Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 1 Introduction • Most firms sell more than one product • Products are differentiated in different ways – horizontally • goods of similar quality targeted at consumers of different types – how is variety determined? – is there too much variety – vertically • consumers agree on quality • differ on willingness to pay for quality – how is quality of goods being offered determined? Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 2 Horizontal product differentiation • Suppose that consumers differ in their tastes – firm has to decide how best to serve different types of consumer – offer products with different characteristics but similar qualities • This is horizontal product differentiation – firm designs products that appeal to different types of consumer – products are of (roughly) similar quality • Questions: – how many products? – of what type? – how do we model this problem? Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 3 A spatial approach to product variety • The spatial model (Hotelling) is useful to consider – pricing – design – variety • Has a much richer application as a model of product differentiation – “location” can be thought of in • space (geography) • time (departure times of planes, buses, trains) • product characteristics (design and variety) – consumers prefer products that are “close” to their preferred types in space, or time or characteristics Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 4 An geographic example of product variety McDonald’s Burger King Wendy’s Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 5 A Spatial approach to product variety 2 • Assume N consumers living equally spaced along Main Street – 1 mile long. • Monopolist must decide how best to supply these consumers • Consumers buy exactly one unit provided that price plus transport costs is less than V. • Consumers incur there-and-back transport costs of t per mile • The monopolist operates one shop – reasonable to expect that this is located at the center of Main Street Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 6 Suppose that the monopolist The spatial model Price sets a price ofPrice p1 p1 + tx p1 + t.x V V All consumers within distance x1 to the left and right of the shop will by the product z=0 t t p1 x1 1/2 What determines x1? x1 z=1 Shop 1 p1 + tx1 = V, so x1 = (V – p1)/t Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 7 The spatial model Price p1 + t.x Suppose the firm 2reduces the price Price p1 +tot.xp2? V V Then all consumers within distance x2 of the shop will buy from the firm z=0 p1 p2 x2 x1 1/2 x1 x2 z=1 Shop 1 Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 8 The spatial model 3 • Suppose that all consumers are to be served at price p. – The highest price is that charged to the consumers at the ends of the market – Their transport costs are t/2 : since they travel ½ mile to the shop – So they pay p + t/2 which must be no greater than V. – So p = V – t/2. • Suppose that marginal costs are c per unit. • Suppose also that a shop has set-up costs of F. • Then profit is p(N, 1) = N(V – t/2 – c) – F. Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 9 Monopoly pricing in the spatial model • What if there are two shops? • The monopolist will coordinate prices at the two shops • With identical costs and symmetric locations, these prices will be equal: p1 = p2 = p – Where should they be located? – What is the optimal price p*? Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 10 Location with two shops Delivered price to Suppose that the entire market is Price If there are two shops they will be located V symmetrically a distance d from the The maximumofprice end-points the p(d) the firmmarket can charge is determined Now raisebythethe price consumers at the at each shop Start with a low center of the marketprice at each shop Suppose that d < 1/4 z=0 consumers at the tomarket be served center equals their reservation price Price V p(d) What determines p(d)? d Shop 1 1/2 1-d Shop 2 z=1 The shops should be moved inwards Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 11 Delivered price to consumers at the end-points equals their reservation price Location with two shops 2 The maximum price the firm can charge is now determined by the consumers at the end-points of the market Price Price V V p(d) p(d) Now raise the price at each shop Start with a low price at each shop Now suppose that d > 1/4 Now what determines p(d)? z=0 d Shop 1 1/2 1-d Shop 2 z=1 The shops should be moved outwards Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 12 It follows that Location shop 1 should be located at Price 1/4 and shop 2 at 3/4 with two shops 3 Price at each shop is then p* = V - t/4 Price V V V - t/4 V - t/4 Profit at each shop is given by the shaded area c c z=0 1/4 Shop 1 1/2 3/4 Shop 2 z=1 Profit is now p(N, 2) = N(V - t/4 - c) – 2F Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 13 Three shops What if there are three shops? By the same argument they should be located at 1/6, 1/2 and 5/6 Price Price V Price at each shop is now V - t/6 V V - t/6 z=0 V - t/6 1/6 Shop 1 1/2 Shop 2 5/6 z=1 Shop 3 Profit is now p(N, 3) = N(V - t/6 - c) – 3F Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 14 Optimal number of shops • A consistent pattern is emerging. • Assume that there are n shops. • They will be symmetrically located distance 1/n apart. • We have already considered n = 2 and n = 3. How many shops should • When n = 2 we have p(N, 2) = V - t/4 there be? • When n = 3 we have p(N, 3) = V - t/6 • It follows that p(N, n) = V - t/2n • Aggregate profit is then p(N, n) = N(V - t/2n - c) – nF Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 15 Optimal number of shops 2 Profit from n shops is p(N, n) = (V - t/2n - c)N - nF and the profit from having n + 1 shops is: p*(N, n+1) = (V - t/2(n + 1)-c)N - (n + 1)F Adding the (n +1)th shop is profitable if p(N,n+1) - p(N,n) > 0 This requires tN/2n - tN/2(n + 1) > F which requires that n(n + 1) < tN/2F. Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 16 An example Suppose that F = $50,000 , N = 5 million and t = $1 Then tN/2F = 50 For an additional shop to be profitable we need n(n + 1) < 50. This is true for n < 6 There should be no more than seven shops in this case: if n = 6 then adding one more shop is profitable. But if n = 7 then adding another shop is unprofitable. Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 17 Some intuition • What does the condition on n tell us? • Simply, we should expect to find greater product variety when: – there are many consumers. – set-up costs of increasing product variety are low. – consumers have strong preferences over product characteristics and differ in these • consumers are unwilling to buy a product if it is not “very close” to their most preferred product Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 18 How much of the market to supply • Should the whole market be served? – Suppose not. Then each shop has a local monopoly – Each shop sells to consumers within distance r – How is r determined? • • • • • • • it must be that p + tr = V so r = (V – p)/t so total demand is 2N(V – p)/t profit to each shop is then p = 2N(p – c)(V – p)/t – F differentiate with respect to p and set to zero: dp/dp = 2N(V – 2p + c)/t = 0 So the optimal price at each shop is p* = (V + c)/2 If all consumers are served price is p(N,n) = V – t/2n – Only part of the market should be served if p(N,n)< p* – This implies that V < c + t/n. Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 19 Partial market supply • If c + t/n > V supply only part of the market and set price p* = (V + c)/2 • If c + t/n < V supply the whole market and set price p(N,n) = V – t/2n • Supply only part of the market: – if the consumer reservation price is low relative to marginal production costs and transport costs – if there are very few outlets Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 20 Are there too Social optimum many shops or What number of shops maximizes total surplus? too few? Total surplus is consumer surplus plus profit Consumer surplus is total willingness to pay minus total revenue Profit is total revenue minus total cost Total surplus is then total willingness to pay minus total costs Total willingness to pay by consumers is N.V Total surplus is therefore NV - Total Cost So what is Total Cost? Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 21 Assume that there are n shops Social optimum 2 Price Price Transport cost for each shop is the area V of these two triangles multiplied by consumer density V Consider shop i Total cost is total transport cost plus set-up costs t/2n z=0 t/2n 1/2n 1/2n z=1 Shop i This area is t/4n2 Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 22 Social optimum 3 Total cost with n shops is, therefore: C(N,n) = n(t/4n2)N + nF If = t =tN/4n $1, F+=nF $50,000, 5 million then this Total cost with n + 1 shops is: C(N,n+1)N==tN/4(n+1)+ (n+1)F condition tells There should beusfive shops: Adding another shop is socially efficient if that C(N,n + 1) << C(N,n) n(n+1) 25 another with n = 4 adding This requires that tN/4n - tN/4(n+1) > F shop is efficient which implies that n(n + 1) < tN/4F The monopolist operates too many shops and, more generally, provides too much product variety Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 23 Product variety and price discrimination • Suppose that the monopolist delivers the product. – then it is possible to price discriminate • What pricing policy to adopt? – – – – charge every consumer his reservation price V the firm pays the transport costs this is uniform delivered pricing it is discriminatory because price does not reflect costs Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 24 Product variety and price discrimination • Suppose that the monopolist delivers the product. – then it is possible to price discriminate • What pricing policy to adopt? – – – – charge every consumer his reservation price V the firm pays the transport costs this is uniform delivered pricing it is discriminatory because price does not reflect costs Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 25 Product variety and price discrimination 2 • Should every consumer be supplied? – suppose that there are n shops evenly spaced on Main Street – cost to the most distant consumer is c + t/2n – supply this consumer so long as V (revenue) > c + t/2n • This is a weaker condition than without price discrimination. • Price discrimination allows more consumers to be served. Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 26 Product variety & price discrimination 3 • How many shops should the monopolist operate now? —Suppose that the monopolist has n shops and is supplying the entire market. —Total revenue minus production costs is NV – Nc —Total transport costs plus set-up costs is C(N, n)=tN/4n + nF —So profit is p(N,n) = NV – Nc – C(N,n) —But then maximizing profit means minimizing C(N, n) —The discriminating monopolist operates the socially optimal number of shops. Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 27 Monopoly and product quality • Firms can, and do, produce goods of different qualities • Quality then is an important strategic variable • The choice of product quality determined by its ability to generate profit; attitude of consumers to q uality • Consider a monopolist producing a single good – what quality should it have? – determined by consumer attitudes to quality • • • • prefer high to low quality willing to pay more for high quality but this requires that the consumer recognizes quality also some are willing to pay more than others for quality Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 28 Demand and quality • We might think of individual demand as being of the form – Qi = 1 if Pi < Ri(Z) and = 0 otherwise for each consumer i – Each consumer buys exactly one unit so long as price is less than her reservation price – the reservation price is affected by product quality Z • Assume that consumers vary in their reservation prices • Then aggregate demand is of the form P = P(Q, Z) • An increase in product quality increases demand Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 29 Demand and quality 2 Begin with a particular demand curve for a good of quality Z1 Price Then an increase in product R1(Z2) Suppose that an from increase quality Z1 toinZ2 rotates P(Q, Z2) quality the increases demandthe curve around If the price is P1willingness and the product quality to pay of the quantity axis as follows is Z then all consumers with reservation 1 inframarginal consumers more P2 prices greater than than P the good 1 will that of buy the marginal R1(Z1) Quantity Q1 can now be consumer This is the These are the P1 sold for the higher marginal inframarginal price P2 consumer consumers P(Q, Z1) Q1 Quantity Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 30 Demand and quality 3 Price R1(Z1) P2 P1 P(Q, Z1) Q1 Suppose instead that an Then anin increase in product increase fromthe Z1 to Z2 rotates qualityquality increases thepay demand curve around willingness to of marginal the price axis as follows consumers more than that of the inframarginal consumers Once again quantity Q1 can now be sold for a higher price P2 P(Q, Z2) Quantity Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 31 Demand and quality 4 • The monopolist must choose both – price (or quantity) – quality • Two profit-maximizing rules – marginal revenue equals marginal cost on the last unit sold for a given quality – marginal revenue from increased quality equals marginal cost of increased quality for a given quantity • This can be illustrated with a simple example: P = Z( - Q) where Z is an index of quality Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 32 Demand and quality 5 P = Z( - Q) Assume that marginal cost of output is zero: MC(Q) = 0 Cost of quality is C(Z) = aZ2 Marginal cost of quality = dC(Z)/d(Z) = 2aZ The firm’s profit is: This means that quality costly and becomes increasingly costly p(Q, Z) =PQ - C(Z) = Z( - Q)Q - aZ2 Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 33 Demand and quality 6 Again, profit is: p(Q, Z) =PQ - C(Z) = Z( - Q)Q - aZ2 The firm chooses Q and Z to maximize profit. Take the choice of quantity first: this is easiest. Marginal revenue = MR = Z - 2ZQ MR = MC Z - 2ZQ = 0 Q* = /2 P* = Z/2 Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 34 Demand and quality 7 Total revenue = P*Q* = (Z/2)x(/2) = Z2/4 So marginal revenue from increased quality is MR(Z) = 2/4 Marginal cost of quality is MC(Z) = 2aZ Equating MR(Z) = MC(Z) then gives Z* = 2/8a Does the monopolist produce too high or too low quality? Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 35 Demand and quality: multiple products • What if the firm chooses to offer more than one product? – what qualities should be offered? – how should they be priced? • Determined by costs and consumer demand Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 36 Demand and quality: multiple products 2 • An example: – two types of consumer – each buys exactly one unit provided that consumer surplus is nonnegative – if there is a choice, buy the product offering the larger consumer surplus – types of consumer distinguished by willingness to pay for quality • This is vertical product differentiation Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 37 Vertical differentiation • Indirect utility to a consumer of type i from consuming a product of quality z at price p is Vi = i(z – zi) – p – where i measures willingness to pay for quality; – zi is the lower bound on quality below which consumer type i will not buy – assume 1 > 2: type 1 consumers value quality more than type 2 – assume z1 > z2 = 0: type 1 consumers only buy if quality is greater than z1: • never fly in coach • never shop in Wal-Mart • only eat in “good” restaurants – type 2 consumers will buy any quality so long as consumer surplus is nonnegative Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 38 Vertical differentiation 2 • Firm cannot distinguish consumer types • Must implement a strategy that causes consumers to selfselect – persuade type 1 consumers to buy a high quality product z1 at a high price – and type 2 consumers to buy a low quality product z2 at a lower price, which equals their maximum willingness to pay • Firm can produce any product in the range z, z • MC = 0 for either quality type Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 39 Vertical differentiation 3 Suppose that the firm offers two products with qualities z1 > z2 For type 2 consumers charge maximum willingness to pay for the low quality product: p2 = 2z2 Type 1 consumers prefer the high quality Now consider type 1Type consumers: firm have faces an incentive 1 consumers to the low quality good compatibility constraint nonnegative consumer high 1(z1 – z1) – p1 >surplus 1(z2 – from z1) – pthe 2 quality good 1(z1 – z1) – p1 > 0 These imply that p1 < 1z1 – (1 2)z2 There is an upper limit on the price that can be charged for the high quality good Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 40 Vertical differentiation 4 • Take the equation p1 = 1z1 – (1 – 2)z2 – – – – this is increasing in quality valuations increasing in the difference between z1 and z2 quality can be prices highly when it is valued highly firm has an incentive to differentiate the two products’ qualities to soften competition between them • monopolist is competing with itself • What about quality choice? – prices p1 = 1z1 – (1 – 2)z2; p2 = 2z2 • check the incentive compatibility constraints – suppose that there are N1 type 1 and N2 type 2 consumers Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 41 Vertical differentiation 5 Profit is P = N1p1 + N2p2 = N11z1 – (N11 – (N1 + N2)2)z2 This is increasing in z1 so set z1 as high as possible: z1 = z For z2 the decision is more complex (N11 – (N1 + N2)2) may be positive or negative Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 42 Vertical differentiation 6 Case 1: Suppose that (N11 – (N1 + N2)2) is positive Then z2 should be set “low” but this is subject to a constraint Recall that p1 = 1z1 – (1 - 2)z2 So reducing z2 increases p1 But we also require that 1(z1 – z1) – p1 > 0 Putting these together gives: The equilibrium prices are then: z2 = 1 z 1 1 2 2 1 z 1 p2 = 1 2 ( p1 = 1 z z 1 Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 43 Vertical differentiation 7 • Offer type 1 consumers the highest possible quality and charge their full willingness to pay • Offer type 2 consumers as low a quality as is consistent with incentive compatibility constraints • Charge type 2 consumers their maximum willingness to pay for this quality – maximum differentiation subject to incentive compatibility constraints Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 44 Vertical differentiation 8 Case 1: Now suppose that (N11 – (N1 + N2)2) is negative Then z2 should be set as high as possible The firm should supply only one product, of the highest possible quality What does this require? From the inequality offer only one product if: Offer only one product: N1 2 1 N1 N 2 1 if there are not “many” type 1 consumers if the difference in willingness to pay for quality is “small” Should the firm price to sell to both types in this case? YES! Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 45 Empirical Application: Price Discrimination and Imperfect Competition Although we have presented price discrimination and product design (versioning) issues in the context of a monopoly, these same tactics also play a role in more competitive settings of imperfect competition Imagine a two-store setting again Assume N customers distributed evenly between the two stores, each with maximum willingness to pay of V . No transport cost—Half of the consumers always buys at nearest store. Other half always buys at cheapest store. Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 46 Price Discrimination and Imperfect Competition 2 If both stores operated by a monopolist, set price = V. Cannot set it higher of there will be no customers. Setting it lower though gains nothing. What if stores operated by separate firms? Imagine P1 = P2 = V. Store 1 serves N/4 pricesensitive customers and N/4 price-insensitive ones. The same is true for Store 2. If Store 1 cuts its price below V. It loses N/2 from all current customers It gains N(V - )/4 by stealing all pricesensitive customers from Store 2 Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 47 Price Discrimination and Imperfect Competition 3 MORAL 1: Both firms have a real incentive to cut price. This ultimately proves self-defeating In equilibrium, both still serve N/2 customers but now do so at a price closer to cost. This is especially frustrating in light of the “brandloyal” or price-insensitive customers Cutting their price does not increase their likelihood of shopping at a particular place. It just loses revenue. MORAL 2: Unlike the monopolist who sets the same price to everyone, these firms have an incentive to discriminate and so continue to charge a high price to loyal consumers while pricing low to others. Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 48 Price Discrimination and Imperfect Competition 4 The intuition then is that price discrimination may be associated with imperfect competition and become more prominent as markets get more competitive (but still less than perfectly competitive). This idea is tested by Stavins (2001) with airline prices. Restrictions such as a required Saturday night stay-over or an advanced purchase serve as screening mechanism for price-sensitive customers. Hence, restrictions lead to lower ticket price. Stavins (2001) idea is that price reduction associated with flight restrictions will be small in markets that are not very competitive. Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 49 Price Discrimination and Imperfect Competition 6 Stavins (2001) looks at nearly 6,000 tickets covering 12 different city-pair routes in September, 1995. She finds strong support for the dual hypothesis that: a) passengers flying on a ticket with restrictions pay less; b) price reduction shrinks as concentration rises In highly competitive (low HHI) markets, a Saturday night restriction leads to a $253 price reduction but only a $165 reduction in less competitive ones. In highly competitive (low HHI) markets, an Advance Purchase restriction leads to a $111 price reduction but only a $41 reduction in less competitive ones. Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 50 Price Discrimination and Imperfect Competition 5 Variable Saturday Night Stay Required Coefficient – 0.408 t-Statistic Coefficient – 4.05 ----- t-Statistic ----- Saturday Night Stay 0.792 3.39 --------RequiredxHHI Advance Purchase --------– 0.023 –5.53 Required Advance Purchase --------0.098 8.38 RequiredxHHI NOTE: HHI is the Herfindahl Index. A Saturday Night Stay or an Advance Purchase lowers the price significantly. But the HHI terms show that this effect weakens as market concentration increases. Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 51 Demand and quality A1 Price Z2 P(Q, Z2) When quality is Z2 price is 2/2 Howisdoes WhenZquality Z1 increased quality price is affect demand? Z1/2 MR(Z2) Z1 P2 = Z2/2 P1 = Z1/2 MR(Z1) P(Q,Z1) /2 Q* Quantity Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 52 Demand and quality A2 Price Z2 Z1 P2 = Z2/2 P1 = Z1/2 So an increase is quality from Z1 to Z surplus 2 increases Social surplus at quality Z2 area minus the is by thisthis area minus quality increase in quality costs costs An increase in quality from The increase in total Z1 to Z2 increases surplus revenue by this area Zis greater than Social surplus at quality 1 the increase in profit. is this area minus quality The monopolist produces costs too little quality /2 Q* Quantity Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 53 Demand and quality Derivation of aggregate demand Order consumers by their reservation prices Aggregate individual demand horizontally Price 1 2 3 4 5 6 78 Quantity Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 54 Location choice 1 d < 1/4 We know that p(d) satisfies the following constraint: p(d) + t(1/2 - d) = V This gives: p(d) = V - t/2 + td p(d) = V - t/2 + td Aggregate profit is then: p(d) = (p(d) - c)N = (V - t/2 + td - c)N This is increasing in d so if d < 1/4 then d should be increased. Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 55 Location choice 2 d > 1/4 We now know that p(d) satisfies the following constraint: p(d) + td = V This gives: p(d) = V - td Aggregate profit is then: p(d) = (p(d) - c)N = (V - td - c)N This is decreasing in d so if d > 1/4 then d should be decreased. Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 56