Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Economics of Management Strategy BEE3027 Lecture 4 Non-linear Pricing • In this section we will deal with ways how a monopoly (or a firm with market power) can capture surplus from consumers. • These are more sophisticated approaches to pricing than the standard models of industrial organisation, which assume firms charge a single price for each unit sold. Monopoly problem • Standard monopolist sets MR = MC to determine optimal output and price. • Typical consequence of that is that there are consumers who would be served in a perfectly competitive market but are not: – Deadweight loss. • How can the problem be overcome? 1st Degree Price discrimination • In this (rather unrealistic) case, the monopolist can determine each consumer’s reservation price and charge that price. • As a result, the monopolist will extract the whole consumer surplus. • It is economically efficient, but it is debatable whether this is desirable. 3rd Degree Price discrimination • Here, the monopolist is not able to perfectly distinguish each consumer’s reservation price. • However it can screen consumers into types: – E.g. Students, OAPs. • As such, it can charge different prices to different types of consumers. 3rd Degree Price discrimination • 3rd Degree Price Discrimination can be beneficial to consumers. • A key factor is the relative size of the two groups and their demand elasticities. • Often, one group will “subsidise” the other. – Students pay cheaper prices for cinema tickets 2nd Degree Price discrimination • Another alternative for a monopolist is to give quantity discounts: – It can charge different prices for different blocks of units a consumer purchases. • This type of pricing scheme is used quite commonly by utility companies. – EDF Energy charges a price for the first block of Kwatts and a lower one for the second block. 2nd Degree Price discrimination • P = 10 - q • Monopolist now chooses two blocks of units to sell at different prices: – q1 at p1 – (q2 – q1) at p2. • Profits are given by: p1q1 p2 (q2 q1 ) cq2 (10 q1 )q1 (10 q2 )(q2 q1 ) cq2 • Monopolist takes q1as given and maximises profit. • MR2 = MC => q1 c 10 2q2 q1 c 0 q2 5 2 2nd Degree Price discrimination • Plug the optimal q2 into the original profit function to obtain: q1 c q1 c q1 c (10 q1 )q1 (10 5 )(5 q1 ) c(5 ) 2 2 2 • Which when simplified gives: q1 c q1 c q1 c (10 q1 )q1 (5 )(5 ) c(5 ) 2 2 2 2nd Degree Price discrimination • Calculating the profit maximising condition: 10 2q1 0.5(10 q1 ) c / 2 0 10 c 20 c q1 , p1 3 3 • Plugging the value of q1 back into q2 gives: 10 c c q1 c 20 2c 10 2c 3 q2 5 5 , p2 2 2 3 3 2nd Degree Price discrimination • So, if c=0: q1 10 / 3, p1 20 / 3 q2 20 / 3, p2 10 / 3 • So, the first block of units is more expensive than the second block of units! • This allows the monopolist to extract extra consumer surplus away from the DWL area: – More efficient! Two-Part Tariff • Many services that we purchase charge consumers with annual membership charges rather than a perunit fee. – – – – Gym; Sports clubs; Theatres; Amusement parks. • The logic is that even a monopolist cannot usually extract all consumer surplus. • By adding an extra pricing instrument, the monopolist is able to extract all CS. Two-Part Tariff • The logic behind two-part tariff is that the monopolist will set P=MC to determine optimal output and set F = CS to extract full surplus. • However, there are several problems: – Monopolist does not necessarily know individual demand schedules perfectly; – Consumers will have different demand schedules, hence if it sets F too high, it may lose some (or all) customers! – Still, two-part tariffs are quite common