the revenue needed to finance public expenditures, a system with low rates needs to have broad tax bases and a balanced mix of tax instruments. The perverse consequences of taxes rise very rapidly with tax rates. Incentives for evasion and avoidance also rise with tax rates, creating significant costs on the domestic economy. Tax structures, including the choice of tax instruments and the specific tax bases and rates imposed, should be selected to 97 provide overall revenue growth that is consistent with a country’s service delivery responsibilities and its need to finance development expenditures. If properly designed, the revenue growth will occur without the need for frequent rate increases and other significant changes in tax legislation. Small modifications in tax structures will always be required to offset unintended consequences and opportunities for evasion and avoidance. Adjustments also will be necessary from time to time in response to an evolving economic structure. But major policy changes because of poor revenue growth should and can be avoided by designing the tax structure to achieve the appropriate revenue growth Taxation should extend into non-monetized and traditional sectors, and specifically into the agricultural sector. Taxation of agricultural land and presumptive taxation are among the effective means to levy such taxes. The VAT, if properly implemented, can also help in taxing these sectors. Failure to tax these sectors results in tax subsidies to traditional economic sectors and discourages movement into the modern sector of the economy. Long-run economic growth will be advantaged by more even taxation of traditional and modern sectors of the economy. A focus on good administration is imperative to achieve the expected revenue performance, neutrality, and fairness from the tax system. Good administration requires an appropriately structured tax administration that is staffed with adequately trained officials and has the resources to operate efficiently. Perhaps most important of all, the tax administration must have the political support needed to collect the taxes that have been imposed in an even, transparent, and fair manner. From an administrative and compliance perspective, many 98 taxes are most efficiently collected at the point of production. Nonetheless, such taxes must be structured very carefully because taxes on production have the potential to create many additional perverse effects including on where businesses locate, the ways production occurs and the location of production. These effects are nearly always adverse to economic growth. Developing countries should promote cooperation on international tax matters through a variety of mechanisms, including the establishment of international organizations that can represent their interests in various tax discussions around the world. Developed countries are normally well represented by organizations such as OECD, but developing countries have no coordinated front in many international tax discussions and negotiations. Effective cooperation among developing and transitional countries and with the developed countries can extend the taxing options available to all countries. 99 Appendix A. Taxation and Decentralization The problems of taxation that developing and transitional governments face when joining the world economy have been faced for decades by subnational governments throughout the world. A sub-national government typically relinquishes control over its borders to create a free trade zone within the nation state of which it forms a part. In particular, sub-national governments have difficulty raising tax revenue from mobile tax bases, such as personal income and corporate income, and they even confront difficulties imposing local sales taxes, due to opportunities that their residents often have for making tax-free purchases outside their jurisdiction. These problems have been made worse by the globalization of their national economy, for now the sub-national governments are buffeted not only by internal economic pressures but by external ones as well. The solutions to the tax problems that sub-national governments confront are similar in many respects to the solutions recommended in this report for nation states. In general, the sub-national governments need to recapture the sovereign power they gave up (or never possessed) through cooperative measures. They also need to rationalize their tax policies and improve their tax administrations. Fortunately, a mechanism for achieving the needed cooperation among sub-national governments is already in place --- namely, the national government. In all too many cases, however, national governments have failed to provide the framework for cooperation that is needed for sub-national governments to obtain the revenues needed to provide local services and other accouterments of government. In this section, we make suggestions on how that framework should be structured. The Trend towards Decentralization One might expect that the problems associated with globalization would have created pressures for centralizing power at the national government and for reducing the importance of sub-national governments. The trend, however, is in exactly the opposite direction. All over the world, countries are moving, 100 sometimes quite rapidly, to decentralize governmental functions. This movement is taking place notwithstanding the real problems that globalization creates for all governments and particularly for small ones. Given this trend toward decentralization, it has become increasingly important that the tax problems of sub-national governments be taken seriously by policy makers and by tax analysts. The role of decentralized governments in the delivery of public services and the collection and administration of taxes differs widely around the world. Countries such as Belarus, Mongolia, the Netherlands, and South Africa rely very heavily on local governments, which are responsible for 40 percent or more of combined national and sub-national expenditures. Other countries, such as Costa Rica, Jordan, Lebanon, and Panama rely much less on local governments, with the sub-national share of expenditures often comprising less than 5 percent of combined total spending. The reasons for decentralization vary widely but include efforts to strengthen democracy, enhance government accountability, and empower citizens. The expected benefits of decentralization also vary. Some countries anticipate that decentralization will lead to better service delivery because the diverse demands and needs of the population can be served more effectively by local officials, who are better informed about what people want. Local officials often can be held more accountable than national officials by the local population, which has greater access to the local mayor than to members of the national legislature. Decentralization may be seen as a means of accommodating the varying interests of different ethnic groups by reducing the potential number of friction points, thus helping to expand nation building. There may also be dis-economies of delivering some services at the national or even regional level, meaning that local service delivery can be less expensive. Fiscal Independence Decentralization can only be successful when national and sub-national governments have established a framework in which sub-national 101 governments can flourish. Perhaps the most vital single requirement is that sub-national governments be financially sustainable. The Committee of Experts on Public Administration noted that the “conditions for decentralization’s success include national Governments to prompt, initiate, monitor and guide the process of political and financial decentralization, as well as the creation of an adequate financial decentralization, and the creation of an adequate financial resource base for local governments to function properly.” The national government must create an environment in which subnational governments can succeed, and the sub-national governments must have sufficient resources to succeed. This appendix focuses on one aspect of an effective decentralized governmental structure — access to the necessary resources. An adequate financial structure is an imperative if sub-national governments are to deliver the services that people demand. Sub-national governments including both intermediate governments, such as states, provinces and counties (regional governments), and the lowest level of government, such as cities, municipalities and villages (local governments). As noted above, sub-national governments cannot command the resources they need to fulfill their obligations without major support from the national government. In many cases, that support should come from direct transfers of revenues collected at the national level and from institutional arrangements, such as tax-base sharing, that allow sub-national governments to raise tax revenues on their own. Local governments also should utilize user fees for services or taxes that are nearly equivalent to user fees when those approaches prove feasible. In almost every developing and transitional country, transfers from the national government must play an important role in the creation of an adequate local financial base. The national government has a much greater capacity than local governments to impose and collect many taxes, including the VAT and income taxes. This greater capacity to tax makes it logical for the national government to generate a significant share of tax revenues and then to shift revenues to the government responsible for service delivery. Transfers from the national government are also a key means of reducing 102 disparity in access to resources. The national government can help equalize access to key services, such as primary education and infrastructure, by transferring more revenues to those local governments that have the least capacity to raise revenues on their own or the greatest need to deliver key services. Local, regional, and provincial governments, however, are not as accountable or transparent when they use national resources to finance their activities as when they use resources they obtain under their own taxing powers. The local population generally has little information about the volume of resources available to a local government when all the money is provided in the form of transfers. As a result, the voting public has little ability to require officials to use the money well. Local government officials often have no control over expenditure levels when financing comes from the center. As a result, local officials would not be able to work with their populations to ensure that the best set of services is delivered even if they felt political pressures to do so. If decentralization is to work well, therefore, sub-national governments must have the ability to impose and collect significant taxes on their own authority. If those sub-national taxes are properly designed and are implemented effectively, they may lead not only to an increase in total resource mobilization but also to improved utilization of those resources. As noted above, the economic competition associated with globalization may have a detrimental effect on the capacity of sub-national governments to generate revenues. Collecting tax revenues is more difficult at the local or regional level because much economic activity can flee or can be hidden easily. For example, businesses or individuals can evade or avoid income taxes by receiving income outside their home jurisdiction, or they can purchase goods in another community and thereby evade or avoid local sales taxes. Methods of Decentralizing Control over Tax Revenue The extent of tax decentralization can be determined in terms of the degree of local or regional control over four factors: 103 tax revenues received; choice of tax rates; definition of tax bases, and tax administration. Control over revenues at the local or regional level obviously is necessary to decentralize government. To achieve genuine fiscal decentralization, however, local and regional governments must have control over some aspects of the process of imposing and collecting taxes. Local Control of Tax Rates. From the perspective of economic and political accountability, the most essential elements of fiscal decentralization are that local and regional governments should be allowed to determine the rates of taxes for which they are politically responsible and that these taxes should be sufficiently important in terms of the revenues generated to ensure that the setting of rates affects expenditures in noticeable ways. Control over the tax rate gives local and regional officials the ability to influence the level of services provided (which is necessary if government is to be devolved), and it makes them more accountable to their citizens, who are better able to see the amount of revenue available to the local and regional governments. Control over rates can come in several forms. If the sub-national government is fully responsible for the administration of a tax, as it might be in the case of a property tax, then it could be given full authority over the rates. A national requirement of some minimum rates, however, might actually enhance control at the local level, as it lessens the problems of tax competition that otherwise would come into play. That minimum rate, although established under national legislation, ought to be determined through consultations with local officials. A maximum rate also might be appropriate in some cases. Generally, competitive forces can be relied upon to prevent unreasonably high rates. A cap on rates is useful in some cases to prevent local jurisdictions from attempting to capture an unreasonable share of the potential tax revenues from certain captive taxpayers. For example, a local government should not be permitted to impose excessive taxes on the property of an extractive industry located within its borders because the potential 104 revenues from that industry ought to be shared more broadly among other subnational governments or with the national government. Local Control over Tax Bases. Providing for local control over tax bases and tax administration are more problematic. Local control over tax bases is inappropriate in many cases because administration and compliance costs are often lower if the same tax bases exist across the country. A consistent base means that businesses operating across the country are not subjected to multiple tax structures. There are also lower administrative costs if taxes are administered at the national level. The theoretical efficiencies of national control over the definition of the tax bases may be lost, however, through the normal operation of politics. All else being equal, a political leader seeking support of the populace would prefer to reduce taxes rather than to raise them, because taxes are always unpopular with those who have to pay them. The chief political reason for raising taxes is to be able to provide the public services that the populace wants and expects from the government. If the political leaders at the national level of government have the power to determine local tax revenues collected by local governments by defining the local tax base broadly or narrowly, they have a strong political incentive to go for the narrow tax base. By doing so, they suffer no revenue loss at their level of government, yet they are able to satisfy the desire of their constituents for lower taxes. This problem is one that has arisen in many countries. The situation in Bosnia provides a good current example. And the problem can be expected to arise whenever the detriments and benefits of taxation are artificially divided. The problem described above has no full solution. A compromise solution can be found, however, through institutional arrangements that require a national or uniform definition of the tax base and that give local governments substantial input into the content of that tax base. Solutions of this type have been worked out in countries as different as Australia and Papua New Guinea. One workable technique is for the national government, in consultation with the affected sub-national governments, to work out an 105 acceptable definition of the tax base and then to require substantial local input, perhaps even with veto power, for any changes to be made in the tax base. Suitable arrangements also would be needed to allow for minor adjustments in the tax base to block the tax-avoidance schemes that are an almost inevitable response to taxation. Local Control over Tax Administration. Local administration of some taxes, such as the property tax, may work well. Even with the property tax, however, some national or regional assistance might be highly desirable. A national office, for example, may be better equipped to value certain types of property, especially property used for industrial purposes. It also might assist in the drafting of a competent taxing statute. In addition, a regional office may be better able to do cadastral surveys in the region to ensure that all property of importance to local governments in the region has been entered onto the tax rolls. For income taxes, including the personal income tax and the business profits tax, and for broad-based sales taxes, such as a VAT, local administration is almost certainly not the best means of collecting revenues. National collection of local and regional taxes may be better than establishing numerous small and probably inefficient local collection agencies. Companies operating throughout the country are better controlled by a national administration that can monitor all of their domestic business activities. It is easier for a national administration, operating on a large scale, to hire specialized auditors and to develop a computerized information system. National tax administration also makes it convenient to transfer revenue agents from time to time in order to limit the likelihood of tax fraud. Separating the collection of taxes from the level of government entitled to the revenues, however, presents problems similar to the problems, discussed above, that arise when the national government defines the tax base and the local governments receive the revenues generated from that tax base. In general, a national tax administration may not collect local taxes effectively when it has no real stake in the results of the collection process. The national 106 tax administration obviously has fewer incentives to collect local taxes and to respond to local officials than it does to collect national taxes and answer to the legislature and to the national government. Hence the national administration may put little effort into ensuring that local taxes are collected effectively. If the national administration is to collect local taxes, the legislature and the tax authorities must introduce good incentives for effective collection. One mechanism that would provide some limited benefits would be for the national tax officials engaged in the collection of local taxes to be paid by the local governments, either directly or through charges made to the local governments for services rendered. The local governments then have the ability to withhold payment if the services were inadequate. Because the costs of collection are typically a small part of the total revenue collected, however, a charge for services cannot be expected to overcome fully the political dynamics favoring non-collection at the national level. Another mechanism that has worked well in many countries is for both the national and the sub-national governments to share the revenue from a particular tax. For example, the national government might collect its own VAT and also a VAT imposed by sub-national governments as a surcharge on the same tax base. Similarly, the national government might allow the subnational governments to impose a surcharge on a national income tax, either the personal income tax or the corporate profits tax. The national tax administration would have a strong incentive to collect the sub-national tax properly because its failure to do so would have serious effects on its own revenues. The surcharge system need not be restricted to national taxes. Local governments might make arrangements for a regional government to jointly impose a property tax, with the regional government having the primary responsibility for valuing property and making assessments. The local government, however, might have responsibility for collection of the tax. Both the regional government and the local government would share in the tax 107 revenues, with each government’s share of the revenue determined in advance and communicated to taxpayers. The fundamental problem with shared collection arrangements is that the local government may end up losing control not only over the collection process but also over the rates and the definition of the tax bases. To allow for control over the rates, the sub-national governments should be permitted, perhaps within some specified range, to determine the amount of their surcharge on the national tax. As suggested above, the local and regional governments that are sharing a tax base with the national government also should have serious input into the design of the tax base and should have some authority to prevent revenue-losing alterations in the tax base. A system of a national tax with a sub-national surcharge has some superficial similarities to the tax-sharing (revenue sharing) system that is found in almost all transitional countries and in a number of developing countries as well. Conceptually and practically, however, the two systems are totally different. Tax sharing is no more than a disguised intergovernmental transfer of resources, with the recipient governments bearing no responsibility at all for the tax rates or the amounts they receive. Under the surcharge system, however, local and regional governments can establish the level of their surcharge on the national tax, and the sub-national share of the tax would be identified specifically to taxpayers when the tax is paid. In addition, the tax would be paid over directly to the relevant sub-national government, without the need for an appropriation of the amount by the national government. In general, the administrative and compliance costs associated with a surcharge system are likely to be low. Administrative costs should be low because the same tax officials would collect the revenue from the same taxpayers, and the amount of the tax would be computed with respect to the same tax base. In the case of a personal income tax, the surcharge could be remitted, often by an employer, to the national government, which then would transmit the remittance to the sub-national government levying the surcharge. Similarly, the vendors responsible for collecting a VAT would remit both the 108 national portion of the tax and the surcharge to the national government. One complication that would arise in administering a surcharge is that the national government would need to collect the information needed to determine which sub-national government should obtain the revenue. Assuming the rules for dispensing the revenue are fairly simple, the administrative costs of collecting the necessary information should be modest. In the case of a sales tax, the revenues presumably would be shared in relation to the sales made in each sub-national jurisdiction and the rates of the surcharge imposed by each sub-national jurisdiction. The proper rules for distributing the revenue raised from a surcharge on the personal income tax are not self-evident. Perhaps the least complex rule would be distribute the revenue in relation to the residence of the taxpayer. An alternative rule would focus on the source of the income taxed. That rule works easily enough if the tax is essential a wage tax, but it does not work well if the base of the tax is defined more broadly. More complex problems would arise in apportioning a surcharge on a corporate profits tax. The most appealing method of apportionment would be to link apportionment to the source of the business profits. Making such a linkage, however, is exceedingly difficult unless done though some type of apportionment formula. Some developed countries, including Canada, Switzerland, and the United States, use an apportionment formula to determine the share of the corporate tax base attributable to their sub-national governments. (McIntyre, 2003) The use of an apportionment formula is workable, but no one should suggest that it does not entail serious administrative and compliance costs. To avoid those costs, most developing and transitional countries might wish to make the corporate profits tax exclusively a national tax. Selecting the Tax Mix The design of a good sub-national tax system is even more country specific than the design of a good tax administration or a good national tax system. Taxation is a local matter, and local taxation is even more a local 109 matter. Still, some useful generalities are possible. We suggest the following guidelines in designing sub-national taxes. Sub-national governments, and particularly local governments, should adopt user fees to finance the serves they provide whenever possible. When subsidies for the poor are appropriate, they should be provided directly through a subsidy program rather than indirectly through a lower charge for services. Developing and transitional countries should make better use of property taxes to fund local and regional services. The property tax, which often has effects analogous to those of user fees, is an especially useful tax for local governments. If regional governments are to be given significant responsibilities for providing nationally critical services, such as education and health care, they need access to a major tax base, such as a personal income tax or a VAT. As discussed above, that access could be provided by allowing the regional government to impose a surcharge on the national tax. Different degrees of decentralization are appropriate for different taxes (Box 7). Service Fees. In almost all countries, local governments can and should make greater use of user charges. Indeed, user fees should be imposed wherever possible to finance services. They can normally be imposed effectively when the recipients of services are easily identifiable and receipt of the service can be separately identified for individuals or households. Obvious examples include utility services, which should be fully priced, and any subsidies desired for equity reasons made explicit as public expenditures. Services such as utilities should be considered for privatization as well. Municipal transit and some health services are other obvious examples where user fees can play an important role. Property Taxes. Local property taxes also should provide a significant revenue source. In many cases, a simple tax on real property (immoveable 110 property) can be seen as the economic equivalent of a user fee because the value of real property often is enhanced by the services that it finances. For example, police and fire protection, repair of local roads, and expenditures for local public schools can enhance property values in rough proportion to the local taxes paid. The relationship of a property tax to a service fee is obviously quite imprecise even in the best of cases, but the relationship is often sufficiently close to mitigate problems of tax competition. As noted above, national or regional governments may play an important role in setting up a standard property tax law and in undertaking the technical tasks of valuing property and training staff. The collection and enforcement of the property tax, however, can be accomplished at the local level. Assuming that the revenues are to remain at the local level, the tax rate definitely should be determined at the local level, albeit within some specified range that could be established by either the national or the regional government. Few developing or transitional countries currently give local governments sufficient discretion or responsibility with respect to property taxes. For this reason and perhaps for others, these taxes are substantially under-utilized in most of these countries (Box 8). 111 Box 8 — Assignment of Taxes to Levels of Government Tax type Tax Tax Base Tax Rate Administration Revenue Ownership 1. Custom National National 2. Excises National or regional National or regional National or regional National or regional 3. Wage and National, regional Personal Income or local National National National National, regional National, regional or local or local 4. Corporate Income National National National National or shared 5. VAT National National National* National or shared 6. Sales Tax Regional or local Regional or local Regional or local Regional and/or local 7. Propert tax Local National or regional Local Local 8. Real Estate Local Local Local Local 9. Motor Vehicles Local Local Local Local 10. Social security National National National National 11. User Fees Service providing Service providing Service providing Service providing Social Services agencies agencies agencies agencies 12. User Fees Service supply Regulatory Service providing Service providing Privatized Utilities companies frameworks companies subject companies Transfers Contributions to regulatory oversight *Regional governments may be given the authority to apply a surcharge to the national tax within a specified band of rates 112 Degrees of Decentralization. The extent to which a tax is decentralization depends in large part on the inherent characteristics of the tax (Box 9). Property taxes and motor vehicle taxes may be decentralized almost completely because they can be administered effectively at the local level and they do not create major problems of tax competition. As noted above, however, some nationally imposed minimum rate to limit tax competition and a maximum rate to prevent local exploitation are desirable. Also desirable is the provision of regional or national technical assistance in setting up the taxes and in dealing with certain technical matters, such as valuation of property. Box 9 — Property Taxes Property tax revenues are low in most developing and transitional economies. The coverage of the tax is not comprehensive, assessments are low, and collection rates are typically low. Nominal tax rates are also low, and governments usually find that rate increases in this very visible tax are difficult to sell politically. Simply raising the legal tax rate would in any case usually burden only the few from whom taxes are actually collected. Increased nominal rates are likely to be acceptable only if accompanied by improvements in tax administration such as more comprehensive coverage, better assessments, more frequent assessment re-valuations, and enforced penalties for late payment. In general, revenues are higher if the property tax is based on the value of land and buildings (instead of just on land), if there are few exemptions and no favourable treatment of particular property classes, and if the scope for local tax competition are limited. Despite its problems, the property tax remains the predominant option for raising revenues at the local government level. The potential yield of land and property taxes is unlikely to be huge, revenues from this source will not be very elastic, and the administrative costs typically are substantial. Nonetheless, all local taxes are difficult to impose. An expanded local property tax is both a logical and a desirable objective for many countries, particularly those in which local governments are expected to play an increasing role in allocating public sector resources. 113 Some taxes, particularly the corporate profits tax, cannot be administered at the local level and can be administered at the regional level only with substantial assistance from the national government. As noted above, a regional corporate profits tax is possible as a surcharge on a national tax. Even in that case, however, difficult problems of apportioning the revenue from the tax would arise. With few exceptions, the preferred route in developing and transitional countries is to make the corporate profits tax an exclusive national tax. If the revenue of that tax needs to be shared to make the sub-national governments financially sustainable, then it should be done through some tax-sharing or grant arrangement rather than through the devolution of the taxing power to the sub-national level. Sales taxes, payroll taxes, and even personal income taxes can be decentralized, at least in part, through the surcharge mechanism. The surcharge mechanism is likely to work well when applied by a regional government but less well at the local level. At the local level, the problem of how to allocate the revenue from the tax becomes difficult, especially in the case of the personal income, which presumably would be apportioned on a residence basis. A local surcharge on a sales tax probably is workable as long as the local surcharge rate is low. If the rate is significant, problems of tax competition are likely to be significant. All of the above remarks need to be taken as broad generalities that may not be applicable in some countries. For example, a large country with a small number of regional governments is likely to have far less problems of tax competition under a sales tax than a small country with many regional governments. The degree to which a national government should share its taxing powers with sub-national government depends significantly on the responsibilities of the regional and local governments for providing significant services to the populace. If the provision of services is decentralized substantially, then the taxing power also should be decentralized substantially. To decentralize the power to tax, however, it is often necessary for the national government to do more than simply assign particular tax bases to local or regional governments. As we have argued above, it also is necessary 114 for the national government to fashion a fiscal framework that allows the regional and local governments to cope effectively with tax competition. 115 Appendix B - International Cooperation on Income Tax Matters The strong movement towards globalization at the end of the 19th century led many countries to seek ways of cooperating to avoid impediments to cross-border trade and investment and to minimize opportunities for tax evasion. A primary mechanism for cooperation was the bilateral income tax treaty. The earliest income tax treaties were adopted by Prussia around the start of the twentieth century. Its first treaty was with Austria, signed in 1899. Soon thereafter, it entered treaties with Bavaria, Saxony, and Baden, followed by treaties with Luxembourg and the city of Bale. Other continental governments soon followed the Prussian lead. Hungary and Austria concluded a treaty in 1909. The development of tax treaties was largely stalled by the hostilities that engulfed much of the world in 1914. With the dramatic increase in tax rates that followed the First World War, many countries, especially in continental Europe, became interested in dealing with double taxation problems through the treaty mechanism. Germany took the lead after the war, signing a treaty with Czechoslovakia in 1921 and with Austria in 1922. In 1922, Italy convened a conference in Rome of the states emerging from the dissolution of the Austro-Hungarian Empire (Austria, Hungary, Poland, Romania, and the Kingdom of the Serbs, Croats, and Slovenes). The goal was to forge a multilateral agreement among the represented countries. The practical result was a bilateral tax treaty between Italy and Austria. 116 Developments up to 1946 Beginning in the early 1920s, the League of Nations began to play a leadership role in promoting international cooperation on direct taxes. It published the first internationally important model tax convention in 1928. That model was the culmination of work that had begun in 1920. The convention recognized the importance of some sharing of taxing power between the source country and the residence country. It did not attempt to limit the methods the Contracting States might use to prevent double taxation. Instead, it offered alternative means of achieving a reasonable sharing of tax revenues from cross-border activities. The League of Nations model convention of 1928 was prepared by a group of government experts on double taxation and tax evasion. The initial group, formed in 1922, had seven members, all officials from European countries (Belgium, Czechoslovakia, France, Great Britain, Italy, the Netherlands, and Switzerland). In 1925, the committee was expanded to include two more European representatives (Germany and Poland) and three additional representatives from outside Europe (Argentina, Japan, and Venezuela). Beginning in 1927, the United States, which was not a member of the League, participated on an informal basis. The expanded committee produced a report and draft convention in 1927, which was circulated to League members and some nonmember States. In 1928, the Secretary General of the League convened a meeting of government experts in Geneva, Switzerland, to consider the draft convention. That group of experts included the eleven who had drafted the report and members from 16 additional countries (Austria, Bulgaria, China, Danzig, Denmark, Estonia, Greece, Hungary, Irish Free State, Latvia, Norway, Romania, South Africa, Spain, Sweden, and the Union of Soviet Socialist Republics). Influence of the international business community appears to have been modest, although the International Chamber of Commerce played a consultative role from the early 1920s onward. The drafters of the convention relied in part on a 1923 League of Nations report on double taxation prepared by a group of four economists from Great Britain (Sir Josiah Stamp), Italy (Professor Einaudi), the Netherlands (Professor Bruins), and the United States (Professor Seligman). 117 The League’s first model convention clearly embraced the twin goals of eliminating double taxation and also preventing undertaxation. The Report (p. 26) states: From the very outset, the Meeting of Government experts realized the necessity of dealing with the questions of tax evasion and double taxation in co-ordination with each other. It is highly desirable that States should come to an agreement with a view to ensuring that a taxpayer shall not be taxed on the same income by a number of different countries, and it seems equally desirable that such international co-operation should prevent certain income from escaping taxation altogether. The most elementary and undisputed principles of fiscal justice, therefore, require that the experts should devise a scheme whereby all incomes would be taxed once, and once only. (Emphasis added.) The League’s group of government experts proposed three alternative ways of taxing income from cross-border activities. All three plans used the concept of a “permanent establishment” (PE) that had appeared in the early Prussian treaties. Under the three plans, the income of an industrial, commercial or agricultural “undertaking” would be taxable in the countries where its permanent establishments are situated. (Model 1a, Art. 5; Model 1b, Art. 2B; Model 1c, Art. 3.) The models differ primarily in their treatment of income from moveable capital. The first model generally reserves the right to tax in the source country, whereas the other two models generally assign the right to tax to the residence country. To prevent double taxation of business profits when an “undertaking” has a PE in more than one country, the three models included in the 1928 convention provide that each treaty partner would tax the income “produced in its territory.” The term “undertaking” was undefined; it apparently has the same meaning as the term “enterprise,” which is an undefined term found in modern tax treaties. In general, an enterprise is a group of corporations or other legal entities under common control and engaged in a common business. The allocation of income among taxing jurisdictions under the 1928 118 convention was to be accomplished through consultation between the “competent administrations of the two Contracting State.” Some form of formulary apportionment was an acceptable method for allocating the income between the countries where the PEs were located. The important point was that all of the income of an undertaking would be allocated to some PE. No exemption or other tax relief for an item of income would be given in one Contracting State without giving the other Contracting State the concomitant right to tax that item of income. The drafters of the 1928 convention were favorably disposed towards the resolution of some tax conflicts by ceding full jurisdiction to tax to the state of residence. On a unilateral basis, some countries, including the United States, had resolved the difficult problems of source taxation of shipping companies by ceding source jurisdiction to the residence country on a reciprocal basis. This approach was unworkable in many countries because they did not attempt to tax the worldwide income of their residents. In addition, it was not an attractive option for countries that would lose revenue from the reciprocal arrangement, due to the lack of foreign activities of their residents. The model convention was written so that it would be compatible with this development without being dependent on it. The 1928 convention addressed only a small subset of the international tax issues of importance to the taxation of cross-border activities. Recognizing the need for additional work, the League of Nations established in 1929 the Fiscal Committee. The Fiscal Committee engaged in activities before, during, and after World War II. It ceased operations after the war when the League was supplanted by the United Nations. During the 1930s, much of the work of the League’s Fiscal Committee was in developing rules and standards for allocating the income of industrial and commercial enterprises operating in more than one country. In 1933, it prepared a draft multilateral convention on the allocation of profits. That model convention was revised in 1935 but never formally adopted. The basic approach in that convention was to treat a permanent establishment as if it were a separate enterprise and to determine its income based on what has 119 come to be called the arm’s length standard. The goal was to allow countries to determine the income of a PE based on the local books of account, without reference to the books of the entire firm. Apportionment by formula was reserved as a last resort. This approach was a marked change from the 1928 model convention, which provided that all of the income of an “undertaking” be allocated among the countries where the enterprise or undertaking has a PE. Work on a model convention continued during the war years. In 1940 and again in 1943, the League’s Fiscal Committee convened a regional conference in Mexico City to revise the 1928 convention. The meeting included representatives from countries of the Western Hemisphere, both developed and developing (Argentina, Bolivia, Canada, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Mexico, Peru, the United States, Uruguay, and Venezuela). The regional conference produced a draft model convention, popularly known as the Mexico Draft. In general, the Mexico Draft took the position that the primary jurisdiction to tax income should be assigned to the source country — the position favored by the developing countries. In this respect, the Mexico Draft was a major refinement of the League’s 1928 model convention. The basic structure of the 1928 convention, however, remained unchanged. The Mexico Draft clarified an ambiguity in the 1928 convention by providing that all of the business income derived in a country would be taxable there unless the activities were “isolated or occasional” and the enterprise earning the income did not have a PE in that country. A protocol to the convention provided rules for attributing income to a PE. These rules, in general, followed the Fiscal Committee’s 1935 draft convention for the allocation of profits. In 1946, the League’s Fiscal Affairs Committee, with a full complement of members, met in London, England, to review the Mexico draft. A new draft, popularly referred to as the London Draft, was produced. The London draft was similar in some respects to the Mexico Draft in the treatment of business profits. It differed from the Mexico Draft, however, in 120 requiring that an enterprise resident in one Contracting State have a PE in the other Contracting State for that latter State to tax the enterprise on any portion of its business profits. The London Draft also imposed significant limitations on the taxation of investment income in the source country, contrary to the position favored by the developing counties and adopted in the Mexico Draft. For example, the Mexico Draft provided that royalties paid for the right to use a patent or secret process would be taxable only in the State where the right is exploited. In contrast, the London Draft reserved the right to tax such royalties to the country of residence. 1946 to Present The United Nations came into being on October 24, 1945, although the League of Nations continued for some short period thereafter. Various governments concerned with tax treaty issues made efforts to revitalize the work of the League of Nations on tax conventions. Although the United Nations took an active interest in that effort, leadership in developing a model treaty was seized by the Organisation for European Economic Cooperation (OEEC). The OEEC was created in 1948 in conjunction with the Marshall Plan for revitalizing the economies of Europe. It has 16 members, all European countries outside the Soviet block. In 1956, the OEEC created its Fiscal Committee and entrusted it with the task of working out a draft model bilateral tax convention. The OEEC became the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) in 1960. Membership of the OECD was extended to the major industrial countries of the world. It now has 30 members. No developing countries are members of the OECD. The OECD published its draft model treaty in 1963. That convention drew heavily from the League’s London Draft, but included additional features that favored capital exporting countries over capital importing countries. In form, the 1963 draft recognized the importance of sharing of revenue between the source and residence countries. Its practical effect, however, was to erect substantial barriers to the exercise of source jurisdiction and to afford multinational firms with major opportunities for tax minimizing strategies through its emphasis on legal form over economic substance. The 121 1963 draft was revised slightly over the next decade and a half. It was published in final form in 1977. The OECD model was extremely effective in eliminating most of the common types of double taxation. It was not very effective, however, in eliminating international tax avoidance and evasion. Indeed, several core features of the OECD model have promoted international undertaxation. The OECD model provides for an exchange of information on tax matters between the Contracting States. The goal of the exchange-of-information article is to curtail tax avoidance and evasion. Unfortunately, the article allows countries to decline to provide information if they have adopted bank-secrecy laws or otherwise are disinclined to exchange information for policy reasons. As a result, the exchange of information clause has not been effective in most cases. However, it has been effective for a few countries, such as the United States and Canada, that have a long tradition of cooperation on tax matters. One feature of the OECD model that promotes tax avoidance is the treatment of affiliated entities. Under the model, a member of a multi-national enterprise (MNE) group will not have a PE in a country solely because it conducts its business in that country through a related company. This rule has been read broadly to mean that the affiliate relationship is irrelevant in determining whether the affiliate is the PE of the MNE group (or some member thereof). As a result, the affiliate must be an agent of the group and must habitually make contracts on behalf of the group to be a PE of the group. Tax planners have no difficulty in ensuring that an affiliate is never the PE of the group unless they have some reason for wanting it to be a PE. The affiliate rule permits what tax specialists refer to as “entity isolation.” In general, the MNE group assigns to a separately incorporated affiliate all of the activities and property that the MNE group needs to conduct business in a particular country and that would constitute a PE. To the extent possible, assets and activities that are likely to generate substantial profits are not assigned to the affiliate. For example, valuable intangible property, such as patents and secret processes, would not be assigned to the affiliate. The 122 intangible property is kept in an offshore affiliate, and the taxable entity is required to pay a substantial royalty to the offshore affiliate for the use of the intangible property in the source state. As a result of such techniques, the MNE group typically is able to restrict the profits taxable in the source country to some modest return on its physical assets located in that country. Three additional features of the OECD model, in addition to the PE rule, support entity isolation. First, the OECD model generally requires the source state to allow a deduction for royalty payments to a foreign MNE unless the tax authorities can show that the payments constitute some type of sham transaction or are unreasonable in amount. Second, the OECD model convention prohibits the source state from imposing a withholding tax on the royalty payments. Third, the OECD model has no effective mechanism for preventing treaty shopping — the use of a treaty by a resident of some third country that is not a party to the treaty. Through treaty shopping, an MNE can move income ostensibly allocated for taxation in the residence country to a tax haven country, with the result that the income of the MNE is not taxed either in the source state or the residence state. These three rules, in combination, permit extensive use of what tax specialists refer to as earnings stripping. The problems with the OECD model described above have been well understood by tax experts for several decades. Nothing has been done to deal with these problems for two reasons. First, the OECD typically operates by consensus, and some members of the OECD have been prepared to prevent agreement on any model that would undercut their ability to attract capital, including capital from those avoiding tax in other countries. Second, the OECD has been a victim of its own success. An important goal of a model convention is to promote uniformity. The OECD model has been embraced by most developed countries, with relatively minor adaptations, and, with some more significant modifications, by much of the rest of the world. To change the model is to upset the uniformity that the model has achieved. Given the very long gestation period for implementing changes in a country’s tax treaties, a change in the model would result in non-uniformity for a decade or more. As a result, the OECD has attempted, with some limited success, to deal 123 with defects in its model through its Commentary. Changes in the Commentary have been effective in addressing certain types of issues, but core issues like entity isolation cannot be addressed effectively through the Commentary. The widespread success of the OECD model in the 1970s provoked a reaction from developing countries. Those countries, being outside of the OECD, were excluded from effective participation in the design of the model. Under the League of Nations, the developed countries were the dominant force in designing a model convention. Only in the Mexico draft were the interests of the developing countries given high prominence. Still, the developing countries were represented in the process of approving model conventions. With the capture of the model treaty process by the OECD, the participation by developing countries ended. They were disenfranchised at a time when the number of developing countries was increasing markedly, due in large part to the collapse of colonialism in Africa and Asia after World War II. The developing countries responded to the success of the OECD model convention by developing their own model convention under the auspices of the United Nations. The United Nations’ involvement in the treaty process originated with a resolution of the Economic and Social Council, dated August 4, 1967. That resolution requested the Secretary-General to set up an ad hoc working group of tax experts and tax administrators who would represent the interests of both developed and developing countries and would represent different regions and tax systems. The ad hoc group would be asked to formulate guidelines and techniques for use in tax treaties between developed and developing countries. In 1968 the Secretary-General responded to the resolution by setting up the Ad Hoc Group of Experts on Tax Treaties between Developed and Developing Countries. The group was composed of tax officials and experts from twenty countries. In principle, these officials were to act in their individual capacity and not as representatives of their government. 124 In 1979, the United Nations published a Manual for the Negotiation of Bilateral Tax Treaties between Developed and Developing Countries. The manual had been prepared by the Group of Experts and the UN Secretariat. The following year, the United Nations published the United Nations Model Double Taxation Convention between Developed and Developing Countries. That publication included a model convention and Commentary, both of which had been prepared and approved by the Group of Experts. The UN model was based in substantial part on the OECD model, but it departed from the latter model on some key points. In particular, it modified the definition of a PE to allow some additional taxation of business income by the source country, and it provided that any reduction in a country’s statutory withholding rates would by done through bilateral negotiations. No specific target withholding rates were established in the model. The obvious expectation was that treaties based on the UN model would include a positive withholding rate on royalties and that the withholding rates on dividends and interest generally would exceed the rates recommended in the OECD model. In 1980, the membership of Ad Hoc Group, renamed the Ad Hoc Group of Experts on International Cooperation in Tax Matters, was increased from 20 to 25. The membership currently includes experts and tax administrators from 10 developed countries and 15 developing and transitional countries. The countries currently represented are: Argentina, Brazil, Burkina Faso, China, Côte d’Ivoire, Egypt, Finland, France, Germany, Ghana, India, Indonesia, Israel, Jamaica, Japan Mexico, Morocco, The Netherlands, Nigeria, Pakistan, Russian Federation, Spain, Switzerland, United Kingdom, and the United States. A representative of the Palestine Authority is invited to attend the meetings of the Group of Experts. The UN model has been effective in influencing the content of bilateral tax treaties between developed and developing countries. In particular, virtually all of the treaties between developed and developing countries provide for a positive withholding rate on royalty income, and the modifications proposed in the PE article by the UN model have been adopted widely. The core of the UN model, however, is taken from the OECD model. 125 As a result, the UN model permits companies to engage in entity isolation to minimize their exposure to taxation in the source country. The UN model does have a somewhat broader exchange-of-information article. Unfortunately, developing countries have had little success in obtaining information from the developed countries through that article. Both the OECD model and the UN model were not modified during the 1980s to respond to the increased globalization of the world economy. The OECD finally began making some amendments to its model in the 1990s, and now publishes its model in loose-leaf form. The United Nations published a new model in 2001 — the first revision in two decades. These revisions made many useful changes, mostly of a technical nature. The revised models, however, have continued the emphasis on formalisms. For example, both model conventions continue to permit entity isolation by treating the corporations comprising a multinational enterprise as if they were independent entities, notwithstanding their economic integration in most cases. Although the OECD and UN models have addressed the set of international tax issues identified by the League of Nations in the 1920s, they have not addressed many important international tax issues that have emerged in the 1980s and thereafter. For example, neither model addresses crossborder mergers, aggressive tax avoidance schemes, treaty shopping, hybrid entities, overlapping controlled-foreign-corporation regimes, and global trading of financial instruments. 126 Over the past several years, the OECD has attempted to involve developing countries in its various activities relating to tax treaties and international taxation in general. It has invited representatives of developing countries as observers on some of its meetings, particularly with respect to ecommerce. It has also invited a selected group of developing countries to register objections to positions taken by the OECD in the Commentary to its model convention. This initiative seems unlikely to result in the developing countries influencing the core decisions made by the OECD on tax treaty matters or on any other matters of importance to the OECD member states. 127 References Alm, James and Hugo López-Castaño (2002) “Payroll Taxes in Colombia,” Unpublished paper prepared for Misión de Finanzas Públicas, Bogotá, December. Bernheim, Douglas B. (2002). “Taxation and Saving,” in Alan J. Auerbach. and Martin Feldstein (eds.), Handbook of Public Economics, Volume 3 (Amsterdam:, North-Holland). Bird, Richard M. and Barbara Miller (1989) “The Incidence of Indirect Taxation on Low-Income Households in Jamaica,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, 27: 393-409. Bird, Richard M. and Duanjie Chen (1998) “The Fiscal Framework for Business in Asia,” in Wendy Dobson, ed., Fiscal Frameworks and Financial Systems in East Asia, Hong Kong Bank of Canada Papers on Asia, vol. 4 (Toronto: Institute for International Business, Faculty of Management, University of Toronto). Burgess, Robin and Nicholas Stern (1993) “Taxation and Development,” Journal of Economic Literature, 31: 762-830. Chattopadhyay, Sumen and Arindam Das-Gupta (2002) “The Compliance Cost of the Personal Income Tax and Its Determinants,” National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi. Chu, Ke-young, Hamid Davoodi, and Sanjeev Gupta (2000) “Income Distribution and Tax and Government Spending Policies in Developing Countries,” IMF Working Paper /00/62, Washington. Ebrill, Liam, Michael Keen, Jean-Paul Bodin, and Victoria Summers (2001). The Modern VAT (Washington: International Monetary Fund) Hughes, Gordon (1987) “The Incidence of Fuel Taxes: A Comparative Study of Three Countries,” in David Newbery and Nicholas Stern, eds., The Theory of Taxation for Developing Countries (Published for the World Bank by Oxford University Press). Jha, Prabhat and Frank Chaloupka (2000) Tobacco Control in Developing Countries (Oxford University Press for World Bank and World Health Organisation). League of Nations (1928) “Double Taxation and Tax Evasion: Report 128 Presented by the General Meeting of Government Experts on double Taxation and Evasion,” II. Economic and Financial 1928.II.49. (Geneva: League of Nations). League of Nations, Fiscal Committee (1946) “London and Mexico Model Tax Conventions: Commentary and Text,” C.88.M.88.1946.II.A. (Geneva: League of Nations). Mann, Arthur J. (2002) “Estimating the Administrative Costs of Taxation: A Methodology with Application to the Case of Guatemala,” DevTech Systems, Arlington VA, August. Martinez-Vazquez, Jorge and Robert M. McNabb (2000) “The Tax Reform Experiment in Transitional Countries,” National Tax Journal, 53: 27398. McIntyre, Michael J. (1997) “Tracing Rules and the Deduction for Interest Payments: A Justification for Tracing and a Critique of Recent U.S. Tracing Rules,” Chapter 17 of Taxation Towards 2000, John G. Head & Richard Krever, Eds. (Sydney: Austrailian Tax Research Foundation). McIntyre, Michael J. (2003) “The Use of Combined Reporting by Nation States,” prepared for Conference at Harvard Law School, “Taxation of Business Profits in the 21st Century,” Oct. 24—26, 2002 (forthcoming). OECD Committee on Fiscal Affairs (1998) Harmful Tax Competition: An Emerging Global Issue (Paris: OECD). OECD Committee on Fiscal Affairs (1992) Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital, updated looseleaf (Paris: OECD). Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (1994) Taxation of New Financial Instruments (Paris: OECD). Sandford, Cedric, ed. (1995) Tax Compliance Costs: Measurement and Policy (Bath, UK: Fiscal Publications). Shah, Anwar and John Whalley (1990)”Tax Incidence Analysis of Developing Countries: An Alternative View,” World Bank Economic Review, 5: 533-52. Tanzi, Vito (1987) “Quantitative Characteristics of the Tax Systems of Developing 129 Countries,” in David Newbery and Nicholas Stern, eds., The Theory of Taxation for Developing Countries (Published for the World Bank by Oxford University Press). Thirsk, Wayne (1997) Tax Reform in Developing Countries (Washington: World Bank). United Nations (2001) United Nations Model Double Taxation Convention between Developed and Developing Countries (New York: United Nations), ST/ESA/PAD/SER.E/21. United Nations (2001) High-level International Intergovernmental Consideration of Financing for Development (“Zedillo Report”) (New York: United Nations), A/55/1000. United Nations (2000) Millennium Declaration (New York: United Nations), A/RES/55/2. United Nations (2000) Report of the Secretary-General to the Preparatory Committee for the High-level International Intergovernmental Event on Financing for Development (New York: United Nations), A/AC.257/12. United Nations (2002) Report of the International Conference on Financing for Development, (Monterrey Consensus”) (New York: United Nations), A/CONF.198/11. 130