* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Optimal Pricing and Return Policies for Perishable Commodities
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Optimal Pricing and Return Policies for Perishable Commodities B. A. Pasternack Presenter: Gökhan METAN Pasternack 1 Outline i) Introduction ii) Model iii) Implications iv) Examples v) Conclusion Pasternack 2 Introduction What the paper is all about? Pricing policies for a manufacturer that produceses goods with short shelf or demand life. Pricing Policy: Specifies the price of the commodity charged from the retailers, per unit credit for the returned goods, and the percentage of purchased goods allowed to be returned for this credit. Pasternack 3 Introduction Question: How would you set the price of the product for your retailers, and what return policy would you impose? How and what kind of decisions are made typically? Price: Return Policy: i- Cost basis decisions i- Full credit for all unsold goods. ii- “What market will bear” approach ii- No credit for unsold goods. No channel coordination! Pasternack 4 Introduction Set a pricing policy Profit Purchase Decision Customer Side Profit Price, demand, product availability Pasternack 5 Introduction Assumptions about the model: i- Single item is considered. ii- Item has short shelf or demand life. iii- Any retailer place only one order from the manufacturer. iv- Goodwill cost is incurred partially by the retailer and partially by the manufacturer. (when inventory is depleated) v- Certain amount may be returned to the manufacturer for partial credit and the remaining is disposed of by the retailer for its salvage value. (when inventory remains beyond the shelf/demand life) Pasternack 6 Introduction Assumptions about the model: Cont’d vi- Manufacturing cost per item is independent of the production quantity. vii- All the retailers charge the same (fix) price for the product. viii- Both the manufacturer and the retailers are profit maximizers. ix- Salvage value is same for manufacturer and the retailers. x- No transfer mark-ups between retailers and the manufacturer. (amount paid by the retailer = amount received by the manufacturer) Pasternack 7 Introduction Assumptions about the model: Cont’d xi- Demand at the retail level is stochastic. xii- Manufacturer has control of the channel and is free to set the pricing policy. Retailers decide to carry the commodity or not. Objective: To develop a pricing policy that optimizes the expected profit of both the manufacturer and the retailers as well as to achieve the channel coordination. Pasternack 8 Introduction Methodology: Single period inventory model (newsboy problem) is employed in the analyses. Interest: Not finding the optimal ordering quantity! What pricing policy for the manufacturer will be optimal ? Pasternack 9 Model Pasternack 10 Model Manufacturing cost per item Unit selling price by the retailer Salvage value per unit Manufacturing cost per item Unit price paid by the retailer to the manufacturer. Pasternack 11 Model In the analyses we will consider two cases: 1) We will first assume such a system that the retailers belong to manufacturers own. That is, they are company stores. 2) In the second case, we will consider indedendent retailers. That is, the retailers determine their order quantity. This will enable us to determine the optimal policy for the system as a whole. This will enable us to determine the optimal policy for retailers where they are independent. Pasternack 12 Model 1st CASE Let the company produces Q units and sells directly to the customers by its own retailers and EPT(Q) be the total expected profit. Total manufacturing cost Total Profit Total Profit Expected profit when demand is less than the production quantity. Total Salvage Value for unsold goods Pasternack Total goodwill cost for lost demands Expected profit when demand is more than the production quantity. 13 Model Result F(QT*)=(p+g2-c)/(p+g2-c3) Pasternack 14 Model 2nd CASE Let the retailer orders Q units and EPR(Q) be the retailer’s expected profit. Retailer’s total ordering cost Pasternack 15 Model Q ORDER DEMAND 0 x RQ (1-R)Q Retailer’s revenue from items sold Credit obtained for unsold goods from the manufacturer Total amount obtained for unsold goods from their salvage value Pasternack 16 Model x Q ORDER DEMAND 0 RQ (1-R)Q Retailer’s revenue from items sold Credit obtained for unsold goods from the manufacturer Pasternack 17 Model Q ORDER x DEMAND 0 RQ (1-R)Q Total goodwill cost of the retailer. Retailer’s revenue from items sold Pasternack 18 Model Note that: 0 0 Q* is the order quantity of independent retailer which satisfies equation (7). Pasternack 19 Model Now, the retailer orders Q* units and EPM(Q*) be the manufacturer’s expected profit. Profit obtained by the sales of Q* units to the retailer Pasternack 20 Model Q* ORDER DEMAND 0 x RQ* (1-R)Q* Total Credit paid for returned unsold goods minus the total salvage value obtained from these items by the manufacturer Pasternack 21 Model x Q* ORDER DEMAND 0 RQ* (1-R)Q* Total Credit paid for returned unsold goods minus the total salvage value obtained from these items by the manufacturer Pasternack 22 Model Q* ORDER x DEMAND 0 RQ* (1-R)Q* Total goodwill cost of the manufacturer (because of lost demand) Pasternack 23 Model Now what we have on hand? From Case-1 Analysis: We know that the manufacturer wants to maximize the total channel profit and hence wants: QT* such that it satisfies F(QT*)=(p+g2-c)/(p+g2-c3) From Case-2 Analysis: We know that the independent retailer wants to maximize its own profit and hence wants: Q* such that it satisfies: Pasternack 24 Model Hence set: Q*=QT* such that it satisfies F(Q*)=F(QT*)=(p+g2-c)/(p+g2-c3) Pasternack 25 Results: If the manufacturer sets these three parameters in such a way that the previous equation is satisfied, the independent retailer should order the same quantity from the manufacturer as would the manufacturer if operating a company store. This results in maximum total profits to the retailer and manufacturer, and the channel is said to be coordinated. Model The manufacturer has the control over the parameters c 1 Observations: (cost of per unit order from the manufacturer), c2 (credit per As unique solution to the equation, different unit there paid isbynothe manufacturer to previous the retailer for returned values for these there decision variables result in different divisions of goods) and R (percentage of the order quantity, Q, that can expected profit between the manufacturer and the retailer. be returned to the manufacturer for a credit of c2 per item). Therefore, the manufacturer’s pricing and return policy will function as a risk sharing agreement between manufacturer and retailer. Pasternack 26 Implications Theorem 1. The policy of a manufacturer allowing unlimited returns for full credit is system suboptimal. Pasternack 27 Implications Theorem 2. The policy of a manufacturer allowing no returns is system suboptimal. Theorems 1 & 2 imply that “unlimited returns for full credit” as well as “no returns” prevents channel coordination. Theorem 3. A policy which allows for unlimited returns (R=1) at partial credit (c2 <c1) will be system optimal for appropriately chosen values of c1 and c2. Pasternack 28 Implications If c1 and c2 are so chosen and the manufacturer allows for unlimited returns, then the total expected profit for the retailer and manufacturer are as follows: Pasternack 29 Implications If the demand for the commodity follows a normal distribution (x ~ N(μ, σ)) then the previous equations become: OBSERVATIONS: c1 chosen at its low end (c1 = c + ε) Manufacturer makes NO PROFIT c1 chosen at its high end (c1 =p – ε) Retailer makes NO PROFIT Pasternack 30 Implications As c2 ↑ c1 also ↑ Pasternack 31 Results & Suggestions: Implications The pricing should be set so that the average retail establishment captures at least some portion of the gain from channel coordination. R E A S O N If it can be demonstrated to the retailers that their profits will improve as a result of price changes, then they should be more willing to accept the new pricing plan. Increasing the retailers’ profits should result in additional distribution outlets being opened, resulting in an increase in overall demand. Pasternack 32 Results & Suggestions: Implications A drawback!!! Multi-retailer Environment Manufacturer sets a single (uniform) pricing policy for all retailers Impacts on retailer profitability will be different An easy but not feasible solution: A different and retailer-specific pricing policy can be A policy total profit determined and set forthat eachincreases retailer retailers’ and this achieves the does not goal. guarantee to itincrease all individual retailer’s manufacturer’s In fact is not defendable under the profit. Act Some(which may faced a decrease in their Robinson-Patman is an with act about the competition expectedinprofit dueenvironment). to the channel coordinated and pricing actions business pricing policy. Pasternack 33 Results & Suggestions: Implications Another issue Goodwill Costs Hard to Quantify Vary among different retailers A uniform pricing policy for those retailer can not be set Fortunately, analyses show that when R=0 the retailers’ order quantity is insensitive to small changes in goodwill cost. Ensure reasonable rate of return $$$$$$ A pricing policy for a new product! Pasternack Desirable enough $$$ 34 Examples Consider a product with: Net retail price of $8.00 Manufacturing cost of $3.00 Salvage value of $1.00 Retailer goodwill cost is $3.00 Manufacturer goodwill cost is $2.00 Total goodwill cost is $5.00 (p=8). (c=3) (c3=1) (g=3) (g1=2) (g2=g+g1=5) Suppose that manufacturer charges $4.00 (c1=4) per item from the retailer and not permit returns for unsold goods (R=0). g=3, g1=2, g2=5, p=8, c=3 , c1=4, c3=1, R=0 Pasternack 35 Examples g=3, g1=2, g2=5, p=8, c=3 , c1=4, c3=1, R=0 Assume a retailer: Demand ~ N(200, 50) and the retailer is a profit maximizer. Q*=226 EPR(Q*)=$626.25 EPM(Q*)=$206.85 (1) From Theorem-2, this cannot be optimal! Manufacturer decides to allow unlimited returns to achieve channel coordination. Set R=1. Pasternack 36 Examples g=3, g1=2, g2=5, p=8, c=3 , c1=4, c3=1, R=1 From F(QT*)=(p+g2-c)/(p+g2-c3) c1=$4.28 Q*=249 c2=$2.936 EPR(Q*)=$643.51 EPM(Q*)=$206.95 (2) If all the gain is given to the retailer Q*=249 c1=$4.37 c2=$3.044 EPR(Q*)=$626.86 EPM(Q*)=$223.61 (3) If all the gain is given to the manufacturer Pasternack 37 Examples c1=$4.32 c2=$2.984 EPR(Q*)=$636.11 EPM(Q*)=$214.35 (4) Both Manuf. & Retailer benefit from the strategy Now suppose this is the selected policy... Pasternack 38 Examples Consider a second retailer: Demand ~ N(200, 10) and the retailer is a profit maximizer. Before channel coordination (c1=4, R=0) Q*=205 EPR(Q*)=$765.25 EPM(Q*)=$201.05 (5) After channel coordination (c1=4.32, R=1, c2=2.984) Q*=210 EPR(Q*)=$716.02 Pasternack EPM(Q*)=$254.07 (6) 39 Conclusion It is possible for a manufacturer to set a pricing and return policy which will ensure channel coordination. For partial return case, the optimal values for the selling price to the retailer and the return credit offered on the item will both be functions of the individual retailer’s demand. Since retailers have different demand distributions fixed price/return policies which allow for partial returns cannot be optimal. Pasternack 40 Conclusion Policy: Unlimited returns for partial credit Optimal values for selling price to the retailer and credit offered to the retailer can be determined independent of the retailer’s demand distribution. A range of optimal values for selling price and return credits exist. Choosing different pairs result in different divisions of the profit. As a result of channel coordination some retailers may face with a decrease in their expected profits. Since any manufacturer normally have a number of retailers, it is clear that the policy with full returns for partial credits is the suitable one for short-lived commodities Pasternack 41 THE END Pasternack 42