Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Gender and the Welfare State in China American Association of Chinese Studies (AACS) Annual Conference Rollins College, 16-18 October 2009 Tonia Warnecke Department of Economics, Rollins College [email protected] Abstract In recent years, the scope of welfare state analysis—originally focused on advanced, industrialized Western countries—has expanded to include developing countries such as China. This paper investigates the evolution of the Chinese welfare state from 1949 to the present day, incorporating a gender perspective. Of particular interest is the evolution of welfare mechanisms and their effects on gender-differentiated outcomes. The paper therefore notes the ways that economic reform and welfare reform interlink to affect women’s access to various welfare state benefits. Gendered patterns in migration and informal labor, as well as the structure of Chinese family policy (parental leave, child benefits, and childcare provision), are also examined in this context. Introduction What is social welfare? What is a welfare state? What type of welfare state (if any) do we need? The answers to these seemingly simple questions have been fervently debated for the last couple of decades, and with the growing amount of literature studying various welfare state regimes, it is even more important to remember what lies at the heart of the analysis. Social welfare generally refers to socioeconomic wellbeing. This is “correlated with the basic level of economic development, of course, but focuses more specifically on a variety of goods and services believed to be essential for individual and social happiness and security (such as health care, housing, social insurance, other employment-related benefits, and additional forms of social assistance)” (Warnecke 2008: 982). Together, the institutions and policies supporting these types of goods and services form a welfarestate regime. The welfare state defends and supports the development of social rights, aiming “to make civil rights actually work…removing the barriers that blocked the 1 full and equal exercise of civil and political rights” (Bussemaker and van Kersbergen 1999: 10). Supporting the idea of a welfare state can indicate a willingness to think about prosperity and economic security as community goals (or even community responsibilities), not merely individual ones. At the very least, it signifies an acceptance that individuals, even hard-working ones, cannot always make things work out well on their own—that they, too, might need help from the state in order to make ends meet, in order to cope with unforeseen circumstances. Reasons for instituting a welfare state range from the pragmatic (politicians want to satisfy their electorate) to the economic (improving human capital can improve economic growth) to the social (demonstrating that the state ‘cares’ can unify the citizenry) (Goodin et al. 1999: 21). Visions of the ‘ideal’ welfare state also change over time, as approaches to economic and political theory change, and as conceptualizations of development change. At any given moment, however, the precise make-up or composition of a welfare state—its priorities, its policies and its eligibility requirements for benefits—heavily influence both the livelihoods and the inequalities shaped by class, race and ethnicity, and gender (it is the latter which is the focus of this paper). In recent years, the scope of welfare state regime analysis—originally focused on advanced, industrialized Western countries—has expanded to include less-studied European regions (such as Southern and Eastern Europe), as well as newly industrialized and developing countries in other regions. This paper discusses the structure of the Chinese welfare state and its social policies, focusing on gender. The structure of welfare regimes can have a major impact on gender (in)equality via effects on labor force participation and outcomes, health and financial sustainability. In this paper, I investigate the evolution of the Chinese welfare state from 1949 to the present day, incorporating a gender perspective. Of particular interest is the evolution of welfare mechanisms and their effects on gender-differentiated outcomes. The paper therefore notes the ways that economic reform and welfare reform interlink to affect women’s access to various welfare state benefits. Gendered patterns in migration and informal labor, as well as the structure of Chinese family policy (parental leave, child benefits, and childcare provision), are also examined in this context. 2 Background: the Chinese welfare state A sizable literature on welfare state regimes attempts to explain why countries have different welfare policies, and which countries have ‘like’ welfare regimes (Esping-Andersen 1990, 1999; Huber et al. 1993; Flaquer 2000). Reasons for the diversity of welfare policies and welfare spending among different countries— whether developed, developing, or a combination—include “external debt, capital flows, and the relative power of labor,” particularities of a given region, and the extent to which a country has undergone processes of modernization (Frazier 2006: 2; see also Esping-Andersen 1990). Though these areas of research are interesting and important, they are not the focus of this paper. Instead, the focus lies on the analysis of one country—China—and how the structure and social policies of its welfare state lead to gendered outcomes. Before bringing gender into the analysis, it is important to first have an understanding of where the Chinese welfare state is today, and from where it has come. It is important to keep in mind, of course, that China is a developing country, and as such, cannot be expected at this time to have a system of social protection equivalent to that of an advanced, industrialized Anglo-American or European country. Developing countries face many constraints to welfare state formation and development, particularly spending constraints and the lack of a notion of broad-based rights to welfare (Frazier 2006). However, viewing China’s welfare state as ‘backward’ or ‘stagnant’ would be incorrect, because China’s welfare state has undergone dramatic changes—some of them progressive—in the past sixty years. In fact, one can distinguish between four main phases of the welfare state: welfare during the command economy period (under Mao) from 1949 to the late 1970s, the initial welfare reform period (under Deng Xiaoping) in the 1980s, the more fundamental welfare reform period (under Jiang) in the 1990s, and recent welfare state developments (in the last few years) pressing for a more inclusive approach. During the command economy period, welfare provision was “comprehensive and universalist, resulting in a relatively high level of social development in terms of e.g. life expectancy and literacy rates, for a low income country” (MacDermott and Kwon 2003: 19). As Guan (2000: 4) explains, the system was based on a socialist 3 ideology, and the state—not the individual—was therefore responsible for ensuring “equality, social justice, and collective action in economic and social life.” The government took full financial responsibility for providing welfare, via the enterprises it controlled (Guan 2000). The key element of the welfare system during this period was the right to employment (usually for life) in an appointed position; this ensured income security for the masses. There were other benefits as well: housing, education, health care, and pensions—but not all individuals received these benefits, and not all recipients enjoyed similar benefit levels. However, salary and benefits were largely planned together and offered together to the relevant worker groups, to compensate them for the relatively low base pay of the socialist system. Chinese welfare provision during the command economy era is often described by a three tiered system. Receiving the highest levels of benefits were civil servants and Communist Party officials; the next highest benefit levels were received by state sector workers in urban areas. The lowest benefit levels, however, went to those in rural areas, who “relied on their collectives for minimal medical care and educational resources” (Frazier 2006: 5). Rural Chinese mostly depended on family networks for social provision, and received no pensions or housing from the state. However, I would argue that a four tiered system may be a more accurate representation. This is because the above-mentioned middle tier (state sector workers) can actually be further divided into two groups: permanent state workers (or workers in state-owned enterprises, SOEs, with urban household registration), and workers in urban collectives. Lee (2005: 1) explains that these urban collectives were “enterprises that were initially set up by local government bureaus to absorb unemployed personnel or provide employment for state-dependent workers. Some were subsidiaries of state-owned firms catering to the latter’s production needs.” Since the SOEs produced a much higher proportion (75%) of total industrial output, and were protected by the state budget (while subsidiaries were not), one could argue that the benefits for SOE workers were more secure. Certainly, benefits in the collectives depended on the profitability of the enterprise, and were always less generous (Davin 2001). Thus, a four-tiered system would explain the distribution of welfare benefits according to the following order (from most to least generous/secure): (1) civil servants and Communist Party officials, (2) permanent 4 (SOE) state workers in urban areas, (3) workers in urban collectives, and (4) those in rural areas. The existence of this tiered system is significant in that it shows the discord between the socialist ideology of comprehensive welfare and the reality of a limited budget for such provisions, along with the low efficiency associated with the centrally planned system (which cast doubt on benefit sustainability). This discord was a catalyst for the economic reforms in the 1970s, which emphasized increased marketization and trade liberalization (MacDermott and Kwon 2003: 19). The economic reforms of the 1970s, which increased the country’s marketorientation, led to the second phase of the Chinese welfare state—the initial welfare reform. Interestingly, common themes of this phase of reform in China—that “emerging inequalities were tolerated as a temporary negative by-product” and that “everyone would benefit from economic growth in the long run” (Stepan 2008: 26)— are common themes from neoclassical economic theory. This is not so surprising, of course, given that neoclassical economists in the West, bolstered by the newly conservative political economy of Ronald Reagan in the US and Margaret Thatcher in the UK, were in a full-court press around the world for precisely the types of economic reforms that China had been undertaking. In this first stage of reform, then, China was following some of the same strategies as capitalist, democratic economies in the West: defining economic development in terms of growth (rather than a more holistic conceptualization of development as ‘human development’ or ‘equitable development’). The initial welfare reform focused mostly on fixing the ‘institutional dysfunctions caused by the economic reform” (MacDermott and Kwon 2003: 19). Prior to welfare reform, the state had been in charge of funding the benefit system. However, the economic reform transformed state-owned enterprises into independent businesses; the state was no longer responsible for reimbursing firms for benefit expenses, and many firms did not believe they would be able to continue offering pension and health benefits. Experiments with pooling systems and free medical care were tried in some instances (Guan 2000: 5). In general, the initial economic reform resulted in a pull-back of the state from financing welfare. 5 The 1990s, however, represented a more fundamental period of welfare reform, solidifying the neoliberal trends of benefit privatization and marketization, and a reduced financial role for the state. This period of reform coincided with an effort to develop a real ‘Chinese’ welfare state based on established goals, rather than responding piecemeal to difficulties created for the welfare system by the economic reforms of the 1970s (Guan 2000). During this period, the state moved most benefit schemes in China from non-contributory to contributory status. In other words, many welfare benefits—particularly pensions and health care—became the financial responsibility of individuals and firms. Not all groups of workers were covered. Furthermore, increased marketization meant that prices increased for benefits, goods and services as government price ceilings and rationing schemes were eliminated. The most fundamental welfare change during this period, though, was the end of the full-employment policy with lifetime employment guarantee. Instead, a new contract labor system emerged, signifying the risk of being laid-off while also providing certain unemployment benefits (again, such benefits usually were targeted at the urban sector). The welfare reforms of the 1990s left China in between a ‘private welfare’ model and a ‘state welfare’ model. According to Guan (2000: 11), “Although there are some similarities between the welfare societalization in China and welfare privatization in some other developing countries, a fundamental difference is that in China most of the welfare institutions are still kept public owned as far as their property rights are concerned. Under the current situation, the non-governmental sector is still very weak and lacks the institutional infrastructure to achieve a thoroughly private welfare model. Government allows and even encourages non-governmental actors to participate in its traditional fields of activity, just because it hopes that financial responsibilities will thus be shared and welfare activities will become more efficient.” One legacy of the command economy model, a weak private sector, has therefore made it difficult for China to develop a true ‘private welfare’ model, as it was pushing towards in the 1990s. Interestingly, though, in recent years the Chinese government seems to be questioning whether the ‘private welfare’ model is the right path for China after all. 6 As we move farther into the new century, China has undergone some changes in thinking about its welfare state. The fourth phase of the welfare state—which only recently has begun—coincides with a growing realization (both national and international) of the increasing inequality within the country, which has been associated with the earlier reforms (of both the economy and the welfare system). This has called into question the previously held belief that economic growth is the most important development goal, and is one reason why a panel of 208 Chinese experts recently claimed that “China is likely to become a welfare state in the next 40 years,” with universal medical care, old age pensions, and minimum living allowances for all urban and rural residents (China View 2008). The government has made some concrete steps to achieve ‘growth with equity’ and reduce the rural-urban gap, such as a new cooperative health care program (established in 2003) for rural residents; the scheme “now covers 91% of total farmers and 98% of rural areas” (China View 2008). In addition, a rural minimum living allowance system (for all provinces, autonomous regions and municipalities in China) was formally established in 2007 (Ibid.). Some scholars are quite optimistic about these changes; for example, Stepan (2008: 28) argues that the idea of a “harmonious socialist society” (the new idea of the Chinese welfare state of the future) “shows more similarities with the paradigm of the EU social policy...than with any of the established [welfare] regime types.” Other scholars, such as Frazier (2006), are much less optimistic, noting that the high benefit coverage rates presented by the state are attained by excluding many groups—migrant labor, small entrepreneurs, laid-off workers, and informal sector workers—from official statistics. According to Frazier (2006: 8), the actual coverage rate (calculated by dividing the number of eligible workers by the labor force of a given locality) is “usually about 50% for pensions, and lower...for medical insurance.” Therefore, the new benefit schemes are considerably less effective than they may appear, and there is a significant chasm between the ‘face’ of China’s welfare state and how it actually functions. Furthermore, the cooptation of the sole legal union in China (the All China Federation of Trade Unions, ACFTU) by the state has strongly tilted “the balance of power further toward the employers” (Lee 2005: 18), giving employees less recourse for defending and maintaining their rights and benefits. A ‘wait-and-see’ approach is likely in order here, since the state’s recent 7 change in perspective on the welfare state is too new to assess properly at this point in time. The evolution of the Chinese welfare state from a gender perspective While the four-tiered system of welfare provision (discussed above) is helpful to distinguish among rural and urban benefits, and benefits accorded to different worker groups, it is less helpful for understanding how China’s welfare state relates to gender. Yet this occurs in many ways. For one thing, the structure of a welfare state influences labor force participation and labor force outcomes for both men and women. Furthermore, if the welfare system relies heavily on the family as welfare provider (instead of the state), this is likely to unduly burden women of the household – especially given socio-cultural norms which assume that females undertake the majority of unpaid labor around the house. A “culture of paternalism is bound to influence two crucial things: the way that development agendas unfold, and the way that social welfare policies are structured” (Warnecke and DeRuyter 2008: 3). Paternalism is “a system under which an authority undertakes to supply needs or regulate conduct of those under its control in matters affecting them as individuals as well as in their relations to authority and to each other” (Merriam-Webster 2008). Paternalism has often been taken to mean ‘behaving like a father’ or ‘treating someone like a child’ (Suber 1999). It implies the existence of a hierarchy (or hierarchies) of power. Although this means that the concept of paternalism is easily applied to the state-citizenry relationship in various political systems, feminist literature focuses on power hierarchies among men and women—linking paternalism to inequities within the household. This casts the global emphasis today on paid (and to a lesser degree, formal) work in a whole new light, given that development is often conceptualized in terms of GDP growth—and national income accounting (which calculates GDP figures) does not include the category of unpaid labor. Furthermore, socio-cultural and gender norms are bound to affect the way that social welfare policies, including family policies, are structured. Though the perception of communism as a viable alternative to capitalism has largely been derided since the fall of the Soviet Union, a gender perspective would note that communist societies could have better women’s rights than capitalist societies do, at least in theory (Rapley 2007). In communist systems, employment 8 guarantees apply to women as well as men, as do other welfare benefits; there is a universal approach. Furthermore, certain benefits were provided more consistently during the command economy period in China (as compared to today), such as paid maternity leave for all state employees (Davin 2001). However, gender still influenced welfare provision and labor market outcomes during this period. Recall that in the command economy era, there were two main groups of urban workers (excluding the Communist Party officials and civil servants): the permanent state employees working in SOEs, and those working in urban collectives and SOE subsidiaries. While the permanent state workers received more stable benefits, women constituted only 32% of this group. In contrast, women comprised 57% of those working in urban collectives or SOE subsidiaries (Lee 2005). According to Lee (2005: 2), “Gender inequalities...were manifested in pay disparity, occupational and job segregation, and welfare gaps, despite state efforts to increase women’s labor force participation rates. On the eve of reform, women’s average wage was 83 per cent that of men’s; the male-female ratio of Communist Party membership was 2:1 and male-headed households were given priority in terms of welfare housing allocations.” Even though ‘universalist’ thinking about welfare did not lead to gender-equitable outcomes during Mao’s leadership, after the command economy period, the situation actually worsened in many policy areas. This can largely be attributed to the genderbiased customs and legislation carried over from the command economy era, combined with the consequences of the ‘growth before equity’ strategy of the first two rounds of welfare reform. For example, the gendered allocation of housing during Mao’s reign still undermines women’s ability to own their own homes today (Lee 2005; Davin 2001). Another carry-over from the command economy period is the lower mandated retirement age for women; women were (and are still) required to retire at age 55, while the retirement age for men is 60 years of age. This means that men are able to build up more tenure in a position, gain more seniority, and ultimately receive a much higher pension than Chinese women—since pensions are “calculated as a proportion of final salary” (Davin 2001: 6). 9 The welfare reforms of the 1980s and 1990s also led to gendered outcomes because of the switch away from a (theoretically) ‘universalist’ approach to welfare provision. The new individualist approach means that benefits are generally connected to one’s status as a worker, not as a citizen. However, these welfare reforms coincided with an increasing gender wage gap in China; by 1999, women’s average wage had fallen to 70 per cent that of men’s (World Bank 2002).1 This would be expected to lead to gender gaps in benefit provision for employed women and men. However, the individualist approach also creates problems for women who may not work (for any reason); such women must then rely on their husbands for benefits—fostering a position of dependency (Warnecke 2008).2 The fact that women are still largely viewed to be secondary income earners within a male breadwinner household, (and thus women’s career opportunities are not taken as seriously as those of men), exacerbates these problems (Liu 2007: 128-30). Today, the dependency of females on their husbands (and other male relatives) for benefits and social protection also applies to land ownership in China. In the command economy period, rural residents were able to stay on and work a specified plot of land for a period of time—first 3 years and then 15. During the reforms of the 1980s, however, the 1988 Revised Land Administration Law specified that “land is contracted for 30 years with no adjustments” (Lee 2005: 28). While allowing for longer tenure sounds good in theory, there are gender implications. By restricting all adjustments to land ownership, women now have trouble gaining rights to a plot of land for which ownership should rightfully be adjusted due to the death of a male relative (Li and Bruce 2005: 323). In “the absence of detailed instructions ensuring women’s rights, local communities routinely deprive women of access and rights to land” in these situations (Li and Bruce 2005: 322). The problem is exacerbated by the post-command economy custom of titling land to the male head of household (not to both man and wife). Therefore, social and cultural norms govern land ownership as much as national laws do. 1 The increasing reliance on temporary positions and informal labor in China (and the socio-cultural norms allocating these ‘worse jobs’ to women) can help to explain this outcome. This will be discussed further in the next section. 2 Of course, single mothers face the most challenges in this type of system. 10 Gendered patterns of migration, informal employment and welfare state benefits Gender-differentiated welfare outcomes can also be linked to changing patterns of migration and the growing incidence of informal labor in China (both are associated with the previous economic reforms). As previously mentioned, coverage ratios for benefits in China exclude several categories of workers, yet women constitute a significant proportion of some of these categories—particularly migrant workers and informal workers. Although the number of migrants in any country is notoriously difficult to measure, many scholars estimate that migration within China is becoming increasingly feminized. In fact, “recently the rate of increase of female out-migration surpassed that of males, although the absolute number of male migrants still exceeds that of females” (World Bank 2002: 15). While in 2000 47.5% of all migrant workers were thought to be women, in certain regions female migrants vastly outnumber male migrants; in Shenzhen, women account for 65.6% of all migrants (Lee 2005: 5). China’s increase in female migration can partially be attributed to the large— and growing—role of Special Economic Zones (SEZs), which are export-processing zones. Export processing zones commonly prefer to hire women due to longstanding stereotypes of their nimble fingers and docile nature (Churchill 2004); about 80% of SEZ workers in China are women (Knox 1997). By contributing to economic growth, export processing zones are entitled to several government concessions, including evasion of wage and labor laws (Engman et al. 2007). In terms of welfare benefits, however, Davin (2001: 7) argues that “migrants tend not to be covered at all;” most SEZ workers are temporary workers, and only ‘permanent’ workers (most of whom are not migrants because they have grown up in the SEZ area) receive benefits. Another phenomenon to consider here is the high incidence of informal employment in China. While informal employment is widely associated with low wages and poor working conditions, it also poses problems for women’s ability to access benefits of the welfare state. In 2004, nearly 60% of urban employment was informal employment (employment outside the state and private sectors); this represents a dramatic increase from just over 20% in 1994 (Li and Kumar 2007). There is currently no institutionalization of welfare benefits for informal workers in China, which disproportionately harms women since they constitute a large proportion of workers in China’s informal sector (Cooke 2005). 11 So far, we have seen that the combination of economic reform and welfare reform has led to a situation where women are disproportionately disadvantaged by the structure of China’s welfare state. Now, a special focus on one aspect of social protection—family policy—will provide some additional insight regarding the impact of China’s welfare state on women’s labor force outcomes. Family Policy in China A welfare state’s family policies—maternal/parental leave, child benefits, and childcare provision—greatly influence female labor force participation by either promoting or discouraging the employment of mothers (Warnecke 2008). Studies show that parental leaves shorter than 20 weeks increase female participation, while longer parental leaves decrease the probability of a mother returning to work; likewise, childcare subsidies boost female participation, but child benefits reduce it (Jaumotte 2003: 1,8).3 Therefore, it is the combination of family policies which matters. If policymakers adhere to traditional conceptions of the gender division of labor, little state assistance may be given to enable women to balance work with family life. This essentially forces women to choose between working outside the home and raising a family.4 Parental leave Despite Chinese Labour Law provisions for 90 days of paid maternity leave (Bowen et al. 2007: 272); there do not appear to be any effective means of sanctioning such regulations to promote paid maternity leave in China (Nielsen et al. 2005: 360). In fact, external audits of various manufacturing companies have noted several violations of these provisions—for example, providing maternity leave only to management staff (MIMCO 2000). Even though Article 26 of the Law of the People's Republic of China on the Protection of Rights and Interests of Women states, “No 3 This apparent contradiction can be explained in neoclassical economics by the income and substitution effects. The income effect is exemplified by the child benefit. This benefit (a cash transfer) increases the household income level, which increases demand for all normal goods— including nonmarket goods (e.g., leisure time). To satisfy the demand for nonmarket goods, fewer labor hours are supplied to the market. (Free time becomes more affordable.) In contrast, childcare subsidies reduce the price of childcare. Since childcare costs are essentially a tax on market earnings, the subsidy acts to increase the real wage. By raising the rate of return to market labor, market labor becomes more attractive—causing women to substitute market work for nonmarket work. 4 The female economic activity rate in China has fallen for the last 15 years; the 2008 rate was 70.4 % (ILO 2008, http://laborsta.ilo.org). During this period, the male economic activity rate has consistently been 10-15% higher than the female rate. 12 unit may dismiss woman staff and workers or unilaterally terminate labor contracts with them by reason of marriage, pregnancy, maternity leave or baby-nursing,” there is evidence to suggest that women are increasingly pressured to defer marriage and childbirth in order to retain their jobs (China Daily 2006). Due to the lack of labor law enforcement, when women (particularly rural migrant women) become pregnant it is simply easier to substitute them with replacement workers rather than pay them maternity leave (Nielsen et al. 2005: 360). Such trends reinforce the (involuntary) decision to either work or bear children, but not combine the two. Child benefits Evidence suggests similar ingrained obstacles to the provision of child benefits, given the erosion of the social support system in the transition to a market economy. Because of governmental control over family planning, it is difficult to compare child benefits in China with those in other countries. It is true that in some provinces (Southwest China’s Yunnan province, for example), families who sign an agreement to have only one child do receive a cash benefit of 1,000 yuan— approximately $146 USD (China Daily 2004). The rewards for adhering to the ‘one child’ policy are not limited to cash; they “include an exemption of education fees, additions to their child's scores in college entrance exams and advantages towards additional education” (Ibid.; see also Bowen et al. 2007). Instead of focusing on such child benefits, one could, however, also refer to ‘child penalties’ to families violating the ‘one child’ policy. For example, social fostering or maintenance fees, often called ‘family planning fines’ in the West, are imposed on families who have more than one child if they were not approved to do so. In Beijing, fines are based upon the average per capita income—and are usually between three to eight times that figure (Gilbert 2009). Such fines can easily cripple a family for life. In Guangxi, police had “frozen the bank accounts of alleged violators [of the one child policy] and given them an ultimatum of paying up or having their life savings confiscated” (Ni 2007). Put in this context, child benefits and child penalties in China are intended to illustrate government control over fertility and childbearing decisions. As such, the ways that family allowances could affect female labor force participation have not entered the equation. 13 Childcare provision Theoretically, the “one child” policy could affect childcare provision in various ways. On one level, it would be expected to ease the demand for childcare provision, as family sizes shrank. However, on another level it could be argued that this policy only serves to reinforce attitudes that the problems women face in family duties are somehow minimal compared to women in other countries and hence that childcare support measures should be minimal,5 reinforcing the traditional Confucian bias against women (Bowen et al. 2007). Keeping this in mind, it should not be surprising that China lacks a specified governmental framework for child care. The child protection agencies are often affiliated to non-governmental organizations, but “without an integrative and specified government administration in child care work, the state cannot efficiently supervise and regulate public (primarily affiliated to working units or schools) or private child care. Moreover, given its weak administrative basis, the financing of child care and child service is vulnerable” (Gao 2009: 12). Therefore, a significant portion of child care in China is provided on an unpaid basis by relatives. In fact, Kilburn and Datar (2002: 7) estimate that 29% of families using child care in China do not pay for it. While paid child care is heavily subsidized by the state, these subsidies are not available to all families. Usually the subsidies are targeted at public sector (government) workers and workers in state-owned enterprises (Gao 2009). In contrast to many Western industrial nations, however, where women are disproportionately represented in public sector jobs, in China more women work for non-governmental or non-state-owned enterprises—and thus are less likely to receive any child care assistance (Gao 2009: 13). This creates wide gaps between households that receive child care subsidies—who spend only about 0.4% of their income on the service (Kilburn and Datar 2002: 7)—and households that do not. Nonetheless, overall child care availability is still quite limited in China, with only 1 in 4 children in urban areas (and 1 in 7 children in rural areas) living in a community with some type of child care center (Kilburn and Datar 2002). Even more See Clancy, M. and Tata, J. “A Global Perspective on Balancing Work and Family”, at http://www.midwestacademy.org/Proceedings/2005/papers/Clancy%20and%20Tata%20%20revision.doc 5 14 telling, however, is the take-up rate for child care. Analyzing four waves of longitudinal data from the China Health and Nutrition Survey, Kilburn and Datar (2002) examine the child care take-up rate for the 0 to 5 age group. They find that in urban areas, 16 percent of children receive care at child care centers, compared to only 3 percent of children in rural areas. This poses a significant problem for mothers trying to engage in waged work outside the home. Conclusion During the command economy era in China, the ‘universalist’ theory of welfare provision did not translate into universal benefits for all groups of people. Though many divisions existed in terms of benefit levels and access (including divisions based on residence and place of work), it is still important to note cultural and institutional biases against women during this period. Despite the shift to a market economy and rapid economic growth, these gender biases remain in China. The economic reforms worsened gender wage gaps and led to the societal marginalization of migrants and informal workers, many of whom were (and still are) women unable to access welfare state benefits. Furthermore, family policies (an important aspect of any welfare state) are not structured in a way that can support simultaneous labor force participation and childbearing for women. Thus, China can still be considered as paternalist and patriarchal in its approach to development and welfare provision. It is true, of course, that China has embraced a new ‘face’ of the welfare state, in response to public and international outcry regarding its rising inequality. While this could result in significant change (for all Chinese, including women), not enough time has passed for the country to demonstrate what this ‘Chinese socialist welfare state’ will look like. References Bowen, C., Yan Wu, C. and Scherer, R. (2007), ‘Holding up half of the sky? Attitudes toward women as managers in the People's Republic of China,’ International Journal of Human Resource Management, 18(2): 268-83. Bussemaker, J. and K. Van Kersbergen (1999), ‘Contemporary social-capitalist welfare states and gender inequality’, in D. Sainsbury (ed.), Gender and Welfare State Regimes, Oxford: Oxford University Press. China Daily (2004), ‘Cash reward offered to one-child families,’ June 9. 15 China Daily (2006), ‘Firing Provokes Debate on Maternity Rights,’ November 3. China View (2008), ‘China to become a welfare state by 2049,’ accessed online 9/20/09: http://news.xinhuanet.com/english/2008-11/02/content_10295173.htm Churchill, N. (2004), ‘Maquiladoras, migration, and daily life: women and work in the contemporary Mexican political economy,’ in D. Aguilar and A. Lacsamana (eds.), Women and globalization, Amherst, NY: Humanity Books, pp. 120-153. Cooke, F.L. (2005), HRM, work, and employment in China, London: Routledge. Davin, D. (2001), ‘The impact of export-oriented manufacturing on Chinese women workers’, Geneva: United Nations Research Institute for Social Development. Engman, M., Onodera, O., and Pinali, E. (2007), ‘Export Processing Zones: past and future role in trade and development,’ OECD Trade Policy Working Paper No. 53, Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, pp. 5-17, 61-64. Esping-Andersen, G. (1990), The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, Cambridge: Polity Press. Esping-Andersen, G. (1999), Social Foundations of Postindustrial Economies, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Flaquer, L. (2000), ‘Family Policy and Welfare State in Southern Europe,’ Barcelona: Universitat Autónoma de Barcelona (Institut de Ciéncies Polítiques i Socials), accessed online 7/5/09: www.diba.es/icps/working_papers/docs/WP_I_185.pdf Frazier, M.W. (2006), ‘Welfare State Building: China in comparative perspective’, paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, August 31-September 3, 2006. Gao, X. (2009), ‘Child Care Subsidy Policies: Contribution and Challenge, in the U.S. and China,’ presented at the APPAM Special Conference on Asian Social Protection in Comparative Perspective, Singapore. Gilbert, K. (2009). “Chinese government to increase fines for violating one-child policy.” Accessed online 8/9/09: http://www.silentfalldocumentary.com/abortionnews/56-chinese-government-to-increase-fines-for-violating-one-child-policy Goodin, R.E., Headey, B., Muffels, R., and Dirven, H-J (1999), The Real Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Guan, X. (2000), ‘China’s social policy: reform and development in the context of marketization and globalization’, Geneva: United Nations Research Institute for Social Development. Jaumotte, F. (2003), ‘Female Labour Force Participation: Past Trends and Main Determinants in OECD Countries,’ Working Paper 376, OECD Economics Department. 16 Kilburn, M.R., and Datar, A. (2002), ‘The Availability of Child Care Centers in China and its Impact on Child Care and Maternal Work Decisions,’ Labor and Population Program Working Paper Series 02-12, RAND. Knox, A. (1997), Southern China: Migrant Workers and economic transformation, London: Catholic Institute for International Relations. Lee, C.K. (2005), ‘Livelihood struggles and market reform: (Un)making Chinese labour after state socialism’, Geneva: United Nations Research Institute for Social Development. Li, B. and Kumar, S. (2007), ‘Urban labour market changes and social protection for urban informal workers: challenges for China and India’, in F. Wu (ed.), China’s emerging cities: the making of new urbanism. London: Routledge. Li, Z. And Bruce, J. (2005), ‘Gender, landlessness and equity in rural China’, in P. Ho (ed.), Developmental dilemmas: Land reform and institutional change in China. Oxon, UK and New York: Routledge. Liu, J. (2007), ‘Gender dynamics and redundancy in urban China,’ Feminist Economics, 13(3): 125-58. MacDermott, J., and H. Kwon (2003), ‘Social policy in a development context: transforming the developmental welfare state in East Asia’, Report of the UNRISD workshop (30 June-1 July), Geneva: United Nations Research Institute for Social Development. MIMCO (2000), ‘Follow-up Audit Report for Guan Yao (Zhongmei) Plant And Chang An (Meitai) Plant,’ New York: Mattel Independent Monitoring Council for Global Manufacturing Principles. Ni, C-C. (2007), ‘China’s one-child policy spurs riots,’ Los Angeles Times, May 24. Rapley, J. (2007), Understanding Development: Theory and Practice in the Third World (3rd edition), Boulder and London: Lynne Rienner Publishers. Stepan, M. (2008), The development of the Chinese welfare state and the prospects of EU policy diffusion, Rotterdam: Erasmus University. Suber, P. (1999), ‘Paternalism’, in C.B. Gray (ed.), Philosophy of Law: An Encyclopedia, Garland Pub. Co: 632-635. Warnecke, T. (2008), ‘Women as Wives, Mothers or Workers: How Welfare Eligibility Requirements Influence Female Labor Force Participation – A Case Study of Spain’, Journal of Economic Issues, 42(4): 981-1004. Warnecke, T. and A. DeRuyter (2008), ‘Paternalism and development: expanding the analysis of welfare regimes in Southern Europe and Asia’, Paper presented at the Association for Public Policy and Management special international conference, Asian Social Protection in Comparative Perspective, Singapore, January 7-9, 2009. World Bank (2002), China: Country Gender Review, Washington, DC: World Bank. 17