Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Demand Analysis Some Questions • What is behind a consumer’s demand curve? • How do consumers choose from among various consumer “goods”? • What determines the value of a consumer good? What is Consumer Theory? • Study of how people use their limited means to make purposeful choices. • Assumes that consumers understand their choices (possibilities) and the prices (opportunity costs) associated with each choice. • Assumes that consumers consider the alternatives and choose the one they like best. Consumer Theory - Why? • Two important reasons: – to understand the foundations of market demand (bake the demand curve from scratch) – to address several interesting consumer theory issues that are best understood using this model rather than the aggregate demand model Two Components of Consumer Demand • Opportunities: – What can the consumer afford? – What are the consumption possibilities? – Summarized by the budget constraint • Preferences: – What does the consumer like? – How much does a consumer like a good? – Summarized by the utility function Utility • The value a consumer places on a unit of a good or service depends on the pleasure or satisfaction he or she expects to derive form having or consuming it at the point of making a consumption (consumer) choice. • In economics the satisfaction or pleasure consumers derive from the consumption of consumer goods is called “utility”. • Consumers, however, cannot have every thing they wish to have. Consumers’ choices are constrained by their incomes. • Within the limits of their incomes, consumers make their consumption choices by evaluating and comparing consumer goods with regard to their “utilities.” Our basic assumptions about a “rational” consumer: • Consumers are utility maximizers • Consumers prefer more of a good (thing) to less of it. • Facing choices X and Y, a consumer would either prefer X to Y or Y to X, or would be indifferent between them. • Transitivity: If a consumer prefers X to Y and Y to Z, we conclude he/she prefers X to Z • Diminishing marginal utility: As more and more of good is consumed by a consumer, ceteris paribus, beyond a certain point the utility of each additional unit starts to fall. How to Measure Utility Measuring utility in “utils” (Cardinal): • Jack derives 10 utils from having one slice of pizza but only 5 utils from having a burger. • In many introductory microeconomics textbooks this approach to measuring utility is still considered effective for teaching purposes. Measuring utility by comparison (Ordinal): • Jill prefers a burger to a slice of pizza and a slice of pizza to a hotdog. Often consumers are able to be more precise in expressing their preferences. For example, we could say: • Jill is willing to trade a burger for four hotdogs but she will give up only two hotdogs for a slice of pizza. • We can infer that to Jill, a burger has twice as much utility as a slice of pizza, and a slice of pizza has twice as much utility as a hotdog. Utility and Money • Because we use money (rather than hotdogs!) in just about all of our trade transactions, we might as well use it as our comparative measure of utility. (Note: This way of measuring utility is not much different from measuring utility in utils) • Jill could say: I am willing to pay $4 for a burger, $2 for a slice of pizza and $1 for a hotdog. Note: Even though Jill obviously values a burger more (four times as much) than a hot dog, she may still choose to buy a hotdog, even if she has enough money to buy a burger, or a slice of pizza, for that matter. (We will see why and how shortly.) Total Utility versus Marginal Utility • Marginal utility is the utility a consumer derives from the last unit of a consumer good she or he consumes (during a given consumption period), ceteris paribus. • Total utility is the total utility a consumer derives from the consumption of all of the units of a good or a combination of goods over a given consumption period, ceteris paribus. Total utility = Sum of marginal utilities The Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility • Over a given consumption period, the more of a good a consumer has, or has consumed, the less marginal utility an additional unit contributes to his or her overall satisfaction (total utility). • Alternatively, we could say: over a given consumption period, as more and more of a good is consumed by a consumer, beyond a certain point, the marginal utility of additional units begins to fall. Total and Marginal Utility for Ice Cream Q 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 ($) TU 0 40 85 120 140 150 157 160 160 155 145 ($) MU 40 45 35 20 10 7 3 0 -5 -10 145 Total Utility 200 150 100 50 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 7 8 9 10 11 ($) M U 50 40 30 20 10 0 1 -10 -20 2 3 4 5 6 1 11 Q 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 ($) TU 0 40 85 120 140 150 157 160 160 155 145 ($) MU 40 45 35 20 10 7 3 0 -5 -10 145 How much ice cream does Jill buy in a month? Some facts of life: • Limited income • Opportunity cost of making a choice: Buying ice cream leaves Jill less money to buy other things: each dollar spent on ice cream could be spent on hamburger. • In fact, consumers compare the (expected) utility derived from one additional dollar spent on one good to the utility derived from one additional dollar spent on another good. What is a Budget Constraint? • A budget constraint shows the consumer’s purchase opportunities as every combination of two goods that can be bought at given prices using a given amount of income. • The budget constraint measures the combinations of purchases that a person can afford to make with a given amount of monetary income. THE BUDGET LINE: What is Attainable 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 12 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures 8 6 4 2 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 THE BUDGET LINE: What is Attainable 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 12 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures 8 6 4 2 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 THE BUDGET LINE: What is Attainable 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 12 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures 8 6 4 2 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 THE BUDGET LINE: What is Attainable 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 12 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures 8 6 4 2 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 THE BUDGET LINE: What is Attainable 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 12 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures 8 6 4 2 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 THE BUDGET LINE: What is Attainable 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 12 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures 8 (Unattainable) 6 4 2 (Attainable) 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 THE BUDGET LINE: What is Attainable 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 12 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures 8 (Unattainable) 6 4 2 (Attainable) 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 THE BUDGET LINE: What is Attainable 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 12 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures 8 (Unattainable) 6 4 2 (Attainable) 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 INDIFFERENCE CURVES What is Preferred 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 An Indifference Schedule Combination j Units of A Units of B 12 2 j 12 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures 8 6 4 2 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 INDIFFERENCE CURVES What is Preferred 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 An Indifference Schedule Combination j k j 12 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures 8 k 6 4 Units of A Units of B 2 12 6 2 4 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 INDIFFERENCE CURVES What is Preferred 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 An Indifference Schedule Combination j k l Units of A Units of B 12 6 4 2 4 6 j 12 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures 8 k 6 l 4 2 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 INDIFFERENCE CURVES What is Preferred 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 An Indifference Schedule Combination Units of A j k l m 12 6 4 3 Units of B 2 4 6 8 j 12 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures 8 k 6 l 4 m 2 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 INDIFFERENCE CURVES What is Preferred 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 An Indifference Schedule Combination Units of A j k l m 12 6 4 3 Units of B 2 4 6 8 j 12 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures 8 k 6 l 4 m I 2 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 INDIFFERENCE CURVES What is Preferred 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 An Indifference Schedule Combination Units of A j k l m 12 6 4 3 Units of B 2 4 6 8 j 12 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures 8 k 6 The slope represents the marginal rate of substitution, (MRS) l 4 m 2 I2 I1 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 INDIFFERENCE CURVES What is Preferred 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 An Indifference Schedule Combination Units of A j k l m 12 6 4 3 Units of B 2 4 6 8 12 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures 8 6 4 2 I1 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 INDIFFERENCE CURVES What is Preferred 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 An Indifference Schedule Combination Units of A j k l m 12 6 4 3 Units of B 2 4 6 8 12 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures 8 6 4 I4 I3 2 I2 I1 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 INDIFFERENCE CURVES What is Preferred 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 An Indifference Schedule Combination Units of A j k l m 12 6 4 3 Units of B 2 4 6 8 12 An Indifference Map 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures 8 6 4 I4 I3 2 I2 I1 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 EQUILIBRIUM AT TANGENCY 8 6 4 2 0 0 $12 3 12 6 12 9 12 12 12 An Indifference Schedule Combination Units of A j k l m 12 6 4 3 Units of B 2 4 6 8 12 10 Quantity of A Units of Units of Total A Price B Price $1.50 $1.00 Expenditures (Unattainable) 8 6 4 2 I4 I3 I2 (Attainable) I1 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 EQUILIBRIUM AT TANGENCY (Unattainable) Quantity of A Equilibrium 12 occurs when the consumer 10 selects the 8 combination which reaches 6 the highest 4 attainable indifference 2 curve. I4 I3 I2 (Attainable) I1 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 EQUILIBRIUM AT TANGENCY What happens if the price of B increases to $1.50? The budget line rotates reflecting the reduction in the quantity of B units which is attainable. 12 $1.00 6 Quantity of A PriceB QuantityB 10 8 6 4 2 I3 0 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 EQUILIBRIUM AT TANGENCY What happens if the price of B increases to $1.50? The budget line rotates reflecting the reduction in the quantity of B units which is attainable. 12 $1.00 1.50 6 3 Quantity of A PriceB QuantityB 10 8 6 4 2 By recording the various quantities 0 demanded at the various prices yields the Demand schedule I3 I2 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 EQUILIBRIUM AT TANGENCY What happens if the price of B increases to $1.50? The budget line rotates reflecting the reduction in the quantity of B units which is attainable. 12 $1.00 1.50 6 3 Quantity of A PriceB QuantityB 10 8 6 4 2 By recording the various quantities 0 demanded at the various prices yields the Demand schedule I3 I2 2 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12 DERIVING THE DEMAND CURVE What happens if the price of B increases to $1.50? Price of B PriceB QuantityB $1.00 1.50 6 3 $1.50 Plotting the Points yields the Demand Curve for Product B 1.00 By recording the various quantities 0 demanded at the 2 various prices yields the demand schedule. DB 4 6 8 Quantity of B 10 12