Download FRBSF E L CONOMIC ETTER

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Recession wikipedia , lookup

Nominal rigidity wikipedia , lookup

Economic democracy wikipedia , lookup

Đổi Mới wikipedia , lookup

Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup

Long Depression wikipedia , lookup

Economic calculation problem wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER
Number 2006-15, June 30, 2006
Residential Investment
over the Real Estate Cycle
Much attention recently has been given to the possibility of a slowdown in the U.S. residential real estate
market. While real residential investment has continued to grow and existing house prices have held
up through the first quarter of 2006, analysts have
pointed to other signs of slowing.Two commonly
cited indicators are an apparent slowing of sales of
new and existing homes and a buildup of inventories
of new homes in many markets. In this Economic
Letter, I characterize past episodes of residential investment downturns and evaluate how specific housing
market variables, such as sales volumes and inventories, perform as predictors of downturns.
Measuring real estate market activity
The main indicator of the quantity of new housing
supplied to the economy is the residential fixed investment series from the national income and product
accounts. Residential investment is made up of new
construction put in place, expenditures on maintenance and home improvement, equipment purchased
for use in residential structures (e.g., washers and
dryers purchased by landlords and rented out to
tenants), and brokerage commissions. Over the past
25 years residential investment has accounted for
approximately 30% of gross private investment and
approximately 5% of total domestic output. As a
share of total investment, residential investment has
been in decline since the 1960s, mainly due to the
surge in investment in business equipment and software starting around that same time. As a share of
total output, however, residential investment is currently at its highest share since the mid-1980s: In
2006: Q1, real residential investment grew by 3.1%,
contributing about two-tenths of a percentage point
to real GDP growth.
Residential investment is a highly volatile component
of GDP.Yet as shown in Figure 1, the volatility has
decreased markedly in recent years. Indeed, this series
is one of the most frequently cited pieces of evidence
when describing the overall decline in macroeconomic volatility (see Dynan, Elmendorf, and Sichel
(2006) and Peek and Wilcox (2006)). Before the mid1980s, residential investment was characterized by
periods of extreme boom and then bust.The response
of residential investment to the strong economy and
robust house price appreciation since 1996 has been
much more gradual, by comparison.
Figure 1
Change in real residential fixed investment
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.
If we characterize an investment slowdown as two
consecutive quarters of declining real spending, there
have been eight downturns since 1976.The shaded
recession bars in Figure 1 indicate that when the
overall economy tips into recession, invariably residential investment turns down as well; however, the
timing of these downturns does not always track the
recession dates perfectly, and some downturns even
occur during overall economic expansions.This leads
to a natural classification of residential investment
downturns. Recession-related downturns last an average of seven quarters and are characterized by large
declines in investment; on average, real residential
investment falls by about 50% from the previous peak
(see Figure 2).These averages are strongly influenced
by the downturns occurring before the 1980s, when
the depth and duration of recessions were also severe.
On the other hand, non-recession-related downturns
are relatively shorter, lasting an average of two to
three quarters, and relatively milder, resulting in an
average dip in investment of roughly 10%.
Forecasting residential investment downturns
Residential investment should be thought of as the
quantity of new housing supplied to the economy,
and, in the long run, it should satisfy the overall demand for new housing.Thus, residential investment
depends on supply factors, such as construction mate-
FRBSF Economic Letter
Figure 2
Real private residential investment
in residential investment downturns
2
Number 2006-15, June 30, 2006
downturn has started. For non-recession-related
downturns, however, there is no clear signal, on average, from sales volumes data either before or during
the downturn.
The so-called “month’s supply of housing” ratio, or
the number of new housing units for sale in a given
month divided by the number of new units sold, is
also fairly useful for predicting investment downturns.
For recession-related downturns, the ratio (shown in
Figure 3) starts to rise on average six quarters before
the actual downturn, and continues to rise for six
quarters into the downturn. For the average nonrecession-related downturn, the inventory ratio turns
up just one quarter before the downturn and then
eases back down after two quarters (which is also the
average duration of a non-recession-related downturn).
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis. Series indexed to 1 in quarter 0
(peak in investment).
rials costs, as well as demand factors, such as demographics, interest rates (or the cost of capital), prices,
and the stock of household wealth.These demandside factors are particularly important in helping to
explain why residential downturns tend to accompany economic downturns. In this spirit, a standard
macro model of residential investment will typically
posit that investment depends on variables like aggregate consumption, interest rates, and prices (see
Brayton and Tinsley (1996)). Notably absent from
this specification are the variables most cited in the
press as evidence of a slowing housing market: sales
volumes and growing inventories.
At any point in time, however, the new supply brought
to market may not exactly equal the amount of new
housing demanded. In particular, negative shocks to
demand can result in there being too much supply
on the market. If these changes in demand are not
expected to be transitory, then developers will slow
the pace of new construction and a downturn will
occur.To forecast these turning points, we need to
know what variables developers use to learn about
changes in demand. It is possible that variables that
do not enter into the model sketched out above, such
as sales volumes and inventory levels, are related to
the information that developers use to make, or alter,
their plans.
In this type of framework, variables that speak to selling conditions for finished projects seem to be fairly
useful in predicting downturns; for example, sales
volumes dip one quarter before the average downturn in investment. For recession-related downturns,
sales drop very quickly (by about 10%) once the
This exercise indicates that prices seem to be considerably less useful predictors of downturns than
quantity-type measures.This might seem surprising
because, unlike sales volumes and inventories, prices
have a forward-looking aspect and thus would seem
to be good predictors of the future state of the housing market. Figure 4 shows the average behavior of
real new house prices leading up to and then following a peak in residential investment.The focus here
is on new house prices because, presumably, they,
rather than existing house prices, are most relevant for
real estate developers’ decisionmaking. Additionally,
new house prices are likely to be more sensitive to
market weakness than existing house prices. Developers
are always “motivated sellers.” If demand is soft, they
generally do not have the option of withdrawing the
house from the market and simply living in it. For
recession-related downturns, the real price of new
houses declines about four quarters after the peak, on
average. Real new house prices register no detectable
declines surrounding the average non-recessionrelated downturn.This basic stylized fact is even more
apparent when using prices of existing homes. Only
in the severest downturns do we witness real price
declines, and never do these price declines come in
advance of a downturn in investment.
One caveat to this analysis is that it is based on the
comparison of the average behavior of a housing
market series leading up to two different types of
downturns in residential investment. Obviously, averaging in the figures masks a fair degree of variation
across the different downturns. However, more formal statistical modeling supports the notion that
variables such as sales volumes and inventory ratios
yield earlier and more reliable signals when the downturn is recession-related.This is natural; recessionrelated downturns have tended to be more severe
than the non-recession-related episodes.
FRBSF Economic Letter
Figure 3
New houses for sale-to-houses sold
in residential investment downturns
Source: U.S. Census Bureau. Series indexed to 1 in quarter 0 (peak in
investment).
It is also interesting to note that the recent behavior
of the month’s supply ratio bears more resemblance
to the typical behavior before a recession-related
downturn than to a non-recession-related downturn.Yet economists, such as those sampled in surveys
of professional forecasters, are generally predicting
only a moderation in overall economic growth in
coming quarters. Given these conflicting observations, it is natural to wonder how much stand-alone
information for predicting residential investment is
contained in the housing market data.The answer,
based on the last 30 years of data is mixed. If we
estimate a model of the event that a residential downturn occurs using lagged values of the housing market
variables mentioned above, we can generally improve
the model prediction error by adding in forecasts of
output growth.This suggests that it is best to consider economy-wide factors in addition to specific
housing market variables when evaluating the real
estate market.
Conclusion
Housing market statistics, such as sales volumes and
months of supply on the market, can provide some
useful information about turning points for residential investment. Much of this early warning, however, comes in advance of severe, recession-related
downturns. Before non-recession-related downturns,
which are typically relatively shorter and milder, these
3
Number 2006-15, June 30, 2006
Figure 4
Real new house prices in residential
investment downturns
Source: U.S. Census Bureau. Series indexed to 1 in quarter 0 (peak in
investment).
variables are less reliable. The analysis suggests that
incoming information from the housing market should
be evaluated in the context of the overall economy’s
performance.To the extent that forecasts for solid output and employment growth are realized, this would
not preclude slower growth in residential investment,
but it should provide support for the real estate market and residential investment.
John Krainer
Economist
References
Brayton, F., and P. Tinsley, eds. 1996. “A Guide to
FRB/US: A Macroeconomic Model of the United
States.” Federal Reserve Board Finance and
Economics Discussion Series. http://
www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/1996/199642/
199642abs.html
Dynan, K., D. Elmendorf, and D. Sichel. 2006. “Can
Financial Innovation Help to Explain the Reduced
Volatility of Economic Activity?” Journal of Monetary
Economics 53(1), pp. 123–150.
Peek, J., and J.Wilcox. 2006.“Housing, Credit Constraints,
and Macro Stability:The Secondary Mortgage Market
and Reduced Cyclicality of Residential Investment.”
American Economic Review 96(2) (May), pp. 135–140.
ECONOMIC RESEARCH
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF SAN FRANCISCO
PRESORTED
STANDARD MAIL
U.S. POSTAGE
PAID
PERMIT NO. 752
San Francisco, Calif.
P.O. Box 7702
San Francisco, CA 94120
Address Service Requested
Printed on recycled paper
with soybean inks
Index to Recent Issues of FRBSF Economic Letter
DATE
11/25
11/30
12/2
12/9
12/16
12/23
12/30
1/27
2/24
3/3
3/10
3/17
4/07
4/14
4/21
4/28
5/12
5/19
6/2
6/23
NUMBER
05-32
05-33
05-34
05-35
05-36
05-37
05-38
06-01
06-02
06-03
06-04
06-05
06-06
06-07
06-08
06-09
06-10
06-11
06-12-13
06-14
TITLE
AUTHOR
The Bretton Woods System: Are We Experiencing a Revival?
Glick/Spiegel
Uncertainty and Monetary Policy
Dennis
Recent Policy Issues Regarding Credit Risk Transfer
Lopez
Shifting Data: A Challenge for Monetary Policymakers
Fernald/Wang
Bank ATMs and ATM Surcharges
Gowrisankaran/Krainer
The Diffusion of Personal Computers across the U.S.
Doms
Do Oil Futures Prices Help Predict Future Oil Prices?
Wu/McCallum
2006: A Year of Transition at the Federal Reserve
Yellen
Productivity Growth: Causes and Consequences, Conference Summary Wilson
Postal Savings in Japan and Mortgage Markets in the U.S.
Cargill/Scott
External Imbalances and Adjustment in the Pacific Basin
Glick/Spiegel
Enhancing Fed Credibility
Yellen
What Is the Federal Reserve Banks’ Imputed Cost of Equity Capital? Barnes/Lopez
Security Analysts and Regulatory Reform
Marquez
Job Matching: Evidence from the Beveridge Curve
Valletta/Hodges
Prospects for the Economy
Yellen
Bank Diversification, Economic Diversification?
Strahan
Cargill
Central Bank Capital, Financial Strength, and the Bank of Japan
Monetary Policy in a Global Environment
Yellen
International Financial Integration and the Current Account Balance Cavallo
Opinions expressed in the Economic Letter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank
of San Francisco or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.This publication is edited by Judith Goff, with
the assistance of Anita Todd. Permission to reprint portions of articles or whole articles must be obtained in writing. Permission
to photocopy is unrestricted. Please send editorial comments and requests for subscriptions, back copies, address changes, and
reprint permission to: Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco, CA
94120, phone (415) 974-2163, fax (415) 974-3341, e-mail [email protected]. The Economic Letter and other publications
and information are available on our website, http://www.frbsf.org.