Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Annex 2 -63- PEACE DIVIDEND ANALYSIS OF MILITARY DEMOBILIZATION A. Introduction 1. Background. Cambodia’s two recent attempts at demobilization have not materialized. In 1993, the four fighting factions were to unite and demobilize from a unified army under UNTAC supervision. The eventual refusal of the Khmer Rouge to participate in this program led to incomplete demilitarization and in fact prolonged the armed conflict. In 1995-96, the government prepared the comprehensive Cambodia Veterans Assistance Program (CVAP) which also foresaw the reintegration into civilian life of several thousand Khmer Rouge defectors. Owing to the political turbulence that led the July 1997 events, the CVAP has yet to be implemented. 2. As a result of these two aborted demobilization attempts, defense continues to absorb a large portion of government resources, thereby preempting developmental expenditures. Table 1 clearly demonstrates the very high portion of defense expenditures compared with other countries. Table 1: Central Government Budget - International Comparison 1/ Country Cambodia India Syria Yemen Turkey Philippines Guatemala Croatia Defense (%) Social (%) 44.4 14.5 28.2 30.3 15.8 10.6 15.2 21.1 21.7 11.9 26.8 30.8 21.6 26.3 38.4 60.9 Def./soc. 2.04 1.22 1.05 0.98 0.73 0.40 0.40 0.35 Country Cameroon Mongolia Malaysia Kenya Albania Ghana Indonesia Sri Lanka Defense (%) Social (%) Def./soc. 9.4 11.5 12.7 6.2 7.1 4.9 6.2 2.6 29.0 38.8 48.0 27.1 40.2 42.3 70.4 46.2 0.32 0.30 0.26 0.23 0.18 0.12 0.09 0.06 1/ For other countries, data are for 1995 or the most recent year; for Cambodia, data are for 1995. Source: World Bank, World Development Report 1997. 3. Objective. The objective of this Chapter is twofold. First, defense expenditure is analyzed in relation to key economic and financial data to assess the importance of reining and rationalizing defense expenditure in economic development, thereby identifying a financial rationale for demobilization. Second, the dimensions and financial benefits of implementing the CVAP are investigated under different demobilization scenarios, from a comparative static and a dynamic vantage point. The aim is to assess the long-term sustainability of military restructuring relative to economic development. 4. Data Sources. Accuracy in military expenditure data in developing countries is almost always an elusive goal. Military investment often bypasses the official budget. The size of the army is frequently overstated by the military so that certain individuals can benefit from payments to “ghost soldiers”. Where average army wages are low, such overstatement may be a deliberate decision by unit commanders to enable them to more properly feed and house their troops. In Cambodia, the government budget does not include military investment data, and no attempt is made here to trace any such possible expenses. This chapter deals with recurrent data only. 5. Three main sources are used for analysis: (i) staff estimates and projections of GDP and other macroeconomic data based on data provided by the government; (ii) the government’s official budget data; and (iii) data on army size and remuneration by rank from the Royal Cambodian Armed Forces -64(RCAF). Not surprisingly, deviations--sometimes substantial--arise during the comparison of data analyzed from these three sources. 6. Particular uncertainty pertains to the size of the army, which is officially estimated in early 1998 to have been over 138,000. However, the identification and registration process planned under the CVAP has not yet been initiated. Hence, actual numbers may be higher (in particular when local militia have been included) or lower. As a result of such data limitations, this discussion is not intended to be precise in its estimations. Rather, it attempts to give indications of the order of magnitude as much as possible. B. Analysis of Defense Expenditure 7. Throughout the 1994-97 period, recurrent defense expenditure decreased in real terms, from CR 392 billion in 1994 to CR 305 billion in 1997 (in 1997 prices). This decrease is almost entirely due to the reduction in non-wages, whereas wages essentially remained constant at an average of around CR 200 billion. Between 1994 and 1997, non-wages declined from CR 194 billion to CR 96 billion. In relative terms, the share of wages and non-wages in the recurrent defense budget changed from 49.5 percent each in 1994, to 66.5 percent for wages and 31.4 percent for non-wages in 1997. This reduction reflects the RCAF's intention to maintain, to the extent possible, the troops while suspending many administrative functions (Table 2). Table 2: Recurrent Defense Expenditure (millions of riel in 1997 prices) Salaries and indemnities Administration Public interventions Total 1994 1995 1996 1997 194,103 194,008 3,728 391,839 223,143 153,763 4,446 381,352 197,196 114,489 6,545 318,230 202,567 95,556 6,620 304,743 Source: Data provided by the government. 8. The share of national defense in the government’s recurrent expenditure has been decreasing fairly steadily. National defense accounted for 37.3 percent of total recurrent expenditure in 1997, down from 46.4 percent in 1994. Combined, public security and national defense reached a staggering 58.6 percent in 1994, and remained above 50 percent throughout the period. Over 1994-97, the share of national defense in GDP decreased from 5.0 percent in 1994 to 3.3 percent in 1997. 9. In 1997 the share of social and economic services in the government’s recurrent budget reached 23.5 percent and 7.5 percent, respectively. Combined, they reached only about 80 percent of defense spending that year, up from almost two-thirds in 1994. Similarly, defense expenditure in real terms per person decreased from around CR 40,000 in 1994 to CR 29,000 in 1997 (Table 3). Yet, defense’s importance remains striking. Comparing recurrent defense expenditure to the government’s fiscal situation, recurrent defense expenditure represented, on average, over 60 percent of the overall deficit during the 1995-97 period. (It should be noted that these expenditures included some spending of social and economic nature such as allocations for the families of defected Khmer Rouge soldiers and infrastructure rehabilitation for them.) Overall, total recurrent expenditure decreased from CR 861 billion in 1996 to CR 816 billion in 1997. Noteworthy in this respect is the nominal increase of 4.4 percent in 1997 in defense expenditure when social services and economic services decreased by 3.8 -65percent and 16.9 percent, respectively, reflecting the events of July 1997 and the subsequent increase in the officially estimated size of the RCAF from 125,000 in 1996 to 138,000 in 1998.1 Table 3: Defense and Social/Economic Services Defense/GDP Social Services/GDP Economic Services/GDP Defense/Social Services Defense/Economic Services Defense/Social and Economic Services Real Per Capita Defense Expenditure (riel) 1994 1995 1996 1997 5.0% 2.3% 0.8% 4.5% 2.2% 0.7% 3.6% 2.4% 0.9% 3.3% 2.1% 0.7% 2.2 6.2 1.6 2.0 6.2 1.5 1.5 4.0 1.1 1.6 5.0 1.2 39,984 38,135 31,199 29,023 Source: Staff estimates. 10. Defense wages and Non-wages. Army wages include a salary and a variety of indemnities: (i) a 20 percent bonus on the base wage, which differs by rank; (ii) monthly child and spouse allowances; (iii) a daily food allowance; (iv) a monthly rice ration; and (v) an annual clothing allowance. All allowances and rations are independent of rank. A socioeconomic profile developed in 1995-96 in the preparation of the CVAP determined that a soldier has on average 2.8 children and that two-thirds of soldiers are married. With these assumptions and using RCAF data, per capita allowances and rations, monetized, amount to CR 805,500 annually. 11. This amount compares to median salaries (including bonus) of CR 820,800 for generals and CR 300,960 for privates. Because of the substantial allowances and rations, the official wage structure is fairly egalitarian, with median annual wages ranging from CR 1.6 million for generals to CR 1.1 million for privates. The total wage bill amounts to an estimated CR 163 billion, leading to an average wage of 1.2 million annually.2 This compares with an estimated CR 867,000 per capita GDP in 1997. The average family size as determined by the socioeconomic profile was 4.5. If a soldier was the sole breadwinner in a family, his wage would be abysmally low and completely insufficient to cover daily needs. C. Cambodia Veterans Assistance Program 1 An estimated 20,000 Khmer Rouge fighters have joined the RCAF since the short civil war in 1997. The number of FUNCINPEC soldiers currently in exile or in the bush as well as the remainder of the Khmer Rouge is not known. Hence, the figure of 138,000 may be more an indication of the potential maximum size of the RCAF with all groups incorporated, rather than its actual strength. 2 Comparing budget and RCAF data leads to an interesting observation. Using RCAF data, the wage bill amounts to CR 163 billion whereas salaries and indemnities as reported in the budget amounted to 203 billion in 1997. The budgeted average wage is thus CR 1.5 million, or one-quarter higher. Possible explanations for this difference, which cannot be clarified from either source, may include: the inclusion in the budget (but not in the RCAF) of local militia, a change in the socioeconomic profile of RCAF soldiers, an underestimate of the official RCAF size (up to a maximum of 34,100), and/or the diversion of funds to other uses (up to a maximum of CR 40 billion). Using budget data it is also interesting to note that the average wage decreased from CR 1.6 million in 1996 to approximately 1.4 million in 1997, given the absorption of defected Khmer Rouge fighters. -66- 12. The CVAP foresaw the demobilization in three phases and the subsequent reintegration into civilian life of 40,000 RCAF soldiers as well as the reintegration of 3,000 additional Khmer Rouge defectors. The program included the provision of a transitional safety net (“departure allowance”) for the most critical reinsertion phase as well as support for their social and economic reintegration, with a focus on the disabled and chronically ill. The total departure allowance was calculated at CR 2.25 million per soldier (US$900 at 1996 exchange rates), irrespective of rank or years of service. On a per capita basis, these US$900 would have placed a veteran’s family in the upper fourth decile of the country’s income distribution scale. Total program costs were estimated at US$72.7 million. The government remains committed to the CVAP as a sign of both demilitarizing society and restructuring public expenditure toward productive purposes. 13. Scenarios. Using the parameters of the CVAP, the program would reduce the RCAF by 43,000, from 138,500 to 95,500 (Scenario 1). The current rank structure is biased in favor of higher ranks; hence, demobilization would reduce the number of generals and commissioned officers by almost 29,000. In comparison, the ranks of non-commissioned officers and privates would be reduced by only 14,000, increasing their share in the post-demobilization RCAF to almost three-quarters. However, the events of 1997/98 led to the defection of Khmer Rouge fighters and their subsequent incorporation into the armed forces. Hence, the CVAP requires updating, especially regarding the number of soldiers (and defectors) to be demobilized. For illustrative purposes, therefore, an additional analysis was undertaken, assuming the demobilization of 78,300 soldiers, to reach a force of 60,200 (Scenario 2). The calculations for both scenarios and methods assume that wage and non-wage costs per soldier do not increase in real term as a result of demobilization. 14. Methods. The budgetary impact of both scenarios is calculated using two methods: (i) a static analysis and (ii) a dynamic analysis. The static analysis presents a hypothetical case which assumes that other government expenditures remain constant. It determines the effect of military downsizing if the CVAP were implemented within one year. Though unrealistic, the static analysis provides an illustration of the budgetary savings had demobilization occurred in 1997. The dynamic analysis traces the impact over time to assess the long-term sustainability of military restructuring. As planned in the CVAP, both scenarios are calculated using three phases of demobilization over a three-year period. The assumed demobilization calendars are as follows: (i) 15,000 in 1999, 15,000 in 2000, and 13,000 in 2001; (ii) 25,000 in 1999, 25,000 in 2000, and 28,300 in 2001. In both cases, it is assumed that the lower ranks would be demobilized first, and that generals and commissioned officers would not be demobilized before 2001. Furthermore, each phase of demobilization is assumed to be undertaken at the beginning of the respective year. D. Static Impact Analysis of Military Demobilization 15. Under Scenario 1, other things being equal, after completion of the demobilization exercise, annual savings in the government’s wage bill would amount to CR 52 billion, using RCAF data. Reducing non-wage costs proportionally (i.e., keeping total per capita costs constant at predemobilization levels) would reduce expenses by another CR 44 billion, resulting in an overall savings (“peace dividend”) of CR 96 billion, or 11.8 percent of the total 1997 recurrent budget (1.1 percent of GDP). Post-demobilization defense expenditure would amount to CR 208 billion. Using the 1997 budget and assuming the savings from demobilization are used to increase spending on general (1/4), social (1/2) and economic (1/4) services, the share of the recurrent defense budget in total government expenditure would be reduced to 25.5 percent. Other things being equal, the recurrent defense budget’s share in GDP (base 1997) would decrease to 2.3 percent. The ratio of defense expenditure over social and economic services combined would decline to 0.6 (Table 4). -67Table 4: Static Impact Analysis (millions of riel) 1997 General Services 1/ Defense and Security National Defense 2/ Public Security Social Services 1/ Economic Services 1/ Other Total Defense/Social & Economic Service (ratio) Defense/GDP (base 1998) 136,088 419,336 304,744 114,592 189,700 61,310 9,576 816,010 Share Scenario 1 Scenario 2 (%) (%) (%) 16.7 19.6 22.0 51.4 39.6 30.1 37.3 25.5 16.1 14.0 14.0 14.0 23.2 29.2 33.9 7.5 10.5 12.8 1.2 1.2 1.2 100.0 100.0 100.0 1.2 3.3 0.6 2.3 0.3 1.4 1/ Savings from demobilization are used to increase services. 2/ Post-demobilization per capita costs are constant. Scenario 1 (2): demobilization of 43,000 (78,300) soldiers. Source : Staff estimates. 16. Under Scenario 2, other things being equal, reducing non-wage costs proportionally, the peace dividend would amount to approximately CR 173 billion, and the share of national defense in the total recurrent budget would decrease to 16.1 percent, a reduction of 21.2 percent compared with predemobilization recurrent expenses. The post-demobilization share of national defense in GDP (base 1997) would decline to 1.4 percent, and the ratio of defense expenditure over social and economic services combined would decline to 0.3. E. Dynamic Impact Analysis of Military Demobilization3 17. Scenario 1: 43,000 soldiers. With per capita costs constant, the share of defense in total recurrent expenditure would decrease from 37.3 percent in 1997 to 16.0 percent in 2002. Defense expenditure would decrease by over 10 percent annually during the period 1999-2001, finally reaching CR 210 billion in 2002. The non-defense budget would increase on average by almost one-third during the same period and would amount to CR 1,104 billion in 2002. The demobilization of 43,000 soldiers in three phases would reduce the recurrent deficit by 36.6 percent in 2000 and 49.1 percent in 2002, with per capita costs constant. (Table 5). 18. Scenario 2: 78,300 soldiers. With per capita costs constant, the share of defense in total recurrent expenditure would decrease from 37.3 percent in 1997 to 10.1 percent in 2002. Defense expenditure would decrease by on average almost one-quarter annually during the period 1999-2001, finally reaching CR 132 billion in 2002. The non-defense budget would increase by on average over onethird during the same period and would amount to CR 1,181 billion in 2002. The demobilization of 78,300 soldiers in three phases would reduce the recurrent deficit by 60.9 percent in 2000, with per capita costs constant. (Table 6). 3 The dynamic impact analysis is based on the high case scenario, which presupposes the implementation of the CVAP. Preliminary figures for 1998 indicate a stagnant real GDP and a stark decline in real government expenditure. Compared to the budgeted amounts, defense spending already crowds out other civilian expenditure. It is assumed throughout the dynamic impact analysis that defense expenditure would ultimately reach the level of 1997, whereas non-defense expenditure would bear the necessary adjustment within a fixed budget of CR 896 billion in nominal terms. -68- Table 5: Dynamic Impact Analysis - Scenario 1 (in millions of riel in 1997 prices) Total Current Expenditure Defense 1/ Defense/Total Current Expenditure Defense/GDP RCAF Strength Per Capita Wages (Riel) 1997 1998 1999 816,009 304,743 37.3% 3.3% 755,300 304,743 40.3% 3.3% 969,969 1,083,512 1,212,330 271,740 238,737 210,136 28.0% 22.0% 17.3% 2.9% 2.4% 2.0% 138,506 1,173,907 138,506 1,173,907 123,506 1,173,907 2000 108,506 1,173,907 2001 95,507 1,173,907 2002 1,313,783 210,136 16.0% 1.9% 95,507 1,173,907 1/ Per capita wage and non-wage costs constant in real terms. Source: Staff estimates. Table 6: Dynamic Impact Analysis - Scenario 2 (in millions of riel in 1997 prices) Total Current Expenditure Defense 1/ Defense/Total Current Expenditure Defense/GDP RCAF Strength Per Capita Wages (Riel) 1997 1998 816,009 304,743 37.3% 3.3% 755,300 1,103,215 1,216,759 1,356,585 1,363,779 304,743 249,738 194,732 132,453 132,453 40.3% 25.7% 18.0% 10.9% 10.1% 3.3% 2.6% 1.9% 1.2% 1.2% 138,506 1,173,907 138,506 1,173,907 1999 113,506 1,173,907 2000 88,506 1,173,907 2001 60,200 1,173,907 2002 60,200 1,173,907 1/ Per capita wage and non-wage costs constant in real term. Source: Staff estimates. 19. Scenario without Demobilization. Assuming that (i) the government would not embark on downsizing the military and that (ii) per capita wages and non-wages would remain constant in real terms, the share of defense in total recurrent expenditure would decrease from 37.3 percent in 1997 to 23.2 percent in 2002. Defense’s share in GDP would decline from 3.3 percent in 1997 to 2.7 percent in 2002. 20. Summary of the Costs and Benefits of Demobilization. Table 7 presents a summary of the impact of demobilization in relation to total recurrent expenditure and GDP. Without demobilization, the share of defense in GDP would decrease from 3.3 percent to 2.7 percent. The demobilization of 43,000 and 78,300 soldiers would reduce this share to 1.9 percent and 1.2 percent, respectively. Table 8 shows the costs and benefits in financial resources. The demobilization of 43,000 and 78,300 ex-combatants would lead to annual savings of US$25 million and US$45 million, respectively, starting from 2001. In contrast, total costs for implementing demobilization and reintegration of 43,000 and 78,000 soldiers would amount to US$73 million and US$125 million. -69Table 7: Impact of Demobilization (in percent) Without CVAP 1997 2002 Defense/Total Current Expenditure 1/ Defense/GDP 1/ 37.3 3.3 23.2 2.7 Scenario 1 1997 2002 37.3 3.3 Scenario 2 1997 2002 16.0 1.9 37.3 3.3 10.1 1.2 1/ Assuming per capita wage and non-wage costs remain constant in real terms. Sources: Staff estimates. Table 8: Costs and Benefits of Demobilization (in millions of US$) Defense Expenditure 1997 Defense Expenditure 2002 (w/ demobilization) 1/ Savings (w/ demobilization) 1/ CVAP costs (1999-2002) Scenario 1 Scenario 2 80.7 55.7 25.1 72.7 80.7 35.1 45.6 124.5 1/ Per capita wage and non-wage costs constant in real terms. Source: Government budget data, staff estimates. 21. Comparison of Financial Returns to Demobilization. Demobilization and reintegration programs have been undertaken in increasing numbers, especially on the African continent. A recent Bank study on the experiences with and lessons from such programs attempted to quantify the financial returns to demobilization so as to make them comparable across countries. Table 9 presents a comparison between the two scenarios in Cambodia and the results in Ethiopia, Namibia, and Uganda on the basis of three-year averages before and after demobilization.4 In Ethiopia, for example, demobilization was undertaken in the immediate aftermath of war. Hence, budgetary savings cannot be attributed to military downsizing alone. Uganda, on the other hand, implemented a peacetime program. Cambodia’s demobilization and reintegration program would rank well in terms of financial returns compared with similar programs undertaken in other countries. F. Conclusion 22. If the government were to proceed with the demobilization of 43,000 soldiers as envisaged in the CVAP, national defense would still account for around one-fifth of total recurrent expenditure if per capita costs remained constant. However, in view of the improved security situation and the increased defection rate of Khmer Rouge fighters, the number of soldiers to be demobilized is expected to be higher, and a reduction of 78,300 soldiers would result in more impressive savings. A revision of the CVAP is therefore necessary to determine the target number for demobilization and reintegration as well as the ensuing program costs. 4 The calculations for Cambodia underestimate the long-term savings because the three-year averages are calculated from 2000-2002, namely, while demobilization is ongoing. A similar limitation applies to Uganda. -70Table 9: Financial Returns to Demobilization Cambodia 1 Cambodia 2 Demobilization Defense Exp./Recurrent Exp. Pre-Demobilization 1/ Defense Exp./Recurrent Exp. Post-Demobilization 1/ Budget Savings/Recurrent Expenditure 2/ Defense/Social Exp. Pre-Demobilization (ratio) 3/ Defense/Social Exp. Post-Demobilization (ratio) 3/ Budget savings/DRP costs (ratio) 4/ 43,000 36.7% 18.5% 18.3% 1.58 0.88 0.36 78,300 36.7% 13.0% 23.7% 1.58 0.48 0.38 Ethiopia 475,800 46.6% 16.4% 30.2% 2.50 0.71 1.74 Namibia 49,500 12.4% 6.3% 6.1% 0.36 0.14 0.95 Uganda 36,400 34.9% 25.0% 9.9% 1.43 0.91 0.24 1/ Three-year averages before and after demobilization. Assumption for Cambodia: per capita costs constant in real terms. 2/ Budget savings refer to annual government savings from reduced military expenditure using the three-year averages. 3/ Three-year averages before and after demobilization. Assumption for Cambodia: per capita wage and non-wage costs remain constant in real term. 4/ Annual post-demobilization savings compared to program costs. The inverse indicates the number of years until DRP costs have been 'earned'. Note: Only Uganda, as a peace-time demobilization, is strictly comparable to Cambodia. Source: Colletta et al. 1996b. Case Studies in War-to-Peace Transition; staff estimates. 23. To have a lasting impact on development policy, the analysis suggests a more drastic reduction in the size of the RCAF and an improvement in living conditions (that is, an increase in wages and nonwages) for the remaining soldiers, to improve motivation and discipline. Such a policy, however, requires higher short- to medium-term investment that is beyond the government’s financial capability. The currently estimated CVAP budget for 43,000 veterans amounts to US$72.8 million. The demobilization of another 35,300 soldiers would increase the budget to at least US$125 million. Without full donor support, neither program is feasible. 24. It should be noted that the analysis is undertaken for the period up to 2002, and that the full benefit of military restructuring would be realized over the longer term. Moreover, in the long run, the peace dividend of army demobilization cannot be seen in financial terms (budgetary savings) only. A well-trained professional army can enhance security and trust which in turn would improve the investment climate at both the local and the national levels. An efficiently implemented CVAP would undoubtedly contribute to such an improved economic environment and to the strengthening of civil society. In addition, if, after having received reinsertion and reintegration support, veterans’ incomes would correspond to the (low) national average, veterans would contribute CR 37 billion to national production in 1997 prices (CR 68 billion under the second scenario). The total resources created annually after completion of the demobilization program, through (i) budgetary savings (assuming costs per soldier remain constant in real terms) and (ii) additional personal income, would then amount to CR 132 billion and CR 240 billion, respectively, corresponding to 1.4 percent and 2.6 percent of GDP. Clearly, demobilization would be an important investment in sustainable development. -71- Asia C:\WINWORD\camgran2.doc 09/21/98 1:05 PM