Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Henryk Ćwikliński Anita Szymańska University of Gdansk, Poland COMPARISON OF IMPACT OF ECONOMIC POLICIES ON ABILITY TO CREATE JOBS IN THE USA AND IN POLAND (UPON ITS ENTRANCE TO THE EU) Abstract After the decade of 1990s when Poland adopted the successful program of market-oriented transition, its continuation has been under threat since 2001. The striking drop in employment to about 51% of the population in the age 15-64 and the unemployment rate of 20% give Poland the last position among the EU members. The authors try to find solutions to the Polish labor market studying the U.S. model of creating jobs as well as European methods of improving their labor markets. The studies lead to the conclusion that there are different degrees of labor market flexibility as well as national attitudes toward policy intervention. The main issue is how to expand employment, raise productivity and, in effect, how to increase per capita income that is now 41% of the OECD levels in Poland. The further conclusion is that in order to increase the effective labor demand it is necessary to reestablish an appropriate balance between monetary and fiscal policies (the first one has been perfect since at least 1998). If so, it is necessary to speed up privatization and to restore public finances. The crucial aim is to reduce cost of doing business by cutting in the tax wedge. 1. KEY INDICATORS OF LABOR MARKETS In order to assess ability of an economy to create jobs it is necessary to review some of the most important data concerning labor markets in the USA and in the EU countries. The table 1 shows employment/population ratios in those countries in the period 1990-2003. 1 Table 1 Employment/population ratios in the USA and in the UE countries. Persons aged 15-64 years (percentages) 1990 2000 2003 USAa 72.2 74.1 71.2 EU-15 61.4 63.6 64.8 EU- 25 - - 63.6 Austria . 67.9 68.2 Belgium 54.4 60.9 59.3 Cyprus . . 69.2 Czech Republic . 65.2 64.7 75.4 76.4 75.1 Estonia . . 62.9 Finland 74.1 67.0 67.4 France 59.9 61.1 61.9 Germanyb 64.1 65.6 64.6 Greece 54.8 55.9 58.0 . 56.0 57.0 Ireland 52.1 64.5 65.0 Italy 52.6 53.9 56.2 Latvia . . 61.8 Lithuania . . 61.1 59.2 62.7 63.6 . . 54.5 61.1 72.9 73.6 . 55.0 51.2 67.4 68.3 67.1 Slovak Republic . 56.8 57.7 Slovenia . . 62.6 Spaina 51.8 57.4 60.7 Sweden 83.1 74.2 74.3 United Kingdom 72.5 72.4 72.9 Denmark Hungary Luxemburg Malta Netherlands Poland Portugal a) refers to persons aged 16 to 64 b) data up to 1990 are for Western Germany only . data not available Source: OECD Employment Outlook 2004; Eurostat: www.europa.eu.int, U.S. www.bls.gov.; GUS, own calculations. Department of Labor: 2 In 2003, 71.2 percent of Americans between 16 and 64 years of age were employed, as against 63.6 percent for the whole enlarged European Union, i.e. the same average level of employment/population ratio in the EU when it consisted of 15 member countries in 2000. Apart from the USA, in the table 1 there are also four other countries with the indicator higher then 70 percent of employed population. These are the United Kingdom and Denmark where the indicator has been very stable since at least 1990, Sweden where the indicator declined by about 9 percent between 1990 and 2000 and the Netherlands where there has been an acceleration of employed population by 12.5 percent since 1990. A considerable employment growth could also be observed in Ireland and Spain to 65 and 60.7 percent respectively. By contrast, in Finland employment declined by about 7 percent, to 67.4 percent of its population in 2003. The employment/population ratios of 1990 for the new members of the EU can`t be found in international statistics. In the 8 of them, liberated from the communist regime, formally everyone had been even obliged to be employed before 1990. Of course, it hadn`t been “full employment” but “unemployment on job” (Kornai, 1980). 14 years after the beginning of the economic transition, the best employment/population ratio was 67.4 percent in the Czech Republic and the worst one was in Poland: 51.2 percent. It was the worst indicator among 25 members of the EU. After the review of the data from the table 1, it is possible to lay down the following outset conclusions: - the ability to create jobs in the US economic model is stable and relatively high; in the EU it is generally lower and very different in particular member countries; - in Poland it is necessary to upgrade this ability, following the US or the best European solutions. It seems to be necessary to verify these conclusions by further analyses. 3 Table 2 Labor force participation rate in the USA and in the UE countries. Persons aged 15-64 years (percentages) 1990 2000 2003 USAa 76.5 77.2 75.8 EU-15 67.1 69.4 70.3 EU- 19c . 68.9 69.4 Austria . 71.3 71.6 Belgium 58.7 65.2 64.3 . 71.6 70.4 Denmark 82.4 80.0 79.4 Finland 76.6 74.3 74.1 France 66.0 68.0 68.2 Germanyb 67.4 71.1 71.3 Greece 59.1 63.0 63.8 . 59.9 60.6 Ireland 60.1 67.4 68.0 Italy 59.5 60.3 61.6 Luxemburg 60.1 64.2 . Netherlands 66.2 74.9 76.4 . 65.8 64.2 70.9 71.3 72.0 . 69.9 70.0 Spaina 61.7 66.7 68.5 Swedena 84.6 78.9 78.9 United Kingdom 77.8 76.6 76.6 Czech Republic Hungary Poland Portugal Slovak Republic a) refers to persons aged 16 to 64 b) data up to 1990 are for Western Germany only c) for the countries in this table only . data not available Source: OECD Employment Outlook 2004. Participation rates are calculated as the labor force divided by the total working-age population, where the count of the working-age population, the labor force, the employed and the unemployed is normally restricted to individuals 15 or 16 through 64 years of age. As the term “labor force”, used to calculate the labor force participation, considers employed as well as unemployed, the indicators in the table 2 seem to be of less importance than those in the table 1. Anyway, they confirm the outset conclusions. 4 The unemployment rate is the most important indicator used when discussing labor market problems. These rates are presented in the table 3. Table 3 Standardized unemployment rate in the USA and in EU countries. Persons aged 15-64 years (percentages) 1990 2000 2003 USAa 5.7 4.0 6.1 EU-15 8.4 8.3 7.8 EU- 25d . . 9.1 Austria . 4.7 4.7 Belgium 7.3 6.6 7.7 Cyprus . . 4.4 Czech Republic . 8.8 7.8 8.5 4.5 5.5 Estonia . 13.7 10.0 Finland 3.2 9.9 9.1 France 9.2 10.1 9.3 Germanyb 4.9 7.8 9.4 Greece 7.2 11.3 9.1 . 6.4 5.9 Ireland 13.3 4.4 4.5 Italy 11.5 10.6 8.7 Latvia . 14.5 10.5 Lithuania . 15.4 12.7 Luxemburg 1.6 2.4 . Netherlands 7.7 2.7 3.6 Poland 6.3 16.4 20.0 Portugal 4.9 4.2 6.8 . 18.8 17.6 Spaina 16.1 13.9 11.4 Sweden 1.8 5.9 5.8 United Kingdom 6.8 5.6 4.9 Denmark Hungary Slovak Republic a) refers to persons aged 16 to 64 b) data up to 1990 are for Western Germany only d) data for June 2004 . data not available Source: OECD Employment Outlook 2004, National Bank of Poland, Statistical Offices (Bureaus) of Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania, I. Kuhnert: An Overview of the Economics of the New Members States, Eurostat: www.europa.eu.int 5 Unemployment in the USA has been lower than in the EU-15 throughout the period considered. The rates of unemployment over the time were, however, far from uniform in the EU. Austria and the UK had rather stable, low rates of unemployment, whereas the Netherlands, Ireland and Denmark made a great progress reducing their rates to 3.6; 4.5 and 5.5 percent respectively, i.e. to the “American” level. The rate for Sweden rose from 1.8 percent in 1990 to 5.8 percent in 2003 but it still remains low. By contrast, the rate of unemployment grew substantially in Germany (after the unification) and in Finland from 4.9 in 1990 to 9.4 percent in 2003 and from 3.2 percent in 1990 to 9.1 percent in 2003 respectively. The average rate of unemployment is higher in the new member states of the EU. It was 14.3 percent in 2003 (Kuhnert 2004). A strong impact on this figure is made by the rate for Poland. It has been about 20 percent for last years (over 3 million adult citizens). It is the very serious problem to be solved by upgrading Poland`s ability to create jobs. The data from the table 4 remain this opinion beyond any doubts. Table 4 Incidence of long-term unemployment in the USA and in the selected EU countries (as a percentage of total unemployment) 2003 USA 11.8 EU-15 43.4 EU- 19a 45.3 Austria 24.5 Belgium 46.3 Czech Republic 49.9 Denmark 19.9 Finland 24.7 France 33.8 Germany 50.0 Greece 56.5 Hungary 42.2 Ireland 35.4 Italy 58.2 Luxemburg 27.4 Netherlands 29.2 6 Poland 52.5 Portugal 32.0 Slovak Republic 61.1 Spain 39.8 Sweden 17.8 United Kingdom 23.0 a) for above countries only Source: Eurostat: www.europa.eu.int; U.S. Department of Labor: www.bls.gov; Employment Outlook 2004. Figures from the table 4 show that in the USA only 11.8 percent of unemployed could not find a job for a longer period than 12 months. It is an evidence that the unemployment in the USA, with its rate about 6 percent is mostly frictional. It can be considered as a natural rate of unemployment. An average share of unemployment longer than a year in the total number of jobless people in the EU was about 4 times worse than in the USA in 2003. This indicator was relatively good in Sweden (17.8%), Denmark (19.9%), in the UK (23%) and in Austria (24.5%) but in the countries, where the long-term unemployment was 50 percent or even more (the Czech Republic, Germany, Poland, Greece, Italy and the Slovak Republic), it can be an evidence of strong structural unemployment and/or serious macroeconomic problems. In international reviews there are many other indicators which concern in a particular manner examining the labor issues, for example: employment/population rates by selected age groups, by educational attainment, by composition of part-time employment with women`s share in part employment; average annual hours actually worked per person in employment, public expenditure and participant inflows in labor market programs and many others. These problems deserve a separate book. In this paper, however, it seems to be necessary to examine one additional factor, i.e. tax wedges on labor. The tax wedge is the difference between what employers pay out in wages and social security charges and what employees take home after tax and social security deductions. The high tax wedge, measured as a percentage of the overall cost to an employer, can be a major obstacle to job creation and people`s willingness to work. 7 Table 5 Household Tax Wedge in the USA and in the selected EU countries in 2003 (as total labor costs equivalent to the average production worker)a One earner family with two children USA 15.5 EU-15 29.5 EU- 19b 30.4 Austria 29.5 Belgium 39.0 Czech Republic 30.6 Denmark 30.1 Finland 37.8 France 40.0 Germany 33.5 Greece 34.3 Hungary 30.5 Ireland 7.4 Italy 35.5 Luxemburg 9.6 Netherlands 33.7 Poland 41.3 Portugal 23.7 Slovak Republic 32.3 Spain 30.9 Sweden 39.5 United Kingdom 18.3 a) The tax wedge reflects income tax plus employee contribution less cash benefits plus employer social contributions. b) for above countries only Source: OECD (2004), Taxing Wages 2002-2003: www.oecd.org/document. Based on 2003 figures, for a one earner married couple with two children at the same earnings level, the tax wedge ranged from 7.4 percent in Ireland to 41.3 percent in Poland which is the only country with the indicator over 40 percent and has the worst result in the EU again. The Ireland`s indicator is two times better than the tax wedge in the USA (15.5 percent) which is, in turn, two times better than the average level in the EU. In the EU small Luxemburg and the UK also have good results, respectively 9.6 and 18.3 percent but, by 8 contrast, in the EU there are 15 countries that have the tax wage at the level of about 30 percent and more. If in any of them, the unemployment rate and the rate of long-term unemployment have been relatively low (for example in Sweden, France and Belgium) it might be a proof that a great share of employees work for public sector (or, may be, for the EU administration, as in the case of Belgium). The welfare state`s rules can also have influence on such pattern of indicators. It could be interesting if the tax wages change in the countries from the table 4. The chart A gives an answer to this question. Chart A Change in the tax wedge for a married production worker with two children from 1996 to 2003 (in percentages) Slovak Rep. Poland Austria Netherlands France Czech Rep. Denmark Germany Belgium Greece Spain Portugal Luxemburg Finland Sweden U.K. Italy U.S.A. Hungary Ireland -20 -15 -10 -5 0 5 10 % Source: As in the table 5. 9 Data in the chart A show that Ireland saw the biggest fall in the tax wedge from 1996 to 2003, with a reduction of 18.3 percent, followed by Hungary (9.9 percent), the USA (8.3 percent), Italy (8.2 percent) and the United Kingdom (7.0 percent). However, in a number of countries the tax wedge increased over the period, with seeing the biggest increase at 7.1 percent in the Slovak Republic. In Poland, with the tax wedge 41.3 percent in 2003, it rose by 1.8 percent in 1996-2003 period. Now there is no doubt that it is necessary to improve ability to create jobs in Poland. A rise in employment, however, has to be associated with a rise in productivity. The ILO report (2003) says that an output per person employed in the USA reached a level of USD 60,728 in 2002 while in the EU – 15 countries an output per person employed was USD 43,034 (about 70 percent). Improving the EU`s productivity and raising the employment rate are fundamental to achieving a more rapid rate of growth in the EU over the long term, especially in the new member countries – as it is presented in the table 6. Table 6 Labor productivity per person employed, EU-15 = 100 2002 EU-25 92.8 EU-15 100.0 New Members 52.2 Cyprus 78.3 Czech Republic 53.7 Estonia 41.8 Hungary 62.6 Latvia 37.1 Lithuania 41.9 Malta 89.8 Poland 48.8 Slovak Republic 56.2 Slovenia 68.4 Labor productivity = GDP in PPS per person employed Source: Kuhnert (2004) If overall labor productivity in the new member states is slightly above half the value observed for the EU – 15 (in Poland it is even less than half) and the EU is being held back relative to the USA in this respect of about 30 percent, the clear conclusion is that in order to create jobs and to improve the productivity it is necessary to undertake serious measures 10 concerning not only the labor market itself but the whole macroeconomy in Poland, following the US and the best European (for example Ireland`s) policies. 2. THE MAIN FEATURES OF THE U.S. AND EUROPEAN MODELS OF LABOR MARKETS As it is shown on the chart B, after the Second World War the unemployment rate has never exceeded 10 percent in the USA. The rates of unemployment on the level of natural ones as well as the shocking difference between the USA and the EU in the incidence of long term unemployment (see table 4) can be an evidence that even while large numbers of jobs are being destroyed, many others are being created in the US at the same time (Solow 2000). As the matter of fact, the difference between American and European unemployment arises from the cumulation of several differences in institutions and policies discussed by Solow (2000): - the relatively low replacement rate embodied in the US compared with most European countries – as Ostoj (2002) wrote unemployment benefits were at the level of some 12 percent of average wages in the USA while in Europe from 18 percent in the UK to 71 percent in Denmark in 1990s. - relatively short duration of benefits allowed in the USA – maximum 6 months (also in the Czech Republic and in Estonia), compared with 12 months in the UK, in Hungary and Slovakia, 24 months – for example in Spain, 36 months in Germany, 54 months in France and no limits in Belgium (The World Bank 2002), - the broad scope of legal restrictions on discharging workers in Europe which has the long-run effect of discouraging job creation; - the relatively low minimum wage in the US, which allows higher employment of lowproductivity workers at the expense of greater wage inequality (for example in the retail-trade absorbing a large number of low-productivity, low-wage workers); - the US labor market generally allows greater wage differentiation between classes of workers than in Europe; - the greater density and power of trade unions in Europe; 11 - the wider wedge of payroll taxes and social charges in Europe (except Ireland and the UK – see table 5); 12 Chart B Standardized unemployment rates in the U.S.A. (as a percentage of total labor force) % 12 10 8 6 4 2 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 1974 1972 1970 1968 1966 1964 1962 1960 1958 1956 1954 1952 1950 1948 0 Source: U.S. Department of Labor: www.bls.gov 13 - effective indexing of nominal wages in order to maintain real wages in administration or in selected branches in some European countries – as the result real wages don`t keep pace with productivity and can be an important barrier to increase employment; - generally higher product-market deregulation (of opening hours, land use, banking practices etc.) in the USA, which always helps to reduce unemployment by improving employment prospects. Of course, there are also many other factors that influence ability to create jobs and can be the subject of comparison (for example: early-retirement schemes, invalid or sick pay schemes, decentralization of wage determination, regular or temporary contracts regulations and other). Generally, most of European markets are perceived as rigid and inflexible when compared with these in North America, where legislation is less protective of employment and foster greater mobility. Additionally, the tax burden on labor in Central and Eastern European countries, the new members of the E.U., is the highest in Europe. Instead of adopting law ensuring greater flexibility of their labor markets, they devote big amounts of budgetary resources to the unemployed (The World Bank 2002). The European analysts are perfectly aware of the above problems. One can find remarks on the widening gap between the GDP per person employed between the US and the EU that is the result of a widening productivity gap between Europe and the United States as well as on the fact that in Europe employment growth stalled in 2003 and the rate of unemployment rose slightly. They pay attention to the budget deficits that increased in many countries, in some cases to levels inconsistent with long-term economic stability and to low level of investment, creating new jobs (for example: E.C. articles on Europe 2004) The Lisbon strategy has been the official and the most important EU document issued in response to these problems. The Lisbon strategy entails a variety of targets and objectives, agreed not only at the Lisbon Council itself (March 2000) but also at Stockholm (March 2001), Göteborg (June 2001) and Barcelona (March 2002). Not all are quantified or timespecific, but those, which concern employment, are the following: - an overall employment rate of 67% in 2005 (Stockholm) and 70% in 2010 (Lisbon); - a female employment rate of 57% in 2005 (Stockholm) and 60% in 2010 (Lisbon); - an employment rate for workers aged 55-64 of 50% in 2010 (Stockholm); 14 - an increase of five years by 2010 in the average effective retirement age (Barcelona); - available childcare by 2010 for 90% of pre-school children over three and for 33% of and children under three (Barcelona).(source: European Economy, July 2003, no. 4) In March 2004 the Economic Policy Committee (EPC) published its annual report on structural reforms untitled “Reinforcing implementation”. The reform priorities there are as follows: 1. Strongly promote growth-oriented economic strategies by stimulating both productivity and employment rates within a framework of sound fiscal and macroeconomic policies. Accelerated implementation of structural reforms in labor and product markets, and an effective transition to the knowledge-based economy are key to making the EU economies more competitive and dynamic. 2. Tackling structural problems in labor markets and fostering labor supply are essential to success, as the EPC identified a year ago. Progress in this area is insufficient to meet the agreed Lisbon objectives, in particular for older workers. The EPC stresses that action is needed, with the appropriate contribution of social partners in conformity with national preferences, along the lines suggested by the European Employment Taskforce by Mr.Wim Kok: o increase flexibility inter alia by promoting wage bargaining systems to allow wages to reflect better productivity differentials; o rebalance the concept of job security to emphasize improving people`s capability to gain employment and progress in work; o take action on benefit reforms (level, durations and/or eligibility and availability criteria) in addition to tax reforms already implemented, so as to make work pay. Measures need to focus on increasing labor force participation/employment as well as improving fiscal sustainability (European Economy, March 2004, no.7). However, achieving of the above targets and objectives depends on economic policy of each member state separately. 15 3. HOW TO EXPAND EMPLOYMENT AND RAISE PRODUCTIVITY IN POLAND? In the case of Poland, the improvement of labor market performance is, first of all, the question of more flexible regulations of this market. The main issue is how to expand employment, raise productivity and, in effect, how to increase per capita income that is now only 41 percent of the OECD average level in Poland. During the decade of the 1990s the economic performance of this country was one of the best among developing countries and clearly the best among economies formerly in the Soviet sphere. The recession, caused by the transition to the market economy, took only two years in Poland (1990 and 1991). Since 1992 the economy grew – in 1995 and in 1997 even by about 7 percent a year. The rate of industrial production also rose by about 12 percent in 1994 and 1997. The income per capita rose from USD 3,844 in 1991 to 8,700 in 1999 (p.p.p. indicator). Unfortunately, the Poland`s economic transition hasn`t been completed (Ćwikliński 2003). The only important and notable exception is monetary policy. Thanks to its proper strategy, the rate of inflation was reduced to 1.9 percent in 2003. Real interests, however, remain high. The state`s budget is one of the main borrowers and it is a good reason to perform researches if crowding – out effect occurs in Poland. The second stage of the economic transition is necessary in Poland because of at least two main reasons (Ćwikliński 2004): o about 2,000 Polish companies, generating about a fourth of employment and GDP, remain in state hands; o restoring public finances is an urgent matter, both to prevent the public debt from breaching the 60 percent constitutional limit and also to re-establish an appropriate balance between fiscal and monetary policy so that interest rates can be safely lowered. In 1990 when the transition was begun, there were 8,453 state – owned firms to be privatized. The total quantity of state – owned firms and, additionally, companies fully or partly owned by the state treasury in 2002 are presented in the table 7. 16 Table 7. State – owned firms and companies of the state treasury stock in Poland in 2002 Total of which Functioning 3263 2130 value of capital Going bankrupt Firms partly owned by treasury Owned by treasury (PLN billion) (PLN billion) 69.9 48.7 1133 Source: “Rzeczpospolita”, July 31st, 2003 The figures of the table 7 prove that the privatization hasn’t been still completed in Poland as the media sometimes suggests it. 38.6 percent of all enterprises in Poland are subject to collective ownership. Also, progress in the restructuring of the remaining state – controlled industries has been insufficient and the adoption of several sectoral restructuring industries hasn’t brought positive results (2003 EU Comprehensive Country Monitoring Report: Poland). Further analysis show that if we take into consideration the value of core capital, 16.7 percent of total value of all state – controlled enterprises were in the sector “electricity”, 14 percent in “crude oil and gas” and 7 percent in “financial sector”. Taking into consideration the quantity of those firms, in 2002 16.7 percent of the state – controlled ones could be found in the sector “trade” and 11 percent belonged to the sector “industry”. One third of these enterprises (1,133) were under procedure leading them to bankruptcy (where–of 813 belonged totally to the state). These were mainly firms connected with agriculture industry (60 percent) as well as light industry (56 percent), shipyard, construction and steel industries (each over 42 percent). The problem is because the state – owned enterprises have had immense debts paid actually by taxpayers. In 2002 the debts of the mining sector were of PLN 22.5 billion. In 2003 the Ministry of Economy declared it was going to pay PLN 14 billion of these debts (“Rzeczpospolita”. July 30th, 2003). Restructuring costs of this branch were estimated of further PLN 2 billion till 2006. The debts of the Polish state – owned steel industry were of about PLN 11 billion. Almost the same were debts of the Polish State Railways. Their lose was of almost PLN 8.5 billion in 2001 and PLN 10.8 billion in 2002 (“Rzeczpospolita”, Febr. 8-9th, 2003, May 7th, 2003). At the same time the state’s (actually the taxpayers’) “aid” to these sectors as well as to other ones was great. It was estimated as of PLN 2.65 billion for the mining sector and for the Polish State Railways of PLN 2.1 billion in 2001. It was the amount three times higher than the state’s spending for R&D that year. If we add “the aid” to other sectors – especially agriculture state agencies – the total value of the subsidies of the state was worth almost PLN 11 billion (1.5 percent of GDP) in 2001 (“Rzeczpospolita”, Oct. 29, 2002). 17 In 2002, among 25 companies of the highest incomes, there were more than half owned or directly managed by the state administration but many of them were making losses (Orlowski, 2003). Their incomes were the highest because of their monopolistic position or special parliament regulations. Poland still needs to finish restructuring and privatization of the state – controlled industries, in particular in the coal mining, gas, electricity, chemicals, steel and defense sector. The progress in privatization is presented in the table 8. Table 8. Privatization incomes in Poland 1997 – 2003 (PLN billion) Incomes 1997 6.6 1998 7.1 1999 13.3 2000 26.7 2001 6.8 2002 2.2 2003 3.0 Source: Ministry of Treasury, “Rzeczpospolita”, 15.4.2003, 31.7.2003 and CASE 1/2004 The data in the table 8 prove that there hasn’t been an important progress in privatization since 2001. The incomes of the privatization amounted to only 25.5 percent in 2001, 8.2 percent in 2002 and 11.2 percent of the value of the privatization earned in 2000. The slowdown in the privatization process partly reflects the fact that the most profitable firms have already been sold, and most of the remaining state firms do not easily attract investors (2003 EU Comprehensive Country Monitoring Report: Poland). The additional conditions attached to the sales, notably to safeguard employment (i.e. thousands of voters), further hamper the privatization process. Also, the state – owned companies are a good place to offer posts for comrades belonging to a governing party. This way, the whole sectors, i.e. mining, steel, chemicals, gas, agriculture and others still need considerable efforts to be restructured. A deep restructuring of public expenditure is the second, very important issue of the Polish economic transition. This issue has been too difficult for all governments in independent Poland since 1990 in the face of opposition from vested interest of bureaucrats, public sector managers and trade unions. Every election campaign after 1992 was addressed 18 to those who were against hardship of the economic transition. The results of the policy of doing nothing with restructuring of pubic expenditures have become evidently clear after the election in 2001 when the post-communist party (SLD) formed the government. The figures showing it are presented in the table 9. Table 9. Selected items of the state budget, 1999 – 2003 Revenues Total Expenditures Budget deficit of which tax revenues PLN billion % of GDP 1999 125.9 112.7 138.4 - 12.5 - 2.0 2000 135.7 119.6 151.1 - 15.4 - 2.2 2001 140.5 119.1 172.9 - 32.4 - 4.3 2002 143.5 128.8 182.9 - 39.4 - 5.1 2003 152.2 135.2 189.2 - 37.0 - 4.6 Source: Ministry of Finance, CASE 2004 In 2003 the state budget deficit was PLN 37 billion, i.e. 4.6 percent of GDP. It was the third year when the result was higher than the Maastricht criteria allow. Some 84 percent of the deficit was financed on the domestic market, mainly by revenues from treasury bonds. It should be stressed that such financing was equal to PLN 6.8 billion and therefore much higher than the planned 1.9 billion. The planned state budget deficit was underestimated due to an underestimation to extra – budgetary funds. The Labor Fund had spent its entire annual transfers by the end of September 2003, with the Social Security Fund doing the same by end of November. When their cash had gone, the activities of such funds had to be financed from commercial bank credits. As some spending remains off-budget in state funds and agencies, where it is difficult to control, this can be an example of decisions, which don’t increase the budget deficit (it is expected to be of about 5 percent of GDP in 2004 again) but reflect in public debt figures. Table 10. The public debt in Poland in 2000-2004 Public debt (as % of GDP)a 2000 42.3 2001 43.2 2002 47.2 2003 51.6 2004b 54.8 a) calculation with ESA 95 gives better results b) forecast Source: Ministry of Finance, “Rzeczpospolita” 18th.05.2004. 19 Yet the governments have made little progress on reforming public finance except reduction in the corporate income tax (CIT) rate to 19 percent in 2004. On the other hand, however, it has had to introduce for many goods and services “the ordinary rate” of VAT, which in Poland is one of the highest in the EU (22 percent), since May 1st 2004. The money of “the ordinary rate of VAT” has been one of the reasons of certain raise in inflation but it has helped the government because non – discretionary spending, for example on public sector wages, pensions and various allowances, accounts for nearly 70 percent of total public outlay. Conclusions The Lisbon Strategy and many other EU official documents can remain “wishful thinking” unless the role of politicians and government administration with their budgets is limited in particular member countries. It creates too high costs and it can be the main obstacle to further economic development. Economic freedom was one of the aims of the transition from the totalitarian Soviettype regime to free society in Poland. The achievements of the early 1990s were immense but the work hasn`t been completed. As the result, not market but the government imperfections are the main problem to be solved in Poland. These imperfections prevent private companies from investing and creating new jobs. Tackling joblessness requires policies that increase both demand and effective labor supply. Demand for labor has to be stimulated by policies that reduce firms’ cost of doing business and promote private investment. The authorities should concentrate on public expenditure reforms by improving medium – term budgetary planning and control mechanisms in order to ensure that these plans are executed and that overall savings are realized. Moreover, monitoring and parliamentary oversight of extra budgetary programs should be raised to the same level as for programs financed directly from the state budget (OECD Economic Survey of Poland, 2004). Tighter fiscal policy, by providing a more stable macroeconomic environment and allowing interest rates to fall, should make investment more affordable. Additionally, speeding-up privatization again should bring both: revenues to the budget and savings when it is not necessary to pay for losses of the state owned enterprices. In order to increase effective labor supply, following the US path and Ireland`s example of development, it is necessary to sharply reduce the passive income support provided to able-bodied individuals through the disability system and various premature labor market withdrawal schemes. Rationalizing the personal transfer system, by restricting access 20 to the disability system to persons who are actually physically unable to work, while increasing means-tested support in the social assistance system for those in need, would be a very important step toward exit from the fraudulent rules of the former Soviet system. Also reductions in the minimum wage targeted on youth and new entrants and cuts in the tax wedge for low-paid workers would help make hiring unskilled workers. There are also many other issues that can influence on the improvement of the labor market performance and reduce inactivity traps in Poland, for example benefits for unemployed, benefits and contributions from farmers and general social assistance system that need to be harmonized both to promote rural-urban migration and so as to facilitate farm consolidation. Together with improving the quality of education in rural areas it should be an essential component of a strategy to address rural poverty. Poland`s economy lost too much time for its development between 1939 and 1989 and made impressive progress in the 1990s. Now it is facing a challenge of the second stage of its transition. It can`t be a transition to any form of a welfare state. In order to cope with competitive pressure and market forces within the European Union, it is necessary to move onto a more dynamic growth path that combines rising employment with more productive jobs. The OECD (2004) estimates that unless policies change, Poland will not have achieved average OECD income levels even in 50 years from now. Bibliography 2003 EU Comprehensive Country Monitoring Report: Poland, http://europa.eu.int CASE (2004). Polish Economic Outlook, no.1 Ćwikliński H. (2003), Poland`s Incomplete Economic Transition, in “North European and Baltic Sea Integration – the NEBI Yearbook 2003”, Springer Verlag, Berlin – Heidelberg Ćwikliński H. (2004), Why the Second Stage of Polish Economic Transition Is Necessary?, a paper at the 3rd Annual Meeting of the European Economics and Finance Society, Sopot 13-16 May E.C. articles on Europe (2004), ECFIN/008/04-EN, http://europa.eu.int/comm/economy finanse/index_en.htm European Economy (July 2003, no. 4), Key structural challenges in the acceding countries: the integration of the acceding countries into the Community`s economic policy co-ordination European Economy (March 2004, no.7), Annual report on structural reforms 2004, “Reinforcing implementation” Eurostat: www.europa.eu.int 21 GUS (2003) Statistical Yearbook of the Republic of Poland ILO (2003), Key Indicators of the Labour Market, third edition, International Labour Office, Geneva Kornai J. (1980), Economics of Shortage, North-Holland Publishing Co., Amsterdam-New York-Oxford. Kuhnert I. (2004), An Overview of the Economies of the New Member States, Eurostat, theme 2-17 National Bank of Poland, http://www.nbp.pl OECD (2004), Economic Survey of Poland OECD (2004), Employment Outlook OECD (2004), Taxing Wages 2002-2003, www.oecd.org/document Orłowski M. (2003), Lista 500, Rzeczpospolita Ostój I. (2003), Rynek pracy in: Swadźba S. (ed), System gospodarczy Unii Europejskiej a poza europejskie modele gospodarcze, Katowice 2002 Rzeczpospolita 2002, 2003, the main daily Polish paper Solow R.M. (2000), Unemployment in the United States and in Europe, CESifo Working Paper Series no. 231, Munich The World Bank (2002), Labor Policy Dilemmas – Preceding EU Enlargement, Transition Newsletter, vol. 13, no. 4-5 U.S. Department of Labor, www.bls.gov 22