* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Managing Resource Wealth
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Gas in Cyprus: How to avoid the curse? CONFERENCE ON ‘THE CYPRUS ECONOMY’ L S E , 1 0 TH F E B R U A R Y 2 0 1 2 RICK VAN DER PLOEG OXCARRE, UNIVERSITY OF OXFORD SEE WWW.OXCARRE.OX.AC.UK FOR RESEARCH AND POLICY PAPERS Aphrodite Gas Field Offshore of southern coast of Cyprus: contains 5 to 8 trillion cubic feet of natural gas (area of 100 km2). Concession to Noble Energy. Compare with gas reserves in Netherlands, the UK and Norway at end of 2010 of 41.5, 9.0 and 72.1 trillion cubic feet, resp. Relative to tiny size of population of 800,000, Cyprus has large gas reserves compared with these other European countries. Scaling up to NL population (x20) gives 2.5 to 4 times as much gas reserves as for the NL. Gas reserves of Cyprus Norway has population of 4.8 million (x6), so Cyprus field amounts to 30 or 48 trillion cubic feet if blown up to size of Norway which is 42% to 66% of Norway’s reserves. UK population is 62 million (about x80), so reserves are 400 to 640 compared with 41.5 for UK actual gas reserves. So Cyprus has sizeable reserves! But not compared with Iran or Qatar which have huge reserves of 1045.7 and 894.2 cubic feet, resp. Questions Is there more to the curse than Dutch disease and declining traded sector? Danger for tourism! How about rent grabbing, corruption and conflict? How can exhaustible gas be transformed into reproducible physical or human capital by saving the resource rents? What are best ways of harnessing windfalls? Does this involve sovereign wealth funds, citizen dividends, public infrastructure or cutting debt? How do bottlenecks in non-traded and construction sectors, and notorious volatility of gas/oil prices affect best way of harnessing gas windfall? Disappointing performance despite natural resources 5 17th century Spain despite gold/silver from New World. Resource-poor Holland did much better. Negative growth rates during past decades: e.g., Venezuela, Iran,Libya, Kuwait, Quatar. Decline in OPEC GDP/ capita during last few decades while other countries enjoyed growth. Gold boom in 70’s did not help South Africa much (Stokke, 2005). Dutch economy and the Slochteren natural gas reserves led to unsustainable welfare state. Average yearly real GDP per capita growth 1970-2004 -5 0 5 NEGATIVE PARTIAL CORRELATION BETWEEN ECONOMIC GROWTH AND RESOURCE ABUNDANCE (not for food or agriculture exports) Korea, Rep. Taiwan, China Singapore Malta Hong Cambodia Kong, China Thailand Indonesia Ireland Malaysia Sri Lanka Tunisia Egypt, Arab Rep. Norway Portugal Chile Hungary Japan Spain Austria Finland United Kingdom Belgium Italy United States Pakistan Turkey Greece France Israel Brazil Canada Jordan Australia Morocco Netherlands Costa Rica SwedenColombia Denmark Mexico Sudan Ecuador New Zealand Paraguay Panama Philippines Cameroon Uruguay Burkina Faso Algeria Switzerland Guatemala Congo, Rep. Malawi Honduras Mali Chad Nigeria Argentina Solomon Islands SaoEl Tome and Principe Bolivia Benin Salvador Peru Senegal Ghana Burundi Togo India Central African Republic Niger Madagascar Trinidad and Tobago Fiji Gabon Mauritania Suriname Guyana Saudi Arabia Venezuela, RB Cote d'Ivoire Zambia Nicaragua Congo, Dem. Rep. Kuwait Libya Liberia 0 20 40 60 Natural Resources exports in percent of GDP, 1970 80 Figure: Growth and Natural Resources Abundance Data source: World Development Indicators, 2006 Source: World Bank Development Indicators 2006 6 P0sitive experiences 7 Botswana: 40% of GDP stems from diamonds but has second highest education/GNP and highest growth rates since 1965. GDP/capita is ten times that of Nigeria. Norway had huge growth in oil exports since 1971 and third largest exporter after Saudi-Arabia, but has fared fairly well. United Arab Emirates also turned curse into blessing by investing in modernizing infrastructure and investing in welfare state and free access to education. But avoid speculative booms (Kazakhstan). Mineral abundance US mid 19th to mid 20th century explains much of subsequent growth: driven by learning, IRTS and US government claimed no ultimate title to mineral rights (Habbakuk, 1962; David and Wright, 1977; Wright and Czelusta, 2004). Also, Germany and UK late 19th century. Lessons: avoid corruption, diversify, education, and exploit complementarities linkages of manufacturing with resource sector. Resource Abundance Associated With: 8 Crowding out of non-resource exports and foreign direct investment. Less openness. Elicits corruption and extreme rent seeking. Crowds out foreign capital, social capital, human capital and financial capital. Deters FDI in non-resource sectors Erodes legal system. Bigger Gini index of inequality. Less school enrolment and expected years of schooling (Botwana exception). Delays development of financial institutions. Armed conflicts and civil wars. COMPOSITION OF WEALTH, 2000 INTANGIBLE CAPITAL IS MAIN CREATOR OF WEALTH Source: World Bank (2006, Table 2.1). Note: All dollars at nominal exchange rates. Oil states excluded National wealth is PV sustainable consumption 2000-25 using discount rate of 4%. Produced capital from PIM. 9 I. Dutch Disease and Gas Curse 10 Windfall gain in demand for gas from abroad induces an appreciation of the real exchange rate. Non-resource export sectors go in decline: tourism. The sheltered sector gets a boost as labour and other factors move from traded to sheltered sectors. ‘It seems ungrateful to talk of a disease’ (The Economist) Decline of exposed sectors may be efficient response to the gas boom. However, if there is learning by doing in the non-gas export sectors, there may be falls in output growth and welfare. Extraction of Gas Requires Labour and Capital 11 Resource movement as well as spending effects of gas boom. Labour is drawn both out NT and T to gas sectors. Within context of Heckscher-Ohlin the Rybczynski theorem implies output of capital-intensive non-gas sector expands. If T-sector is K-intensive, gas boom induces proindustrialisation if spending effect is not too large. Strong in small (island) economies. II. Volatility and the Gas Curse 12 ‘What commodity price lack in trend, they make up for in variance’ (Deaton, JEcPersp, 1999). Resource rich economies are vulnerable to high volatility of resource prices, especially as supply is fairly inelastic. Particularly bad as many resource rich economies are not diversified: specialised in resources and small sheltered sector. In fact, they specialise away from non-resource traded goods which causes even more volatility and interest rate rises! Traded sector shrinks until it vanishes (Hausmann & Rigobon). Volatility also bad for growth, investment, income distribution, poverty and educational attainment (Ramey & Ramey, Aizenman & Marion, Flug et al) Links between output volatility and growth 13 Higher volatility means more uncertainty-induced errors and thus less irreversible investment and lower growth (Bernanke, QJE, 1983; Pindyck, 1991; Aizenman and Marion, RIE, 1991) Especially if it is costly to switch factors of production (Bertola, JME, 1994; Dixit and Rob, JET, 1994) Or: higher volatility leads to more precautionary saving and thus more investment and growth (Mirman, Etrica, 1971) Higher variance commands investments with higher return and thus higher growth (Black, 1987) Net effect of volatility on growth can in theory be negative or positive, so needs to be settled empirically Empirical result: volatility is quintessence of resource curse! The facts 14 Volatile countries have lower growth (Figure 1) Average Yearly GDP/Capita Growth (1970-2003, %) -5 0 5 10 1. Equatorial Guinea United Arab Emirates Iraq Liberia 0 10 20 Standard Deviation of Yearly GDP/Capita Growth (1970-2003, %) Fitted Values (slope = -.247 (.049); Adj. R2=.14) 30 The facts 15 Resource dependent countries are more volatile Standard Deviation of Yearly GDP/Capita Growth (1970-2003, %) 10 20 30 Liberia United Arab Emirates Bahamas, The 0 5. 0 20 40 60 Average Resource Share of GDP (1970-2003, %) Fitted Values (slope =.149 (.016); Adj. R2=.44) 80 100 1 .5 0 -.5 Marginal Effect of Rent Share on Growth for Average 1970 Openness 1.5 Blessing for some 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 Finiancial Development in 1970 Marginal Effect of Rent Share on Growth for Average 1970 Openness 95% Confidence Interval 16 1 The Volatility Curse 17 Volatility of unanticipated output growth is quintessential feature of the natural resource curse! Positive direct effect of the level of natural resource exports on growth is swamped by negative indirect effect of volatility on growth performance. Countries with high degrees of financial development can turn resource wealth into blessing and boon for growth. Point-base impact stronger than diffuse resources. III. Windfalls encourage unsustainable policies 18 Erosion of critical faculties of politicians. Netherlands in the seventies dressed up the welfare state and governments since 1989 have been trying to have a sustainable welfare state. Induces excessive borrowing (Manzano and Rigobon, 2002) & invest in ‘prestige’ projects. Loose sight of growth-promoting policies and valuefor-money management. E.g.: FES in Netherlands State-led industrialisation through import substitution and heavy subsidies for manufacturing. IV. Resources ⇒rent seeking, corruption and conflict 19 Allocation of talent: countries with many rent seekers and lawyers grow more slowly than countries with lots of engineers (Murphy et al) Corruption, political instability, bureaucratic inefficiency, assassinations and conflict also hamper economic growth (Mauro, 1995; Leite and Weidmann, 1999). Bad effects of resource growth mainly operates via worsening of institutions, rule of law, etc. Increases civil strife and wars, especially in sub-Saharan Africa thru’ weakening of state or finance of rebels (Collier and Hoeffler, 2004; Ross, 2004). War lord competition (Skaperdas, 2004). Distinguish between grievance and greed (Ollson and Fors, 2004). Especially bad for point-based rather than diffuse resources. Effects of resource dependence on institutional quality on economic growth Annual growth in real GDP per capita Sachs and Warner (1997a) Based on data in Sachs and Warner (1997b) Initial income -1.76 (8.56) -1.28 (6.65) -1.26 (6.70) Openness 1.33 (3.35) 1.45 (3.36) 1.66 (3.87) Resource dependance -10.57 (7.01) Rule of law 0.36 (3.54) - - Institutional quality - 0.6 (0.64) -1.3 (1.13) Investments 1.02 (3.45) 0.15 (6.73) 0.16 (7.15) Interaction term - - 15.40 (2.40) Number of countries 71 Adjusted R2 0.72 -6.69 (5.43) 87 0.69 20 Mehlum, Moene and Torvik (2005a) -14.34 (4.21) 87 0.71 Marginal effects of different types of natural resources on growth for different levels of institutional quality Primary exports share of GDP Ores and Mineral Prod of gold, metals production as silver and exports as share of GNP diamonds as share of GDP share of GDP Worst institutions −0.548 −0.946 −1.127 −1.145 Average institutions −0.378 0.425 0.304 0.279 Average + one s.d. institutions −0.288 1.152 1.062 1.183 Best institutions −0.228 1.629 1.560 1.776 Source: Boschini, et. al. (2003) 21 Turning Gas Windfalls into Sovereign Wealth Assume: r* = ρ Optimal consumption path involves full intertemporal smoothing: Consumption jumps at date of discovery and then constant As resources depleted, F falls (debt reduced/ assets acquired) to hold total stock of wealth constant C = Y + T = Y + r * [ PV ( N ) − F ] = Y + r *[V − F ] Once resource exhausted, permanently higher income from interest on SWF (-r*F). Other approaches Permanent Income Hypothesis: Use of Sovereign Wealth Funds Optimal if r = r* Bird-in-hand. PIH ignoring resource wealth until extracted Optimal. Genuine saving 24 Public and private saving at home and abroad, net of depreciation (GNP − C − δ K) Plus current spending on education to capture change in intangible human wealth Minus depletion of natural exhaustible and renewable resources Minus damage of stock pollutants (CO2 and particulate matter) Equals increase in nation’s wealth (Dasgupta and Mäler, 2000; Hamilton & Hartwick, 2005). Hartwick rule: genuine saving should be zero! GENUINE SAVING AND EXHAUSTIBLE RESOURCE RENTS Source: World Bank 25 Consuming, saving, investing: Ricardian consumers The Ricardian curse: (continued) - Fall in r* private sector surge of investment and (especially, if δ ≥ ρ) consumption. - Government prudence is irrelevant: eg, low t1, high t2 foreseen by private sector. Kazakhstan:2004-08: • Govt saved 2/3rd oil revenue; • SWF + reserves increased by $50bn Private external debt increased by $30bn • Political considerations Political considerations: with partisan preferences about public investment projects, incumbent will over-borrow and over-invest in its pet projects, especially if these are more illiquid than SWF and chance of being kicked out of office is large. Budget inertia and weak lobbying favouring projects that confer large benefits on small groups. Common-pool problems: voracious rent seeking. In failed states, better to leave oil under the ground. Transparency is a must 28 Highest standards of public and corporate accountability, PSR/CSR and transparency: publish what you earn from exports and publish what you do with the revenues. See Resource Charter. Exploitation companies should publish their payments to all governments and encourage mandatory disclosure mechanism. Make debt relief etc. contingent on transparency, free press and anti-corruption efforts – role IMF, World Bank and UNDP. Establish global information office. Western banks should be punished for allowing tainted money to be deposited. How to handle extreme volatility? • Evidence that volatility a key factor in resource curse. 1) Hedging • Mexico: spent $1.5bn on option, earned $8bn • Ecuador, Colombia, Algeria, Texas, Louisiana; • Unlikely to become widespread? • Political risks when lose • Market impact of hedging: • Information • Market power 2) Stabilization fund Role for stabilization fund to: a) Self-insure against periods of low price/ revenue b) ‘Park’ funds abroad when absorptive capacity is limited Resource funds in practise: -- two distinct objectives: • • • Stabilization fund / savings (‘future generations’) fund: Need to keep clear separate objectives & importance 21 out 31 oil producers have funds (2005, IMF); 10 focus on stabilisation, 8 stabilisation and saving. • Stabilisation funds typically price or revenue contingent • Eg Trinidad and Tobago: 60% of ‘excess revenue’ (based on deviation of price from long moving average) placed in fund. Design criteria: how big should a stabilization fund be? • Cost of volatility to the domestic economy? • Opportunities for borrowing in downturn? • Stochastic process governing resource? • Political risk – fund is lootable? 3) Residual volatility – Clear that will not feasible to fully insulate • 2008-early 2009, MENAP forex reserves fell $40 bn and non-oil growth fell 5% points. • Transmission channels other than revenue – Resource sector investment – Other private sector responses – Capital mobility – Zambia – Therefore, also need domestic economy that can handle volatility • Market flexibility….. Labour, capital markets • Avoid hard to reverse commitments • Diversify…..