Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
National Health Accounts Joseph P. Newhouse Harvard University Main Points Should account for non-market inputs, especially time Comparisons of spending across time and space can yield useful inferences Decomposing change in medical spending into price and quantity requires measurement of output by episode A Caveat My experience is with the US accounts, and my examples reflect a developed country bias But I think the conclusions apply generally Non-Market Transactions The accounts measure goods and services traded in the market True of both health accounts and national income and product accounts (NIPA) Latter often used to measure changes in well being Well Being and Non-Market Transactions Time is an important input into health care, but time has an opportunity cost that is not captured in the accounts Time as a Complement Time is sometimes a complement to market inputs Own time spent traveling to and receiving care Time of family members assisting others – Mother taking child to physician Time spent recovering from illness (“Take 2 aspirin and go to bed”) Time Making Production of Health More Efficient This is a role usually assigned to education But people spend time trying to get more health out of a given set of market inputs For example, time spent talking with others about providers of care or otherwise seeking information Time spent gathering information on health effects of lifestyles; health sections in the press Time as a Substitute for Market Inputs Informal care of frail elderly Health promotion; wellness (e.g., exercise) Difficult boundary lines here (e.g., sleep) Measuring Time Used in Production of Health Suppose one wanted to add time to a satellite account; this would require separate time use survey Issues of valuation; persons not working Issues of boundaries Joint production Exercise might have other benefits Conclusion on Time The accounts understate by an unknown, but probably non-trivial amount the resources devoted to health care Recent NAS publication on satellite accounts including time inputs; see next slide (book also covers medical price indices) A Recommended Book Beyond the Market: Designing Non-Market Accounts for the United States; Washington: National Academy Press, 2005. Usefulness of Accounts Some would cite comparing levels of spending across countries Sometimes such comparisons have arguably had an effect; e.g., UK decision to increase spending to OECD average Rates of Change Within country one can not only calculate share of GDP (already available from NIPA), but how rate of change varies among health care sectors For example, share of spending going to pharmaceuticals But public sector spending known from budgets Comparative Rates of Change I have found comparative rates of change useful I am struck by the similarity of rates of change both across countries and over time Annual Real % Cost Increase per Capita, G-7*, 1960-2002* 8 7.1 Real % per Year 7 6 Average=4.9% 5.3 5.1 5 4 4.2 4.0 3.4 3 2 1 0 Can Fra Ger Jap UK US % Annual Increase in Real Personal Health Care Spending per Person, 1960-2002 Country *Italy missing data before 1990. Germany 1970-2002, Japan 1960-2001. Source: OECD Health Data 2004 and US GDP deflator. Similar Increase in Real US Annual $/Person by decade Medicare and Medicaid enacted %/person/yr (real) 7 6.2 6 5 4 5.3 5.2 Average = 4.4% 4.5 3.7 3.7 3.0 3 2 1 0 % Annual Increase in Real per capita Personal Health Care Spending 40s 50s 60s 70s 80s 90s 0003 Decade Managed care Sources: CMS National Health Accounts. Newhouse, JEP 1992(3), Stat Abst, Ec Rpt Pres. GDP Deflator. What Do These Data Tell Us? Any explanation of the cost increase in medical care needs to hold across countries and decades Differences among countries in financing institutions are not the explanation Costly advances in medicine explain much of the increase and probably will continue Costly advances: Newhouse, Jnl Econ Perspectives, 1992. The Increase Was Probably Worth It The roughly similar rates of increase everywhere are a crude market test In US case confirmed by Cutler: CVD and neonatal mortality advances alone can justify the entire US $ increase post 1950 Nordhaus: Value of US Δlife expectancy 1900-95 Value of ΔNational Income Cutler, Your Money or Your Life, Oxford, 2004; Nordhaus: The Health of Nations; NBER, 2002, W8818. A Question to Ponder Would you rather have 2005 health levels and 1955 incomes or 1955 health levels and 2005 incomes? No formal survey, but Nordhaus’ informal survey suggest many opt for the former, consistent with his finding – Choice of former goes up with age Defects of Current Price Indices Current medical price indices suggest much of expenditure increase is a price increase Implies falling productivity in medical care Sometimes used to justify expenditure caps But official price indices are badly biased upward for many reasons, including the omission of health gains Price index bias: Berndt et al., Handbook of Health Econ; Newhouse, NBER W8168, Academia Ec Rev March 2001. Toward Better Price Indices Need to construct price indices from Δcost of episode and Δoutcomes Price indices based on medical inputs such as MD visit cannot account for Δquality of care – For example, better scanner looks like Δprice Heart attack work suggests falling price of heart attack treatment; need to carry out similar work for other conditions Heart attack price: Cutler et al., QJE, November 1998. Conclusions Useful expansion of National Health Accounts to measure time used in the production of health Comparative measures across countries at a point in time and within countries across time can yield useful inferences Need to base price indices on episodes, not prices of medical care inputs