Download NOT

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts
no text concepts found
Transcript
Determining Reserve Ranges
CLRS 1999
by
Rodney Kreps
Guy Carpenter Instrat
Why can’t you actuaries
get the reserves right?
Feel like a target?
What are Reserves?
1 Actual Dollars Paid.
2 Distribution of Potential Actual Dollars
Paid.
3 Locator of the Distribution of Potential
Actual Dollars Paid.
4 An esoteric mystery dependent on the
whims of the CFO.
And the Right Answer -
ALL of the above.
Actual Dollars Paid
• Only true after runoff.
• Gives a hindsight view.
• Lies behind the question
“Why can’t you get it right?”
Distribution of Potential
Actual Dollars Paid
• All planning estimates are distributions.
• ALL planning estimates are distributions.
• ALL planning estimates are
DISTRIBUTIONS.
• Basically, anything interesting on a goingforward basis is a distribution
Distributions frequently
characterized by locator and
spread
• However, the choice of these is basically a
subjective matter.
• Mathematical convenience of calculation is
not necessarily a good criterion for choice.
• Neither is “Gramps did it this way.”
Measures of spread
• Standard deviation
• Usual confidence interval
• Minimum uncertainty
Standard deviation
• Simple formula.
• Other spread measures often expressed as
plus or minus so many standard deviations.
• Familiar from (ab)normal distribution.
Usual confidence interval
• Sense is, “How large an interval do I need
to be reasonably comfortable that the value
is in it?”
• E.g., 90% confidence interval. Why 90%?
• Why not 95%? 99%? 99.9%?
• Statisticians’ canonical comfort level seems
to be 95%.
• Choice depends on situation and individual.
Minimum uncertainty
• AKA “Intrinsic uncertainty,” Softness,” or
“Slop.”
• All estimates and most measurements have
intrinsic uncertainty.
• The stochastic variable is essentially not
known to within the intrinsic uncertainty.
• Sense is, “What is the smallest interval
containing the value?”
Minimum uncertainty (2)
• “How little can I include and not be too
uncomfortable pretending that the value is
inside the interval?”
• Plausible choice: Middle 50%.
• Personal choice: Middle third.
• Clearly it depends on situation and
individual.
E.g. Catastrophe PML
• David Miller paper at May 1999 CAS
meeting.
• Treated only parameter uncertainty from
limited data.
• 95% confidence interval was factor of 2.
• Minimum uncertainty was 30%.
Locator of the Distribution of
Potential Actual Dollars Paid
•
•
•
•
Can’t book a distribution.
Need a locator for the distribution.
Actuaries have traditionally used the mean.
WHY THE MEAN?
WHY THE MEAN?
• It is simple to calculate.
• It is encouraged by the CAS statement of
principles.
• It is safe - “Nobody ever got fired for
buying IBM.”
Some Possible locators
•
•
•
•
•
Mean
Mode
Median
Fixed percentile
Other ?!!
How to choose a relevant
locator?
• Example: bet on one throw of a die whose
sides are weighted proportionally to their
values.
• Obvious choice is 6.
• This is the mode.
• Why not the mean of 4.333?
• Even rounded to 4?
What happened there?
• Frame situation by a “pain” function.
• Take pain as zero when the throw is our chosen
locator, and 1 when it is not.
• This corresponds to doing a single bet.
• Minimize the pain over the distribution:
• Choose as locator as the most probable
value.
Generalization to continuous
variables
• Define an appropriate pain function.
– Depends on business meaning of distribution.
– Function of locator and stochastic variable.
• Choose the locator so as to minimize the average
pain over the distribution.
• “Statistical Decision Theory”
– Can be generalized many directions
• Parallel to Hamiltonian Principle of Least Work
Claim: All the usual locators
can be framed this way
Further claim: this gives us a
way to see the relevance of
different locators in the given
business context.
Example: Mean
• Pain function is quadratic in x with
minimum at the locator:
• P(L,X) = (X-L)^2
• Note that it is equally bad to come in high
or low, and two dollars off is four times as
bad as one dollar off.
Squigglies: Proof for Mean
• Integrate the pain function over the
distribution, and express the result in terms
of the mean M and variance V of x. This
gives Pain as a function of the Locator:
• P(L) = V + (M-L)^2
• Clearly a minimum at L = M
Why the Mean?
• Is there some reason why this symmetric
quadratic pain function makes sense in the
context of reserves?
• Perhaps unfairly: ever try to spend a
squared dollar?
Example: Mode
• Pain function is zero in a small interval
around the locator, and 1 elsewhere.
• Generates the most likely result.
• Could generalize to any finite interval (and
get a different result)
• Corresponds to simple bet, no degrees of
pain.
Example: Median
• Pain function is the absolute difference of x
and the locator:
• P(L,X) = Abs(X-L)
• Equally bad on upside and downside, but
linear: two dollars off is only twice as bad
as one dollar off.
• Generates the X corresponding to the 50th
percentile.
Example: Arbitrary Percentile
• Pain function is linear but asymmetric with
different slope above and below the locator:
• P(L,X) = (L-X) for X<L and S*(X-L) for
X>L
• If S>1, then coming in high (above the
locator) is worse than coming in low.
• Generates the X corresponding to the
S/(S+1) percentile. E.g., S=3 gives the 75th
percentile.
An esoteric mystery dependent
on the whims of the CFO
• What shape would we expect for the pain
function?
• Assume a CFO who is in it for the long
term and has no perverse incentives.
• Assume a stable underwriting environment.
• Take the context, for example, of one-year
reserve runoff.
Suggestion for pain function:
The decrease in net economic worth
of the company as a result of the
reserve changes.
Some interested parties who
affect the pain function:
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
policyholders
stockholders
agents
regulators
rating agencies
investment analysts
lending institutions
If the Losses come in lower than
the stated reserves:
• Analysts perceive company as strongly
reserved.
• Not much problem from the IRS.
• Dividends could have been larger.
• Slightly uncompetitive if underwriters talk
to pricing actuaries and pricing actuaries
talk to reserving actuaries.
If the Losses come in higher than
the stated reserves:
• If only slightly higher, same as industry.
• Otherwise, increasing problems from the
regulators.
– Start to trigger IRIS tests.
• Credit rating suffers.
• Analysts perceive company as weak.
– Possible troubles in collecting Reinsurance, etc.
• Renewals problematical.
Generic Reserving Pain function
• Climbs much more steeply on high side
than low.
• Probably has steps as critical values are
exceeded.
• Probably non-linear on high side.
• Weak dependence on low side
Generic Reserving Pain function (2)
• Simplest form is linear on the low side and
quadratic on the high:
• P(L,X) = S*(L-X) for X<L and (X-L)^2 for
X>L
Made-up example:
• Company has lognormally distributed reserves,
with coefficient of variation of 10%.
• Mean reserves are 3.5 and S = 0.1 (units of
surplus).
• Then 10% high is as bad as 10% low, 16% high
is as bad as 25% low, and 25% high is as bad as
63% low.
• Locator is 5.1% above the mean, at the 71st
percentile level.
...
ESSENTIALS
...
• All estimates are soft.
– Sometimes shockingly so.
– The uncertainty in the reserves is NOT the
uncertainty in the reserve estimator.
• The appropriate reserve estimate
depends on the pain function.
– The mean is unlikely to be the correct
estimator.