Download Fourth Edition - pearsoncmg.com

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Copenhagen Consensus wikipedia , lookup

Public good wikipedia , lookup

Marginalism wikipedia , lookup

Economic equilibrium wikipedia , lookup

Pigovian tax wikipedia , lookup

Coase theorem wikipedia , lookup

Supply and demand wikipedia , lookup

Perfect competition wikipedia , lookup

Externality wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
R. GLENN
HUBBARD
O’BRIEN
ANTHONY PATRICK
Economics
FOURTH EDITION
CHAPTER
5
Externalities, Environmental Policy,
and Public Goods
Chapter Outline and
Learning Objectives
5.1
Externalities and Economic
Efficiency
5.2
Private Solutions to
Externalities: The Coase
Theorem
5.3
Government Policies to
Deal with Externalities
5.4
Four Categories of Goods
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
2 of 36
Can Government Policies Help Protect the Environment?
• Government policies to reduce pollution have proven to be controversial.
• In the past, Congress often ordered firms to use particular methods to
reduce pollution, but many economists are critical of this approach—known
as command and control—because some companies can reduce their
emissions at a lower cost if they are allowed to choose the method.
• Many economists argue that a more efficient way to reduce pollution is
through a market-based approach such as RGGI, a cap-and-trade program,
that relies on economic incentives rather than on administrative rules.
• The U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) plans to implement New
Source Performance Standards (NSPS) for air pollution that would affect the
entire nation.
• AN INSIDE LOOK AT POLICY on page 162 discusses arguments for and
against the stricter air-quality standard proposed by the Environmental
Protection Agency.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
3 of 36
Economics in Your Life
What’s the “Best” Level of Pollution?
Policymakers debate alternative approaches for achieving the goal of reducing
carbon dioxide emissions.
See if you can answer these questions by the end of the chapter:
How do we know the “best” level of carbon emissions?
If carbon dioxide emissions hurt the environment, should the government take
action to eliminate them completely?
Externality A benefit or cost that affects someone who is not directly involved
in the production or consumption of a good or service.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
4 of 36
Externalities and Economic Efficiency
5.1 LEARNING OBJECTIVE
Identify examples of positive and negative externalities and use graphs to show
how externalities affect economic efficiency.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
5 of 36
The Effect of Externalities
Private cost The cost borne by the producer of a good or service.
Social cost The total cost of producing a good or service, including both the
private cost and any external cost.
Private benefit The benefit received by the consumer of a good or service.
Social benefit The total benefit from consuming a good or service, including
both the private benefit and any external benefit.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
6 of 36
How a Negative Externality in Production Reduces Economic Efficiency
Figure 5.1
The Effect of Pollution on
Economic Efficiency
Because utilities do not bear the
cost of acid rain, they produce
electricity beyond the
economically efficient level.
Supply curve S1 represents just
the marginal private cost that the
utility has to pay.
Supply curve S2 represents the
marginal social cost, which
includes the costs to those
affected by acid rain.
If the supply curve were S2, rather
than S1, market equilibrium would
occur at price PEfficient and quantityQEfficient, the economically efficient level of output.
But when the supply curve is S1, the market equilibrium occurs at price PMarket and quantity
QMarket, where there is a deadweight loss equal to the area of the yellow triangle.
Because of the deadweight loss, this equilibrium is not efficient.
When there is a negative externality in producing a good or service, too much
of the good or service will be produced at market equilibrium.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
7 of 36
How a Positive Externality in Consumption Reduces Economic Efficiency
Figure 5.2
The Effect of a Positive Externality
on Economic Efficiency
People who do not consume
college educations can still
benefit from them.
As a result, the marginal social
benefit from a college education
is greater than the marginal
private benefit to college
students.
Because only the marginal
private benefit is represented in
the market demand curve D1, the
quantity of college educations
produced, QMarket, is too low.
If the market demand curve were D2 instead of D1, the level of college educations
produced would be QEfficient, which is the efficient level.
At the market equilibrium of QMarket, there is a deadweight loss equal to the area of the
yellow triangle.
When there is a positive externality in consuming a good or service, too little of
the good or service will be produced at market equilibrium.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
8 of 36
Externalities and Market Failure
Market failure A situation in which the market fails to produce the efficient
level of output.
What Causes Externalities?
Property rights The rights individuals or businesses have to the exclusive use
of their property, including the right to buy or sell it.
Externalities and market failures result from incomplete property rights or from
the difficulty of enforcing property rights in certain situations.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
9 of 36
Private Solutions to Externalities: The Coase Theorem
5.2 LEARNING OBJECTIVE
Discuss the Coase theorem and explain how private bargaining can lead to
economic efficiency in a market with an externality.
Ronald Coase of the University of Chicago, winner of the 1991 Nobel Prize in
Economics, argued that under some circumstances, private solutions to the
problem of externalities will occur.
To understand his argument, it is important to recognize that completely
eliminating an externality usually is not economically efficient.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
10 of 36
Making The Clean Air Act: How a Government Policy
the
Reduced Infant Mortality
Connection
The benefit of reducing air pollution in 1970 was much higher than the benefit from a
proportional reduction in air pollution would be today, when the level of pollution is
much lower.
In the two years following passage of the Clean Air Act, there was a sharp reduction in
air pollution and also a reduction in infant mortality.
MyEconLab Your Turn:
Test your understanding by doing related problem 2.8 at the end of this chapter.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
11 of 36
The Economically Efficient Level of Pollution Reduction
Figure 5.3
The Marginal Benefit from
Pollution Reduction Should
Equal the Marginal Cost
If the reduction of sulfur dioxide
emissions is at 7.0 million tons per
year, the marginal benefit of $250
per ton is greater than the
marginal cost of $175 per ton.
Further reductions in emissions will
increase the net benefit to society.
If the reduction of sulfur dioxide
emissions is at 10.0 million tons,
the marginal cost of $225 per ton
is greater than the marginal
benefit of $150 per ton.
An increase in sulfur dioxide
emissions will increase the net
benefit to society.
Only when the reduction is at 8.5 million tons is the marginal benefit equal to the marginal
cost.
This level is the economically efficient level of pollution reduction.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
12 of 36
The additional benefit—that is, the marginal benefit—received from eliminating
another ton of sulfur dioxide declines as its emissions are reduced.
The net benefit to society from reducing pollution is equal to the difference
between the benefit of reducing pollution and the cost.
To maximize the net benefit to society, pollution should be reduced up to the
point where the marginal benefit from another ton of reduction is equal to the
marginal cost.
The Basis for Private Solutions to Externalities
Coase emphasized that when more than the optimal level of pollution is
occurring, the benefits from reducing the pollution to the optimal level are
greater than the costs.
Don’t Let This Happen to You
Remember That It’s the Net Benefit That Counts
Maximizing the total benefit would be an inefficient goal with less than optimal results.
MyEconLab Your Turn:
Test your understanding by doing related problem 2.9 at the end of this chapter.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
13 of 36
Figure 5.4
The Benefits of Reducing Pollution to the
Optimal Level Are Greater than the Costs
Increasing the reduction in sulfur
dioxide emissions from 7.0 million
tons to 8.5 million tons results in total
benefits equal to the sum of the
areas A and B under the marginal
benefits curve.
The total cost of this decrease in
pollution is equal to the area B under
the marginal cost curve.
The total benefits are greater than
the total costs by an amount equal to
the area of triangle A.
Because the total benefits from
reducing pollution are greater than
the total costs, it’s possible for those
receiving the benefits to arrive at a
private agreement with polluters to
pay them to reduce pollution.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
14 of 36
Making The Fable of the Bees
the
Connection
British economist James Meade
argued that there were positive
externalities in both apple growing
and beekeeping.
He concluded that unless the
government intervened, the market
would not supply enough apple trees
and beehives.
Some apple growers and beekeepers
make private arrangements to arrive at
an economically efficient outcome.
Steven Cheung of the University of
Washington showed, however, that
government intervention was not necessary because beekeepers and apple
growers had long since arrived at private agreements.
In Washington State, farmers with fruit orchards had been renting beehives to
pollinate their trees since at least as early as 1917, and today honeybees
pollinate more than $14 billion worth of crops annually, from blueberries in Maine
all the way to almonds in California.
MyEconLab Your Turn:
Test your understanding by doing related problem 2.11 at the end of this chapter.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
15 of 36
Do Property Rights Matter?
In discussing the bargaining between the utilities and the people suffering the
effects of their pollution, the victims could not legally enforce the right of their
property not to be damaged.
Would it make any difference if the utilities were legally liable?
As Coase was the first to point out, the only difference would be that the utilities
would have an incentive to pay their victims for the right to pollute rather than
the victims having to pay the utilities to reduce pollution.
Either way, either side would pay to reduce pollution up to the point where the
marginal benefit of the last ton of reduction is equal to the marginal cost.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
16 of 36
The Problem of Transactions Costs
Transactions costs The costs in time and other resources that parties incur in
the process of agreeing to and carrying out an exchange of goods or services.
The Coase Theorem
Coase theorem The argument of economist Ronald Coase that if transactions
costs are low, private bargaining will result in an efficient solution to the
problem of externalities.
In general, private bargaining is most likely to reach an efficient outcome if the
number of parties bargaining is small.
In practice, private solutions to the problem of externalities will occur only if all
parties to the agreement have full information about the costs and benefits
associated with the externality and they are willing to accept a reasonable
agreement.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
17 of 36
Government Policies to Deal with Externalities
5.3 LEARNING OBJECTIVE
Analyze government policies to achieve economic efficiency in a market with
an externality.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
18 of 36
Figure 5.5
When There Is a Negative
Externality, a Tax Can Lead to the
Efficient Level of Output
Because utilities do not bear the
cost of acid rain, they produce
electricity beyond the economically
efficient level.
If the government imposes a tax
equal to the cost of acid rain, the
utilities will internalize the externality.
As a consequence, the supply curve
will shift up, from S1 to S2.
The market equilibrium quantity
changes from QMarket, where an
inefficiently high level of electricity is
produced, to QEfficient, the
economically efficient equilibrium
quantity.
The price of electricity will rise from PMarket—which does not include the cost of acid rain—
to PEfficient—which does include the cost.
Consumers pay the price PEfficient, while producers receive a price P, which is equal to
PEfficient minus the amount of the tax.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
19 of 36
Solved Problem 5.3
Using a Tax to Deal with a Negative Externality
Some toilet paper plants discharge bleach into rivers and lakes, causing substantial
environmental damage. Explain how the federal government can use a tax on toilet paper
to bring about the efficient level of production. What should the value of the tax be?
Solving the Problem
Step 1: Review the chapter
material.
Step 2: Use the information
from the graph to determine
the necessary tax.
The graph shows that at the
optimal level of production, the
difference between the
marginal private cost and the
marginal social cost is $50.
Therefore, a tax of $50 per ton
is required to shift the supply
curve up from S1 to S2.
MyEconLab Your Turn:
For more practice, do related problem 3.8 at the end of this chapter.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
20 of 36
Figure 5.6
When There Is a Positive
Externality, a Subsidy Can Bring
About the Efficient Level of Output
People who do not consume
college educations can benefit
from them.
As a result, the social benefit
from a college education is
greater than the private benefit
to college students.
If the government pays a
subsidy equal to the external
benefit, students will internalize
the externality.
The subsidy will cause the demand curve to shift up, from D1 to D2.
As a result, the market equilibrium quantity will shift from QMarket, where an inefficiently low
level of college educations is supplied, to QEfficient, the economically efficient equilibrium
quantity.
Producers receive the price PEfficient, while consumers pay a price P, which is equal to
PEfficient minus the amount of the subsidy.
Pigovian taxes and subsidies Government taxes and subsidies intended to
bring about an efficient level of output in the presence of externalities.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
21 of 36
Making
the
Connection
Should the Government Tax Cigarettes and Soda?
Governments impose “sin taxes” on certain products.
The effect of a tax on soda is shown in the figure.
MyEconLab Your Turn:
Test your understanding by doing related problem 3.9 at the end of this chapter.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
22 of 36
Command-and-Control versus Market-Based Approaches
Command-and-control approach An approach that involves the government
imposing quantitative limits on the amount of pollution firms are allowed to emit
or requiring firms to install specific pollution control devices.
Are Tradable Emissions Allowances Licenses to Pollute?
Some environmentalists have criticized tradable emissions allowances, arguing
that just as the government does not issue licenses to rob banks or to drive
drunk, it should not issue “licenses to pollute.”
But this criticism ignores one of the central lessons of economics: Resources
are scarce, and trade-offs exist.
Resources that are spent on reducing one type of pollution are not available to
reduce other types of pollution or for any other use.
Because reducing acid rain using tradable emissions allowances has cost
utilities $870 million rather than $7.4 billion as originally estimated, society has
saved more than $6.5 billion per year.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
23 of 36
Making
the
Can a Cap-and-Trade System Reduce Global Warming?
Connection
Although CO2 emissions rose slightly during the first few years of a cap-and-trade plan set up
in Europe in 2005, they should decline over time as the number of allowances is reduced.
MyEconLab Your Turn:
Test your understanding by doing related problem 3.14 at the end of this chapter.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
24 of 36
Four Categories of Goods
5.4 LEARNING OBJECTIVE
Explain how goods can be categorized on the basis of whether they are rival or
excludable and use graphs to illustrate the efficient quantities of public goods
and common resources.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
25 of 36
Rivalry The situation that occurs when one person’s consuming a unit of a
good means no one else can consume it.
Excludability The situation in which anyone who does not pay for a good
cannot consume it.
Figure 5.7
Four Categories of Goods
Goods and services can be
divided into four categories
on the basis of whether
people can be excluded from
consuming them and
whether they are rival in
consumption.
A good or service is rival in
consumption if one person
consuming a unit of a good
means that another person
cannot consume that unit.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
26 of 36
We next consider each of the four categories:
1. Private good. A good that is both rival and excludable.
2. Public good. A good that is both nonrival and nonexcludable.
Free riding Benefiting from a good without paying for it.
3. Quasi-public goods. Goods that are excludable but not rival.
4. Common resource. A good that is rival but not excludable.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
27 of 36
The Demand for a Public Good
Figure 5.8
Constructing the Market Demand Curve for a Private Good
The market demand curve for private goods is determined by adding horizontally the
quantity of the good demanded at each price by each consumer.
For instance, in panel (a), Jill demands 2 hamburgers when the price is $4.00, and in
panel (b), Joe demands 4 hamburgers when the price is $4.00.
So, a quantity of 6 hamburgers and a price of $4.00 is a point on the market demand
curve in panel (c).
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
28 of 36
Figure 5.9
Constructing the Demand Curve for a
Public Good
To find the demand curve for a public
good, we add up the price at which
each consumer is willing to purchase
each quantity of the good.
In panel (a), Jill is willing to pay $8 per
hour for a security guard to provide 10
hours of protection.
In panel (b), Joe is willing to pay $10
for that level of protection.
Therefore, in panel (c), the price of $18
per hour and the quantity of 10 hours
will be a point on the demand curve for
security guard services.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
29 of 36
Figure 5.10 The Optimal Quantity of a Public Good
The optimal quantity of
a public good is
produced where the
sum of consumer
surplus and producer
surplus is maximized,
which occurs where the
demand curve
intersects the supply
curve.
In this case, the optimal
quantity of security
guard services is 15
hours, at a price of $9
per hour.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
30 of 36
Solved Problem 5.4
Determining the Optimal Level of Public Goods
Jill and Joe are in need of security guard services. Their demand schedules are as follows:
Jill
Joe
Price
(dollars per hour)
Quantity (hours
of protection)
$20
18
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
The supply schedule is as follows:
a. Draw a graph that shows the optimal level
of security guard services.
Be sure to label the curves on the graph.
b. Briefly explain why 8 hours of security
guard protection is not an optimal quantity.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
Price
(dollars per hour)
Quantity (hours
of protection)
$20
18
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Price
(dollars per hour)
Quantity (hours
of protection)
$8
10
12
14
16
18
20
22
24
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
31 of 36
Solved Problem 5.4
Determining the Optimal Level of Public Goods
Solving the Problem
Step 1: Review the chapter material.
Step 2: Begin by deriving the demand curve or
marginal social benefit curve for security guard
services.
To calculate the marginal social benefit of guard
services, we need to add the prices that Jill and
Joe are willing to pay at each quantity:
Step 3: Answer part (a) by plotting the demand
(marginal social benefit) and supply (marginal
social cost) curves.
Demand or Marginal Social Benefit
Price
(dollars per hour)
$38
34
30
26
22
18
14
10
6
Quantity (hours
of protection)
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
Step 4: Answer part (b) by explaining why 8
hours of security guard protection is not an
optimal quantity.
For each hour beyond 6, the supply curve is above
the demand curve, so the marginal social benefit
received will be less than the marginal social cost
of supplying these hours, resulting in a deadweight
loss and a reduction in economic surplus.
MyEconLab Your Turn:
For more practice, do related problem 4.4 at the end of this chapter.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
32 of 36
Common Resources
Tragedy of the commons The tendency for a common resource to be
overused.
Figure 5.11
Overuse of a Common
Resource
For a common resource such
as wood from a forest, the
efficient level of use, QEfficient,
is determined by the
intersection of the demand
curve—which represents the
marginal benefit received by
consumers—and S2, which
represents the marginal social
cost of cutting the wood.
Because each individual tree cutter ignores the external cost, the equilibrium quantity of
wood cut is QActual, which is greater than the efficient quantity.
At the equilibrium level of output, there is a deadweight loss, as shown by the yellow
triangle.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
33 of 36
Is There a Way Out of the Tragedy of the Commons?
The source of the tragedy of the commons is the same as the source of
negative externalities: lack of clearly defined and enforced property rights.
When enforcing property rights is not feasible, though, two types of solutions to
the tragedy of the commons are possible:
1. If the geographic area involved is limited and the number of people involved
is small, access to the commons can be restricted through community norms
and laws.
2. If the geographic area or the number of people involved is large, legal
restrictions through taxes, quotas, and tradable permits on access to the
commons are required.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
34 of 36
Economics in Your Life
What’s the “Best” Level of Pollution?
At the beginning of the chapter, we asked you to think about what the “best”
level of carbon emissions is. Conceptually, this is a straightforward question to
answer:
The efficient level of carbon emissions is the level for which the marginal
benefit of reducing carbon emissions exactly equals the marginal cost of
reducing carbon emissions.
In practice, however, this is a very difficult question to answer. Scientists
disagree about how much carbon emissions are contributing to climate change
and what the damage from climate change will be.
In addition, the cost of reducing carbon emissions depends on the method of
reduction used. As a result, neither the marginal cost curve nor the marginal
benefit curve for reducing carbon emissions is known with certainty, which
makes it difficult for policymakers to determine the economically efficient level
of carbon emissions and is the source of much of the current debate.
In any case, economists agree that the total cost of completely eliminating
carbon emissions is much greater than the total benefit.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
35 of 36
AN
INSIDE
LOOK
AT POLICY
Pros and Cons of Tougher Air Pollution Regulations
With the implementation of new pollution regulations, producers would bear more of the
external cost of pollution.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
36 of 36