Download Short-run aggregate supply curve

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Monetary policy wikipedia , lookup

Fei–Ranis model of economic growth wikipedia , lookup

Business cycle wikipedia , lookup

Refusal of work wikipedia , lookup

2000s commodities boom wikipedia , lookup

Early 1980s recession wikipedia , lookup

Inflation targeting wikipedia , lookup

Inflation wikipedia , lookup

Full employment wikipedia , lookup

Stagflation wikipedia , lookup

Nominal rigidity wikipedia , lookup

Phillips curve wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Aggregate Supply and The Short-run
Tradeoff
Between Inflation and
Unemployment
CHAPTER 13
1
Aggregate Supply
• Aggregate supply behaves differently in the short run
than in the long run
• In the long run, prices are flexible, and the aggregate
supply curve is vertical
• When the aggregate supply curve is vertical, shifts in the
aggregate demand curve affect the price level, but the
output of the economy remains at its natural rate
• In the short run, prices are sticky, and the aggregate
supply curve is not vertical
• In the short-run, shifts in aggregate demand do cause
fluctuations in output
2
Four Models of Aggregate Supply
• Four models of aggregate supply:
– Sticky-wage
– Worker-Misperception
– Imperfect-information
– Sticky-wage
• In all the models, some market imperfection causes the output of the
• economy to deviate from its natural level
• As a result, the short-run aggregate supply curve is upward sloping,
rather than vertical, and shifts in the aggregate demand curve cause
the level of output to deviate temporarily from its natural level
• These temporary deviations represent the booms and busts of the
business cycle
• Each of the four models takes us to the same short-run aggregate
supply equation of the form…
3
Short-run Aggregate Supply
Equation
Y = Y + (P-Pe) where 
Expected
price level
positive constant:
an indicator of
Natural
how much
rate of output
output responds
to unexpected
changes in the
price level.
Output
•
•
Actual price level
This equation states that output deviates from its natural level when the
price level deviates from the expected price level
The parameter α indicates how much output responds to unexpected
changes in the price level, 1/α is the slope of the aggregate supply curve
4
The Sticky-Wage Model
• To preview the model, consider what happens to the amount of
output produced when the price level rises:
1. When the nominal wage is stuck, a rise in the price level lowers the
real wage, making labor cheaper
2. The lower real wage induces firms to hire more labor
3. The additional labor hired produces more output
• This positive relationship between the price level and the amount of
output means the aggregate supply curve slopes upward during the
time when the nominal wage cannot adjust to a change in the price
level
• The workers and firms set the nominal wage W based on the target
real wage w and on their expectation of the price level
• The nominal wage they set is:
W  w  Pe
Nominal wage=Target real wage X expected price level
• where W is nominal wage and w is target real wage.
5
The Sticky-Wage Model
• After the nominal wage has been set and before labor
has been hired, firms learn actual price level P
• The real wage turns out to be
W / P  w  ( P e / P)
Real wage= Target real wage X (expected price level/actual price level)
• This equation shows that the real wage deviates from its
target if the actual price level differs from the expected
price level
– When the actual price level is greater than expected, the real
wage is less than its target
– When the actual price level is less than expected, the real wage
is greater than its target
6
The Sticky-Wage Model
• The final assumption of the sticky-wage model is that
employment is determined by the quantity of labor that
firms demand
• The bargain between the workers and the firms does not
determine the level of employment in advance
• The workers agree to provide as much labor as the firms
wish to buy at the predetermined wage
• We describe the firms’ hiring decisions by the labor
demand function:
L  Ld (W / P)
• which states that the lower the real wage, the more labor
firms hire
• The output is determined by the production function
Y = F(L)
7
Y = F(L)
L = Ld (W/P)
Labor, L
An increase in the price level,
reduces the real wage for a given
nominal wage, which raises
employment and output and
income.
Labor, L
Y=Y+(P-Pe)
Income, Output, Y
8
The Sticky-Wage Model
• Because the nominal wage is sticky, an
unexpected change in P moves real wage
away from its target real wage and this
change in the real wage influences the
amounts of labor hired and output
produced
• AS can be written as
Y  Y   ( P  Pe )   0
9
The Worker-Misperception Model
• This model assumes that wages can adjust freely and
quickly to balance supply and demand for labor
• Its key assumption is that unexpected movements in
price influence labor supply because workers temporarily
confuse real and nominal wages
• The two components of the worker-misperception model
are labor supply and labor demand
• The quantity of labor firms demand depends on the real
wage:
Ld  Ld (W / P)
• The labor supply curve is
Ls  Ls (W / Pe )
• The quantity of labor supplied depends on the real wage
that workers expect to earn
10
The Worker-Misperception Model
• Workers know their nominal wage W but they do not know the over
price level P
• When deciding how much to work, they consider the expected real
wage, which equals the nominal wage W divided by their
expectation of the price level
• We can also write the expected real wage as
W W P
  e
e
P
P P
• The expected real wage is the product of the actual real wage W/P
and the variable P / P e
P / P e measures the workers’ misperception of the price level P:
•
– If P/P(exp.)>1, price level is higher that what workers expected and if
P/P(exp.)<1, price level is lower that what workers expected
• We can substitute this expression and write
Ls  Ls (W / P e )
W P 
Ls  Ls   e 
P P 
11
The Worker-Misperception Model
• The position of the labor supply curve and thus the eequilibrium in the
labor market depend on worker misperception P / P
• Whenever P rises, the reaction of the economy depends on whether
workers anticipate the change
• If they do, then P(exp.) rises proportionately with P
– Workers’ perceptions are accurate and neither labor supply nor labor
demand changes
– The nominal wage rises by the same amount as P and the real wage
and the level of employment remain the same
• If price increase catches workers by surprise, then P(exp.) remains
the same when P rises
– The increase in P / P e shifts the labor supply to the right, lowering the
real wage and raising the level of employment
– Workers believe that P is lower and thus real wage is higher
– This misperception induces them to supply more labor
– Firms are assumed to be more informed than workers and to recognize
the fall in real wage, so they hire more labor and produce more output
12
The Worker-Misperception Model
• The worker-misperception model says that
deviations of prices from expected prices
induce workers to alter their supply of
labor and this change in labor supply
alters the output firms produce
• The model implies AS curve of the form
Y  Y   ( P  Pe )   0
13
The Imperfect Information Model
• The third explanation for the upward slope of the short-run
aggregate supply curve is called the imperfect-information model
• Unlike the sticky-wage model, this model assumes that markets
clear—that is, all wages and prices are free to adjust to balance
supply and demand
• In this model, the short-run and long-run aggregate supply curves
differ because of temporary misperceptions about prices
• The imperfect-information model assumes that each supplier in the
economy produces a single good and consumes many goods
• Because the number of goods is so large, suppliers cannot observe
all prices at all times
• They monitor the prices of their own goods but not the prices of all
goods they consume
• Due to imperfect information, they sometimes confuse changes in
the overall price level with changes in relative prices
• This confusion influences decisions about how much to supply, and
it leads to a positive relationship between the price level and output
in the short run
14
The Imperfect Information Model
• Consider the decision facing a single supplier- a wheat farmer
• The amount of wheat she choose to produce depends on the
price of wheat relative to the prices of other goods and
services in the economy
• If the relative price of wheat is high, the farmer is motivated to
work hard and produce more wheat
• If the relative price of wheat is low, she prefers to enjoy more
leisure and produce less wheat
• Unfortunately, when the farmer makes her production
decision, she does not know the relative price of wheat
• She does not know the prices of all other goods in the
economy
• She must estimate the relative price of wheat using the
nominal price of wheat and her expectation of the overall price
level
15
The Imperfect Information Model
• Suppose all prices in the economy, including that of wheat, increase
– One possibility is that farmer expected this change in prices and her
estimate of relative price is unchanged
• She does not work harder
– Other possibility is that farmer did not expect the price level to increase
• She is not sure whether other prices have risen or whether only the
price of wheat has risen
• The farmer infers from the increase in the nominal price of wheat
that its relative price has risen somewhat so she produces more
• When the price level rises unexpectedly, all suppliers in the
economy observe increase in the prices of goods they produce
• They all infer rationally but mistakenly that the relative prices of
goods they produce have risen and they produce more
• When prices exceed expected prices, suppliers raise their output
and AS is
Y  Y   ( P  Pe )   0
16
The Sticky-Price Model
• The last model for the upward-sloping short-run
aggregate supply curve is called the sticky-price model
• This model emphasizes that firms do not instantly adjust
the prices they charge in response to changes in
demand
• Sometimes prices are set by long-term contracts
between firms and consumers
• To see how sticky prices can help explain an upwardsloping aggregate supply curve, first consider the pricing
decisions of individual firms and then aggregate the
decisions of many firms to explain the economy as a
whole
• We will have to relax the assumption of perfect
competition whereby firms are price-takers
– They will be price-setters
17
The Sticky-Price Model
• Consider the pricing decision faced by a typical firm
• The firm’s desired price p depends on two
macroeconomic variables:
1. The overall level of prices P
– A higher price level implies that the firm’s costs are higher
– Hence, the higher the overall price level, the more the firm will
like to charge for its product
2. The level of aggregate income Y
– A higher level of income raises the demand for the firm’s product
– Because marginal cost increases at higher levels of production,
the greater the demand, the higher the firm’s desired price
18
The Sticky-Price Model
• The firm’s desired price is:
p  P  a(Y  Y )
• This equations states that the desired price p
depends on the overall level of prices P and on
the level of aggregate demand relative to its
natural rate Y  Y
• The parameter a (which is greater than 0)
measures how much the firm’s desired price
responds to the level of aggregate output
19
The Sticky-Price Model
• Assume that there are two types of firms
– Some have flexible prices: they always set their prices according to this
equation
– Others have sticky prices: they announce their prices in advance based
on what they expect economic conditions to be
• Firms with sticky prices set prices according to
p  Pe  a(Y e  Y e )
• where the superscript “e” represents the expected value of a
variable
• For simplicity, assume these firms expect output to be at its natural
rate, so the last term a(Y e  Y e ) drops out
e
• Then these firms set price so that p  P
• That is, firms with sticky prices set their prices based on what they
expect other firms to charge
20
The Sticky-Price Model
• We can use the pricing rules of the two groups of firms to
derive the aggregate supply equation
• To do this, we find the overall price level in the economy
as the weighted average of the prices set by the two
groups
p  P  a(Y  Y ) p  P e
overall price
P  sP e  (1  s)  P  a(Y  Y ) 
• Subtract (1-s)P from both sides of this equation to obtain
sP  sP e  (1  s)  a(Y  Y ) 
• Divide both sides by s to solve for the overall price level
P  Pe  (1  s)a / s  (Y  Y )
21
The Sticky-Price Model
• The above equation can be explained as:
– When firms expect a high price level, they expect high costs
• Those firms that fix prices in advance set their prices high
• These high prices cause the other firms to set high prices also
• Hence a high expected price level leads to a high actual price level
– When output is high, the demand for goods is high
• Those firms with flexible prices set their prices high which leads to a
high price level
• The effect of output on the price level depends on the proportion of
firms with flexible prices
• The overall price level depends on the expected price level and on
the level of output
Y  Y   ( P  Pe )
s
• where  
(1  s)a
22
The Short-run Aggregate Supply
Curve
e)
Y
=
Y
+

(P-P
SRAS (P =P )
e
P
P2
P1
P0
2 at point A; the economy is at full employment Y and the
Start
LRAS*
SRAS (Pe=P0)actual price level is P0. Here the actual price level equals the
expected price level. Now let’s suppose we increase the price
B
level to P1.
A'
Since P (the actual price level) is now greater than Pe (the
expected price level) Y will rise above the natural rate, and we
A
e
AD'
slide along the SRAS (P =P0) curve to A' .
AD
Y Y' Output
Remember that our new SRAS (Pe=P0) curve is defined by the
presence of fixed expectations (in this case at P0). So in terms
of the SRAS equation, when P rises to P1, holding Pe constant
at P0, Y must rise.
Y = Y + (P-Pe)
The “long-run” will be defined when the expected price level equals the actual price level. So, as price level
expectations adjust, PeP2, we’ll end up on a new short-run aggregate supply curve, SRAS (Pe=P2) at point
B.
We made it back to LRAS, a situation characterized by perfect information where the actual price level (now
P2) equals the expected price level (also, P2).
In terms of the SRAS equation, we can see that as Pe catches up with P, that entire “expectations gap”
23
disappears and we end up on the long run aggregate supply curve at full employment where Y = Y.
Implications
Market with Imperfection
Labor
Markets
Yes Worker-misperception model
clear?
Goods
Imperfect-information model
Workers confuse nominal wage Suppliers confuse changes in the
changes with real wage changes price level with changes in relative
prices
No
Sticky-wage model
Sticky-price model
Nominal wages adjust slowly
The prices of goods adjust slowly
24
Inflation, Unemployment and the
Phillips Curve
• The implication of the short-run aggregate
supply curve
• The curve implies a trade-off between two
measures of economic performance– inflation
and unemployment
• This trade-off, called the Phillips curve, tells us
that to reduce the rate of inflation policymakers
must temporarily raise unemployment, and to
reduce unemployment, they must accept higher
inflation
25
Deriving the Phillips Curve from the
Aggregate Supply Curve
• The Phillips curve in its modern form states that the inflation rate
depends on three forces:
– Expected inflation
– The deviation of unemployment from the natural rate, called
cyclical unemployment
– Supply shocks
• These three forces are expressed in the following equation:
 = e  n) + 
Expected
inflation
Inflation
  Cyclical
unemployment
Supply
shock
26
Deriving the Phillips Curve from the
Aggregate Supply Curve
• β parameter measures the response of inflation to
cyclical unemployment
• Minus sign before the cyclical unemployment term
indicates that high unemployment tends to reduce
inflation
   e   (u  u n )  v
• Where does this equation come from?
P  Pe  (1/  )(Y  Y )
• First, add to the right-hand side of the equation a supply
shock ν to represent exogenous events that alter the
price level and shift the short-run AS curve
27
P  Pe  (1/  )(Y  Y )  v
Deriving the Phillips Curve from the
Aggregate Supply Curve
• Next, to go from the price level to inflation rates, subtract
last year’s price level from both sides of the equation
( P  P1 )  ( P e  Pe1 )  (1/  )(Y  Y )  v
   e  (1/  )(Y  Y )  v
• Third, to go from output to unemployment, use Okun’s
Law
– The deviation of output from its natural rate is inversely related to
the deviation of unemployment from its natural rate
– When output is higher than the natural rate of output,
unemployment is lower than the natural rate of unemployment
(1/  )(Y  Y )   (u  u n )
28
Deriving the Phillips Curve from the
Aggregate Supply Curve
• Substitute this into previous equation
   e   (u  u n )  v
• The Phillips-curve equation and the short-run aggregate
supply equation represent essentially the same
macroeconomic ideas
• Both equations show a link between real and nominal
variables that causes the classical dichotomy (the theoretical
separation of real and nominal variables) to break down in the
short run
• Short-run aggregate supply curve: output is related to
unexpected movements in the price level
• Phillips curve: unemployment is related to unexpected
movements in the inflation rate
– The aggregate supply curve is more convenient when studying
output and the price level, whereas the Phillips curve is more
convenient when studying unemployment and inflation
29
Adaptive Expectations and Inflation
Inertia
• To make the Phillips curve useful for analyzing the choices
facing policymakers, we need to say what determines
expected inflation
• A simple assumption is that people form their expectations of
inflation based on recently observed inflation
• This assumption is called adaptive expectations
• Suppose expected inflation P(exp.) equals last year’s inflation
P(-1)
• In this case, we can write the Phillips curve as:
 e   1
   1   (u  u n )  v
• which states that inflation depends on past inflation, cyclical
unemployment, and a supply shock
• When the Phillips curve is written in this form, it is sometimes
called the Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment, 30
or NAIRU
Adaptive Expectations and Inflation
Inertia
• The term π(-1) implies that inflation has inertia- it keeps going until
something acts to stop it
• If unemployment is at its natural rate and if there are no supply
shocks, the price level will continue to rise at the rate it has been
rising
• This inertia arises because past inflation influences expectations of
future inflation and because these expectations influence the wages
and prices that people set
• In the model of AD/AS, inflation inertia is interpreted as persistent
upward shifts in both the aggregate supply curve and aggregate
demand curve
– If prices have been rising, people will expect them to continue to
rise
– Because the position of the SRAS curve depends on the
expected price level, the curve will shift upward overtime
– It will continue to shift upward until some event such as
recession or supply shock, changes inflation expectations
31
The Causes of Rising and Falling
Inflation
• The second and third terms in the Phillips-curve equation
show the two forces that can change the rate of inflation
– The second term shows that cyclical unemployment exerts
downward or upward pressure on inflation
• Low unemployment pulls the inflation rate up
• This is called demand-pull inflation because high aggregate
demand is responsible for this type of inflation
• High unemployment pulls the inflation rate down
• The parameter β measures how responsive inflation is to cyclical
unemployment
– The third term ν shows that inflation also rises and falls because
of supply shocks
• An adverse supply shock, such as the rise in world oil prices in the
70s, implies a positive value of v and causes inflation to rise
• This is called cost-push inflation because adverse supply shocks
are typically events that push up the costs of production
32
The Short-run Tradeoff Between
Inflation and Unemployment

In
Inthe
theshort
shortrun,
run,inflation
inflationand
andunemployment
unemployment
are
arenegatively
negativelyrelated.
related.At
Atany
anypoint
pointin
intime,
time,aa
policymaker
policymakerwho
whocontrols
controlsaggregate
aggregatedemand
demand
can
canchoose
chooseaacombination
combinationof
ofinflation
inflationand
and
unemployment
unemploymenton
onthis
thisshort-run
short-runPhillips
Phillips
curve.
curve.
e + 
un Unemployment, u
33
The Short-run Tradeoff Between
Inflation and Unemployment
• How can policymakers influence AD with monetary or fiscal policy?
• Expected prices and supply shocks are beyond the policymaker’s
immediate control
• By changing AD, the policymaker can alter output, unemployment
and inflation
• The policymaker can expand AD to lower unemployment and raise
inflation
• The short-run Phillips curve: negative relationship between
unemployment and inflation
• The position of short-run Phillips curve depends on the expected
rate of inflation
• If expected inflation rises, the curve shift upward and the
policymaker’s tradeoff becomes less favorable: inflation is higher for
any level of unemployment
•
As people adjust their expectations about inflation over time, the tradeoff
between inflation and unemployment holds only in the short-run
34
Let’s start at point A, a point of price stability (  = 0%) and full employment (u = un).
Remember, each short-run Phillips curve is defined by the presence of fixed expectations.
Suppose there is an increase in the rate of growth of the money supply causing LM and AD to shift out,
resulting in an unexpected increase in inflation. The Phillips curve equation  = e –  (u-un) + v
implies that the change in inflation misperceptions causes unemployment to decline. So, the economy
moves to a point above full employment at point B.
As long as this inflation misperception exists, the economy will
LRPC (u=un)
remain below its natural rate un at u'.
When the economic agents realize the new level of inflation, they
will end up on a new short-run Phillips curve where expected
D
E
10%
inflation equals the new rate of inflation (5%) at point C, where
actual inflation (5%) equals expected inflation (5%).
If the monetary authorities opt to obtain a lower u again,
then they will increase the money supply such that  is 10
B
C
5%
percent, for example. The economy moves to point D,
where actual inflation is 10percent, but, e is 5 percent.

A
u'
un
When expectations adjust, the
economy will land on a new SRPC, at
e
SRPC ( = 10%) point E, where both  and e equal 10
percent.
e
SRPC ( = 5%)
Unemployment, u
SRPC (e = 0%)
35
Rational Expectations and the
Possibility of Painless Disinflation
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
Because the expectation of inflation influences the short-run tradeoff
between inflation and unemployment, it is crucial to understand how people
form expectations
Rational expectations make the assumption that people optimally use all the
available information about current government policies, to forecast the
future
According to this theory, a change in monetary or fiscal policy will change
expectations, and an evaluation of any policy change must incorporate this
effect on expectations
If people do form their expectations rationally, then inflation may have less
inertia than it first appears
Proponents of rational expectations argue that the short-run Phillips curve
does not accurately represent the options that policymakers have available
They believe that if policy makers are credibly committed to reducing
inflation, rational people will understand the commitment and lower their
expectations of inflation
Inflation can then come down without a rise in unemployment and fall in
output
36
Rational Expectations and the
Possibility of Painless Disinflation
• A painless disinflation has two requirements
• The plan to reduce inflation must be announced
before the workers and firms who set wages and
prices have formed their expectations
• The workers and firms must believe the
announcement, otherwise they will not reduce
their expectations
• If both requirements are met, the announcement
will shift the short-run tradeoff between inflation
and unemployment downward, permitting a
lower rate of inflation without higher
unemployment
37
Hysteresis and the Challenge to
the Natural-Rate Hypothesis
• Our entire discussion of the cost of disinflation has been based on
the natural rate hypothesis
• The hypothesis is summarized in the following statement:
– Fluctuations in aggregate demand affect output and employment only in
the short run. In the long run, the economy returns to the levels of
output, employment, and unemployment described by the classical
model
• Recently, some economists have challenged the natural-rate
hypothesis by suggesting that aggregate demand may affect output
and employment even in the long run
• They have pointed out a number of mechanisms through which
recessions might leave permanent scars on the economy by altering
the natural rate of unemployment
• Hyteresis is the term used to describe the long-lasting influence of
history on the natural rate
• A recession can have permanent effects if it changes the people
who become unemployed (such as reducing the desire to find job)
38