Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) Energy and growth in the 21st century: macroeconomic impacts of the transition to unconventional fossil fuels Kevin Alastair M. Tan Carnegie Mellon University The meteoric rise of oil prices during the mid-2000s sparked strong concern about the world’s ability to maintain a growing energy supply (Rapier, 86). However—at least in mainstream media—these concerns have since been allayed by the rapid proliferation of unconventional sources of hydrocarbons: shale gas, tight oil, tar sands amongst many others (Hughes 2013). These unconventional hydrocarbons have been made viable through a combination of prolonged high energy prices and technological advances, the most prominent being hydraulic fracking (Hall et al. 2014). Estimates of the world’s reserves of unconventional hydrocarbons are immense, by many measures exceeding those of conventional oil and gas. Additionally, much of these unconventionals are located within North America. As such, unconventionals have been touted to revolutionize the energy industry, promising to usher in a new era of cheap energy and North American energy independence (IEA 2013; Hughes 2013; EIA 2014). However, unconventional fossil fuels have a major and seemingly-overlooked caveat: high monetary, energetic and environmental costs of production. Unconventional sources of hydrocarbons are generally much more difficult to extract, transport and refine than conventional sources (Smil, 204-205). Though exact numbers are impossible to determine, many geologists believe that opportunities for growing production from conventional sources are becoming increasingly rare (Rapier, 51). Unless a paradigm shift is seen in the energy industry, it is almost certain that the proportion of unconventionals in world energy production 1 KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) will increase markedly in the upcoming years and decades. Thus, it is important to assess the macroeconomic impacts of the higher costs associated with unconventionals, especially in the context of the continued economic malaise that has plagued much of the world economy since the Great Recession. Energy and Growth – Historical Relationships It is important to characterize the historical relationships between energy and growth, as it is integral in framing the transition to unconventional fossil fuels within a broad historical context. They key to understanding these relationships is through the concept of energy return on investment (EROI). Simply put, the EROI of an energy source is the ratio of the amount of usable energy acquired to the amount of energy expended in attaining it (Gupta & Hall 2011). EROI is key to the success of any biological system, human civilizations not excluded. The success of humans, from its evolutionary origins to the present day, can be attributed to the EROI of its energy sources. With the advent of bipedalism, humans only required a quarter of the energy per unit of travel compared to other primates. Additionally, the discovery of fire externalized the significant energy requirements of digestion and temperature regulation. These not only provided humans with an energetic advantage over other species, but also allowed for evolutionary pressures to direct more energy to brain function, giving rise to humans’ superior cognitive abilities (Brown et al. 2011; Hall & Clitgaard, 42-44). In pre-agricultural societies, the EROI of hunting and gathering dictated population size and standard-of-living. If the round-trip distance of gathering the required amount of food exceeded 11 miles, EROI dropped substantially, as this required an additional days’ work (Hall & Klitgaard, 44). Hunter-gatherer communities were generally placated with an EROI at or above 2 KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) 10kcal gained to 1kcal expended. When EROI dropped below that threshold, communities became strained; the most common resolution was migration. Periods of competition and unfavorable climate conditions dropped EROI below 10:1 with varying frequency, spurring waves of human migrations (Brown et al. 2011). The agricultural revolution dramatically raised the EROI of food. The abundance of energy enabled the formation of cities, bureaucracies, and governments—in other words, civilization. However, the pre-industrial equivalent of Jevon’s Paradox is that gains in agricultural yields will be outweighed by corresponding increases in population and societal complexity (Hall & Klitgaard, 48). The net effect was a decrease in nutritional standards for the masses, and a general deprecation of quality-of-life compared to hunting and gathering (Tainter 191). As agricultural societies grew in terms of population and GDP, they eventually reached the production capacity of their territorial environment. Thus, in order to grow further, civilizations needed to use strategies of territorial expansion and subjugation (Hall & Klitgaard, 57; Tainter, 192). While initial expansion is quite fruitful, continued expansion gradually decreases in EROI. As territory expands and energy supply grows, more energy is required in maintaining it: transportation, infrastructure, bureaucracy and security. Eventually, the EROI of territorial expansion drops below the threshold of viability (Hall & Klitgaard, 57) The outlined developmental trajectory of growth, stagnation and collapse has held until the “rise of the West.” For centuries prior to the rise of the West, Europe was a cultural and economic backwater (Marks, 124). Europe’s economic fortunes began to change during the 16th century renaissance, the beginning of colonialism in the Americas. The ecological richness of unspoiled American land provided European powers with high-EROI sources of energy, primarily 3 KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) in the form of timber, sugar, cotton, and fish (Marks, 125). However, colonially-sourced energy gains were eclipsed by the mass adoption of coal, which first began in 1750’s Britain (Hall & Klitgaard, 69). Coal—a product of millions of years’ worth of compressed biomass—exceeded all previous energy sources in abundance, energy density, and usability by several orders-ofmagnitude. For the first time, humanity could transcend the limits to growth imposed by annual solar energy flows—limits that had plagued all successful civilizations since the agricultural revolution. The end of the “biological old regime” in Europe marked the true beginning of the rise of the West (Marks, 126). Due to the abundance of fossil energy, machines became ubiquitous and could be scaled up exponentially. The adoption of fossil energy in transportation introduced rapid mobility to the masses, effectively compressing space and time. All of these factors World energy production and GDP, 1800-2008. Energy from hydrocarbons resulted in a corresponding increase in GDP. (Hall & Klitgaard, 44) resulted in unprecedented gains in economic productivity, socioeconomic complexity, and population size (Brown et al. 2011). This new-found energy, wealth, and technology spurred widespread and systematic European conquest of the Americas, Asia, and Africa, further fueling the West’s meteoric rise. By the mid-19th century, the West had attained unquestioned economic, geopolitical, and military dominance the world over. Regions still stuck in the “biological old regime” entered a poverty trap due to limited energy access alongside varying degrees of 4 KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) economic, political, and military subjugation. These regions referred to today as the “developing world” (Marks, 205-7). Neoliberalism – Energy, Debt and Growth The rise of neoliberalism in the 1960’s has resulted in massive structural changes in the world economy, changes which have had a profound impact on the relationship between energy and growth. In the decades following World War II, widespread reforms of economic liberalization, financial deregulation, and privatization have brought with it a new economic and geopolitical paradigm commonly referred to as “neoliberalism.” The resurgence of laissez-faire ideology was a response to widespread stagflation in the developed world. The perceived inefficiencies of Keynesian economics and the welfare state were blamed as the primary cause of economic malaise; thus, these systems were eschewed in favor of the private sector and market forces (Hamilton et al. 2009). Aided by the efforts of transnational institutions such as the International Monetary Fund, World Bank, and World Trade Organization, the world’s markets—particularly in the developing world—had become much freer by the end of the 1980’s. This had the effect of accelerating the currents of globalization, bringing about a new level of economic integration and interdependency throughout the capitalist world—the mass delocalization of commodity chains (Hall & Klitgaard, 191-192). With economic liberalization and relaxed labor laws, neoliberalism spurred the deindustrialization of high-income countries. Freer markets made it viable for rich-world companies to access the low-cost labor and commodities markets of the developing world. Furthermore, the erosion of labor protections and deunionization made it much easier to outsource (Hall & Klitgaard, 193). In effect, this externalized much of the energy costs of 5 KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) developed nations, as energyintensive industries such as manufacturing were outsourced to developing nations (Smil, 88). Thus, economies increased their dependence on oil, as transportation distances grew Food and oil prices are tightly coupled. (UN FAO 2012) exponentially. The green revolution is also thought to be a derivative of neoliberal currents (Marks, 186). The green revolution increased agricultural productivity by 200-300%, resulting in a commensurate increase in world population. This was possible primarily due to the use of hydrocarbon energy inputs in agriculture: fertilizers, pesticides, mechanized farming techniques, and increasingly-delocalized food chains. Thus, food prices became tightly coupled with oil prices (Hall & Klitgaard, 385-6). Overall, neoliberalism has increased the “energy overhead” of economic activity. Neoliberal deregulation of the financial industry has caused it to become the dominant force in shaping the world economy (Hamilton et al. 2009). “No matter where you are in the world, you can’t do anything big without the approval of Wall Street” (Hall & Klitgaard, 191). Deregulation has facilitated the availability of credit, both public and private. The advent of complicated financial instruments such as derivatives serve as robust mechanisms of credit creation through the speculation or hedging of the value of other assets, called underliers. Underliers are a combination of commodities and other financial products such as mortgages, stocks, and bonds—in other words, the creation of credit through debt (Hall & Klitgaard, 197-9). 6 KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) Consequently, debt levels in rich countries have skyrocketed, often exceeding value of national GDPs two-or-threefold. Much of the economic growth seen in the neoliberal era can be attributed to debt (i.e. deficit spending), and its consequences have been felt in the form of financial crises and austerity measures (Hamilton et al. 2009). Mainstream economists cite economic growth as a reliable apparatus for sustaining high debt loads, as growth facilitates the relatively painless distribution of debt to the rest of the economy (Hall & Klitgaard, 195). Thus, the assumption of indefinite economic growth serves as a postulate for the contemporary financial system—debt would not be fundable without it. In a world with an expanding energy supply, this postulate has held true. However, the transition to unconventional hydrocarbons indicates that growth in energy production is becoming much harder to achieve. The implications of this are very important to understand, as the transition is already occurring in full force at the present time. Transitioning to Unconventional Fossil Fuels The transition to unconventional hydrocarbons is most evident in the North American natural gas industry. For example, in the United States, shale comprised only 1% of natural gas production in 2000. In 2010, this figure has US natural gas production, 2010-2040. Unconventionals have come to dominate US natural gas production. (EIA Reference Case, 2014) jumped to over 20%, and is 7 KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) projected to exceed 50% during the 2030’s, by which time conventionals should only comprise 5% of total production (EIA 2014). Unconventional natural gas is much more developed in North America compared to other regions, but significant reserves are located in 48 structural basins within 38 countries on all six inhabited continents (EIA 2014; IEA 2013). Massive plans are already under way to produce from unconventional fields outside North America, and thus the dominance of unconventional gas seen in North America is likely to be replicated in other regions (Hughes 2013; IEA 2013). Unconventionals have a lesser foothold in petroleum production compared to natural gas, but nevertheless the proportion of unconventionals in total petroleum production is expected to increase markedly in the 21 century. It is striking st World petroleum production, 2011-2031. A significant proportion of the production shortfall from existing fields is expected to be made up using unconventional sources. (IEA New Policies Scenario, 2013) that four-fifths of today’s conventional oil production comes from fields discovered before 1970 (Smil, 189). Much of conventional petroleum comes from “megafields” which comprise the largest, highest-quality and easiest-to-extract known reserves of oil. The two biggest megafields are Ghawar in Saudi Arabia and Cantarell in Mexico, which were discovered in the 1940s (Hirsch et al. 2005). Ghawar and Cantarell, along with many other megafields, are near or past their peak rate of oil production (Rapier, 94). With conventional sources of oil gradually becoming depleted, maintaining or growing world oil production necessitates the increasing use of unconventional 8 KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) sources (Hall et al. 2014). Oil from conventional fields operating in 2011 produces around 70 million barrels per day (mbd), but this is expected to decline to around 30 mbd by 2030. A significant proportion of this shortfall is likely to be made up using unconventional sources of oil (Hughes 2013; IEA 2013). EROI and the Transition to Unconventionals Meta-analysis of the EROI of various energy sources. EROI of unconventional hydrocarbons is an order-of-magnitude lower than conventionals. Biomass produces negligible energy gains. (Lambert et al. 2013) Unconventional sources of hydrocarbons generally have much lower EROIs compared to conventional sources (Hughes 2013; Hall et al. 2014). Extraction and processing from unconventional sources is difficult and energy-intensive, being more akin to metal mining than traditional drilling. Producing from unconventional sources requires immense amounts of energy and water, and results in enormous amounts of environmentally-hazardous waste products (Rapier, 88; Smil, 204-205). Extracting oil and gas from shale necessitates the use of hydraulic fracturing, which uses pressurized liquids to fracture geological formations that contain trapped hydrocarbons. Fracking liquids are volatile, environmentally hazardous and expensive to produce. From the ground to the consumer, the EROI of oil and gas production from shale falls within 8 - 17:1 (Yaritani & Matsushima 2014). This is much lower than the EROIs of 9 KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) conventional oil and gas production, which are 25 - 100:1 and 20 - 50:1 respectively (Hall et al. 2014). Oil production from tar sands is even more difficult. Tar sands contain oil in the form of amorphous solids or oily rocks. Extraction involves the use of bulldozers, dump-trucks and other heavy machinery. Resultantly, the EROI of tar sands is quite low, ranging between 2 - 5:1 (Cleveland & O’Connor 2011; Poisson & Hall 2013). Production from many tar sands reserves is not beneficial at the macro level, as an energy source benefits biological systems—including human societies—only when EROI is at least 3:1 (Brown et al. 2011). It is important to note that unconventional sources are only being produced because the EROI of conventional sources has dropped to the point where it is viable to do so (Gupta & Hall EROI of global oil & gas production has dropped by 30% in 20 years. (Gagnon et al. 2009) 2011; Hall et al. 2014). The EROI is conventional hydrocarbons is dropping because energy sources that are easier to extract are almost always consumed first (Rapier, 97). Megafields were one of the first hydrocarbon fields to be produced due to the ease of production and quality of the product. As the most desirable fields are depleted, production shifts to less desirable fields that tend to be smaller in size and contain lower-quality product (Hirsch et al. 2005). More recent discoveries also tend to be more inaccessible, being located in inhospitable places such as the deep sea or arctic (Rapier, 97-99). This trend has dropped the EROI of conventional 10 KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) hydrocarbons to the point that unconventional sources are being developed in earnest—in other words, we’ve reached the “bottom of the barrel.” The EROI of world oil and gas production has dropped by 30% from 1990 to 2010 (Gagnon et al. 2009). Canada some of contains the largest reserves of unconventional oil in the world. Canadian tar sands, mostly located in Alberta, have been developed in earnest in the 2000’s. The impact of tar sands on the EROI of EROI of Canadian energy production versus proportion of energy from tar sands. (Poisson & Hall 2013) Canadian energy production has been studied extensively (Hughes 2013). A recent and comprehensive study of the time course of Canadian energy production EROI found that the proportion of total energy production from tar sands correlated negatively with EROI. The study found the negative correlation to be fairly strong, with r = -0.69 (Poisson & Hall 2013). Though not as extensively studied, similar findings have been found for US, Mexican and Venezuelan energy production (Hughes 2013; Hall et al. 2014). Unless there is a paradigm shift in the energy industry (i.e. discovery of a novel energy source), it is likely that the proportion of world energy production from unconventional will continue to increase. Regardless of the exact proportion of unconventionals in world energy production, EROI will continue to drop—we’ve already picked the lowest-hanging fruit, and we have no choice but to climb further up the tree. 11 KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) Macroeconomic Impacts of Decreasing EROI In the United States, petroleum expenditures exceeding ~6% of GDP induce recessions. (Hall & Klitgaard, 134) Since World War II, eleven out of the twelve global recessions were preceded by oil price shocks (Tverberg 2012). The oil price shock that preceded the Great Recession has been attributed to the decreasing EROI of world oil production. Despite increasing monetary and energetic investment, declining EROIs have made it difficult to raise energy production, thus raising prices to record levels (King & Hall 2011). In the age of petroleum, growth seems to stop when oil expenditures exceed 5-10% of GDP, whether in individual countries or the entire world (Hall & Klitgaard, 378). Compounded by the volatility induced by neoliberal reforms (i.e. financial deregulation), ecological economists point to the oil shock of 2006-2008 as the primary cause of the financial crisis and Great Recession (Hamilton et al. 2009; Brown et al. 2011; King & Hall 2011; Tverberg 2012). These record energy prices revealed weaknesses in the world economy and financial system. Higher oil prices inhibited the ability of debtors to repay their debts. Due to astonishingly high debt loads in the developed world, both private and public, it did not take long for high oil prices to destabilize the financial system, which should’ve been more resilient 12 KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) given the strength of the world economy at the time. With the neoliberal paradigm remaining entrenched, and with the EROI of world energy production continuing to decline, economic downturns of similar or greater magnitude to the Great Recession may become commonplace in the 21st century (Lambert et al. 2013). The Great Recession may be the best template by which to characterize these future economic downturns. Energy price shocks induce negative feedback loops of dampened economic activity that spread quickly throughout the world economy (Brown et al. 2011). The neoliberal delocalization of economies results in Stagnation of oil production growth is reflective of decreasing EROI (Tverberg 2012) increased sensitivity to transportation costs, which are even more pertinent in the United States, which is almost wholly dependent on automobile transportation. Due to the green revolution, food prices have become tightly coupled to oil prices. The 2006-2008 oil shock caused the largest food crisis in recent memory; millions were pushed into in water-stressed regions such as the Sahel, while developed nations saw unprecedented use of food subsidy programs, and even desperate acts food scavenging (Hall & Klitgaard, 269). Also, production costs will rise as prices soar for basic commodities such as metals and plastics, which tend to be very petroleumintensive, not to mention that industrial production is energy-intensive in itself (Hamilton et al. 2009). The price of oil alternatives will also soar, as demand shifts towards them. The impact of 13 KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) an oil shock will propagate throughout the global economy, acting as a robust inflationary pressure, resulting in higher interest rates and more expensive credit. Increased energy expenditures results in capital flight, as oil expenditures generally do not feed back into the economies of oil consumers (Hall & Klitgaard, 271). Thus, the discretionary spending of consumers is set to decrease due to higher costs, less credit, and asset devaluation (real estate, etc.), which will quickly stall economic growth and contract the labor market, dampening economic activity even further. State finances will also become strained due to general inflation, shrinking tax revenues, and increased use of social welfare services (Hamilton et al. 2009). As seen with previous oil shocks, inherent weaknesses in economies and governments tend to be revealed, resulting in price crashes, currency devaluations, political upheaval, and social unrest (Hall & Klitgaard, 280). In the United States, recession-inspired social and political movements, such as #Occupy and the Tea Party, have been visible but fairly benign. The same does not hold true in the rest of the developed world, which has seen dramatic shifts in political power along with endemic social unrest. Growth in the 21st Century? There has been a sharp disparity in economic performance between the developed world and newly-industrialized countries (NICs) since the Great Recession. While most high-income countries have yet to recover, NICs are once again enjoying Economic growth and energy production are strongly coupled. (Tverberg 2012) rapid and sustained economic growth. 14 KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) Though meaningful growth is still only enjoyed by a minority in the developing world, the pace and scale of “the rise of the rest” is still unprecedented. Modern middle-class lifestyles have become attainable for billions around the world. This is one of humanity’s greatest achievements, but unfortunately it is at odds with the declining EROI of world energy supply. Industrialization is a very energy and resource-intensive process. While per-capita energy and resource consumption in NICs is still miniscule compared to rich nations, their populations are much larger and continue to grow. Compounded with their adoption of modern energy-intensive lifestyles (cars, meat, etc.), global demand for energy and oil is set to double by 2035 (IEA 2013). This trajectory seems incongruous with the world’s biophysical realities. The assumption held by Smil and others—that the last half of our remaining hydrocarbon supply will be of comparable benefit to the first half—is fundamentally flawed. Our remaining hydrocarbon supply is will feature much lower EROIs than what we have enjoyed in the 20th century, this is evident in the steady EROI decline of world energy production. Coupled with a growing population, mass industrialization and a growth-based economic paradigm, the 21st century will likely feature ever-rising energy prices (King & Hall 2011). Developing nations are at a natural advantage in ‘bear’ energy market, as much lower per-capita energy consumption cushions the economic impact of high prices (Tvelberg 2012; Hall & Klitgaard, 321). The developed world is at a disadvantage in this environment, with its high per-capita energy consumption. In particular, the United States is in one of the worst positions during a period of energy scarcity, as automobile dependence and low-density urban planning compounds the impact of energy prices. (Hirsch et al. 2005; Rapier, 100). 15 KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) Humanity’s continued growth and prosperity is contingent upon the adoption of abundant, environmentally-sustainable, energy-dense and high-EROI sources of energy. Doing so would render the above issues moot. The 21st century finds humanity at the crossroads: coercive action could put us on a path of sustainability and prosperity, while continued inaction could result in ecological, economic and financial crises of increasing frequency and severity. 16 KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) References Annual Energy Outlook 2014. Washington DC: EIA, 2013 Brown, James H., William R. Burnside, Ana D. Davidson, John P. DeLong, William C. Dunn, Marcus J. Hamilton, Jeffrey K. Nekola, and Jordan G. Okie. "Energetic Limits to Economic Growth." Bioscience January 61.1 (2011). Cleveland, Cutler J., and Peter A. O’Connor. "Energy Return on Investment (EROI) of Oil Shale." Sustainability 3.11 (2011): 2307-322. Gagnon, Nathan, Charles A.s. Hall, and Lysle Brinker. "A Preliminary Investigation of Energy Return on Energy Investment for Global Oil and Gas Production." Energies 2.3 (2009): 490503. Gupta, Ajay K., and Charles A.s. Hall. "A Review of the Past and Current State of EROI Data." Sustainability 3.10 (2011): 1796-809. Hall, Charles A. S., and Kent A. Klitgaard. Energy and the Wealth of Nations: Understanding the Biophysical Economy. New York, NY: Springer Verlag, 2012. Hall, Charles A.s., Jessica G. Lambert, and Stephen B. Balogh. "EROI of Different Fuels and the Implications for Society." Energy Policy 64 (2014): 141-52. Hamilton, James D. "Causes and Consequences of the Oil Shock of 2007–08." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2009.1 (2009): 215-61. Hirsch, Robert, Roger Bezdek, and Robert Wendling. "Peaking of World Oil Production: Impacts, Risks, Management." US Department of Energy (2005). King, Carey W., and Charles A.s. Hall. "Relating Financial and Energy Return on Investment." Sustainability 3.10 (2011): 1810-832. 17 KAM Tan / 79-354 (Spring 2014) Lambert, Jessica G., Charles A.s. Hall, Stephen Balogh, Ajay Gupta, and Michelle Arnold. "Energy, EROI and Quality of Life." Energy Policy 64 (2014): 153-67. Marks, Robert. The Origins of the Modern World: A Global and Ecological Narrative from the Fifteenth to the Twenty-first Century. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield, 2007. Poisson, Alexandre, and Charles Hall. "Time Series EROI for Canadian Oil and Gas." Energies 6.11 (2013): 5940-959. Rapier, Robert. Power Plays: Energy Options in the Age of Peak Oil. New York: Apress, 2012. Smil, Vaclav. Energy at the Crossroads: Global Perspectives and Uncertainties. Cambridge, MA: MIT, 2003. Tainter, Joseph A. The Collapse of Complex Societies. Cambridge, Cambridgeshire: Cambridge UP, 1988. Tverberg, Gail E. "Oil Supply Limits and the Continuing Financial Crisis." Energy 37.1 (2012): 2734. World Energy Outlook 2013. Rep. London: IEA, 2013. Yaritani, Hiroaki, and Jun Matsushima. "Analysis of the Energy Balance of Shale Gas Development." Energies 7 (2014). 18