Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Response to Shocks: Incorporating Flexibility in Fiscal Rules Manmohan S. Kumar Fiscal Affairs Department May 5, 2009 Outline Credibility-flexibility trade-off How to make fiscal rules flexible Choice of target Combination of rules Escape clauses; Contingency funds Features Fiscal of existing fiscal rules rules and the crisis Main elements Mechanism placing durable constraints on fiscal discretion through numerical limits on budgetary aggregates (budget balance, public debt, expenditure, revenue) Needed only when the commitment to sustainable public finances lacks credibility because of well-identified bias in the design and implementation of fiscal policy Any fiscal policy rule is made of 3 parts: A numerical target or ceiling delineating the range of adequate fiscal policies in terms of a specific fiscal indicator (or a combination thereof). An explicit cost to be incurred by policymakers if they deviate from the rule. A monitoring/enforcement procedure ensuring that the costs are felt by policymakers when deviations occur. Credibility-Flexibility Trade-Off Debate between rules and flexibility familiar: Rules can help in attaining and sustaining credibility with regard to the soundness of macroeconomic policy But while requiring adjustment to persistent shocks, need flexibility to deal with temporary shocks Degree of flexibility that may be available in the context of a rules-based framework depends on: Design of the rule itself Extent to which there is sufficient credibility to begin with Scope for action: e.g. higher scope for discretionary expansion in bad time if buffers built up in good times Types of Shocks Ideal is to have adequate degree of flexibility, allowed for in an ex ante and transparent manner, to deal with the different types of shocks that would not compromise the underlying sustainability of budgetary positions Country specific considerations What shocks? Output revenue impact “automatic” stabilizers • Question: what role for discretionary policy over the cycle? Interest rate and exchange rate debt service (especially if large short-term / forex debt); Inflation indexed expenditure items (wage bill, social transfers,…) and revenue (non-indexed tax brackets vs. nominal tax debt); Realization of contingent or implicit liabilities (e.g. banking sector crisis, non-performing public enterprises, call of loan guarantees,…); Other shocks: natural disasters, wars,… Responding to output shocks: Choice of Target A debt rule, while constraining fiscal policy to sustainable debt dynamics, lacks flexibility in the face of shocks: could force undesirable policy adjustments. May also be too flexible (i.e. incapable of preventing policy bias) if one is well below the ceiling. Since medium-term debt objective is critical, it can be used in conjunction with other rules An overall budget balance rule with an annual target, or nominal deficit target, has a number of useful features. But, if focussed on annual target, would not provide flexibility with respect to cyclical developments. It cannot prevent procyclicality in good times so it inevitably "imposes" procyclicality in bad times. Expenditure rule: Provides room for automatic stabilizers to operate freely, but does not map into specific debt target (issue of sustainability). Helpful if the main policy bias is procyclicality (not sustainability). Works best in combination with a deficit/debt ceiling and in the context of an MTBF (Sweden, Netherlands, Finland). Over the Cycle Limits of nominal targets led to consideration of “balance over the cycle” type of rule, or Cyclically adjusted balance (CAB) targets. Example of each include: Advantages of “balance over the cycle” are: Balance over the cycle: Sweden, UK (1997-08), Australia Cyclically-adjusted balance: Chile, Netherlands, SGP Medium-term orientation for fiscal policy Allow for automatic stabilizers and discretionary response to shocks Promotes sustainability But challenges with regard to dating the cycle: No established methodology for judging start and end points Sensitive to assumptions about trend and latest data (eg. Current crisis) Data lags and revisions to GDP data Interest rate and exchange rate shocks Interest rate and exchange rate overall balance through debt service, especially if debt is short-term and forex-denominated. A rule based on overall balance would force sharp fiscal policy adjustments in response to such temporary shocks. [Response will be needed if they are persistent.] Primary balance target helps to the extent that shocks are transitory. Issue: under an overall balance rule, falling public debt and debt service makes space for primary expenditure increases. Question: allow for larger spending or put savings in a fund for future generations (eg.if aging is an issue), or a stabilization fund (buffer for future shocks)? Combination of rules Combine a fiscal rule as an intermediate target with an anchor Flexibility in the intermediate target, based on budget balance, primary balance, or expenditure, can be provided as long as debt ratio remains below a specified threshold In response to exogenous shocks, allow limited deviations from the anchor Pronounced deviations would require tightening of the intermediate target Escape Clauses An essential requirement is to have a predetermined, credible & transparent mechanism Desirable to have limited discretion in providing interpretation of events Range of factors that allow escape clauses to be triggered Returning back to the rule Issue of credibility Swiss “debt brake” principle Requires structural fiscal balance ex-ante every year. Implementation: one year ahead ceiling on central government expenditure, equal to the corresponding projected cyclically adjusted revenue Ex-post, structural balance accrues on a fictitious account. Negative balance on the account can never exceed 6 percent of federal expenditure GDP. Positive balances on the account (cumulative structural surpluses) provide room for structural deficits. The rule requires the government to eliminate any negative balance in the account: no timeframe is specified, unless the negative balance exceeds 6 percent of annual federal expenditure (about 0.6 percent of GDP), in which case the account must be brought down to below 6 percent within three years—hence the debt-break mechanism Contingency Funds Rationale Issue of transparency; activation Key features Accumulation of reserves in the fund during “good” times; to be drawn down during downturns or other shocks Rainy Day funds Increasing recourse to rules Number of fiscal rules by category of countries: 1990-2008 80 70 Industrial EU-27 Emerging 60 LIC's 50 40 30 20 10 0 1990 1995 2000 2008 Type of rule Fiscal Rules Single rule; 20; 23% Multiple rules; 68; 77% Country variations in single vs. multiple rules 88% Single Rule 82% Multiple Rules 66% 34% 18% 13% Industrial Emerging LIC Evolution of different types of rules Number of countries with at least one fiscal policy rule (by type of rule) 80 70 Budget balance Debt Expenditure 60 Revenue 50 40 30 20 10 0 1990 1995 2000 2008 Expenditure and revenue rules are thus relative newcomers Median duration of existing fiscal rules (in years) 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Budget balance Debt Expenditure Revenue Budget balance rules appear stronger and have wider coverage Selected features of rules-based fiscal frameworks by type of rule (common features only) 1.00 Budget balance Debt 0.90 Revenue 0.80 Expenditure 0.70 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 0.00 Independent enforcement (relative frequency) Independent monitoring (relative frequency) Coverage (median Statutory basis (median relative to maximum relative to maximum possible score) possible score) Features by country groups Selected features of rules-based fiscal frameworks (relative frequencies by country groups) 1.00 0.90 Industrial Emerging LIC's Resource-rich 0.80 0.70 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 0.00 Independent M TEF Independent FRL (all rules) Provision(s) enforcement (relative to forecasts (all for fiscal procedure (all BBR and DR) rules) stabilization rules) (relative to BBR) Exclusion of Independent high-quality monitoring (all spending rules) (relative to BBR and ER) Large shock 4 2 0 -2 -4 United States -6 United Kingdom Japan Germany Output gap (in percent of potential GDP) -8 -10 1996A1 1997A1 1998A1 1999A1 2000A1 2001A1 2002A1 2003A1 2004A1 2005A1 2006A1 2007A1 2008A1 2009A1 Type of response Was the rule changed? If so, why? If not, why not? Flexible numerical constraint Flexible time frame for adjustment Escape clauses No change, but conflict? Change In numerical constraint Abeyance Response by different country groupings 75% 72% 50% 26% 24% 24% 25% 3% 0% No Need No but Conflict Industrial Yes No Need No but Conflict Emerging Yes No Need No but Conflict Yes Low Income Overall response 51% 32% 17% No Need No but Conflict Yes Unchanged rules No Need because: Flexible Numerical Constraints Countries Australia Belgium Brazil Canada Cape Verde Colombia Ecuador Finland Iceland Indonesia Liberia Luxembo urg Mauritius Norway Venezuela Equatorial Guinea EU27 Flexible Time Frame for Adjustment New Zealand Austria Czech Republic Nigeria Romania Escape Clause France Germany India Kenya Unchanged but tension No change in rules but strong conflict between the rule and desirable policy responses Benin Botswana Burkina Faso Cameroon Central African Republic Chad Comoros Congo Cote d'Ivoire Dominica Gabon Georgia Grenada Guinea Bissau Israel Japan Kosovo Mali Niger Panama Senegal Sierra Leone Pakistan Rules changed Yes, Numerical Constraints Change Permanently Temporarily with Specific Timeframe Temporarily without Specific Timeframe 2 4 33% 67% Germany Mexico Yes, Rule Changes Permanent Abolition In Abeyance with Specific Timeframe In Abeyance without Specific Timeframe 0 0 5 4 0% 0% 56% 44% Chile Austria Argentina Italy Costa Rica Finland Namibia Netherlands Lithuania Peru Russia Spain UK Response, and public debt Debt ratio end-2008 No Need No but Conflict Yes In percent of GDP 196 113 76 65 59 57 51 48 40 37 21 0 Industrial Emerging LIC Total Response, and change in overall balance 2008 2009 1.0 0.5 0.0 0.0 0.0 Emerging Change in OB -1.1 LIC -0.9 -0.9 Total -1.4 -1.6 Industrial -0.7 -1.6 -2.1 -3.0 Emerging -1.0 -1.8 Change in OB Industrial LIC -0.9 -2.0 -2.1 -3.0 -3.0 -4.0 -4.0 No Need No but Conflict Total Yes -3.8 -4.0 -4.1 -4.3 -5.0 -4.6 No Need -6.0 No but Conflict Yes -5.6 -4.0 Response, and GDP growth 2008 2009 7.3 2.0 2.3 No Need No Need No but Conflict No but Conflict Yes Yes 0.0 3.9 3.5 3.5 3.4 2.7 2.1 0.8 Growth in percent Growth in percent 4.5 Industrial -2.2 -3.0 -4.3 0.0 LIC Total -1.3 -4.0 Emerging LIC -1.6 1.0 Industrial -0.6 0.0 Emerging Total -6.2 -3.3 Case study: UK UK activated an escape clause that allows for an open-ended return to discretion. Rule suspended and a "temporary operating rule" put in place: To "improve the cyclically-adjusted budget each year, once the economy emerges from the downturn, so it reaches balance and debt is falling as a proportion of GDP once the global shocks have worked their way through the economy in full”. Timeframe moved from 2015/16 to 2017/18 between November 2008 and April 2009 Budget, and the projected peak level of debt-to-GDP increased from 59 to almost 80 percent. “The government’s ‘temporary operating rule’ offers it considerable flexibility in setting fiscal policy, but it may not be seen as much of a constraint on tax and spending decisions”. Contrast with the notion of escape clause under the SGP Right arrangement is probably somewhere in between (e.g. escape clause a la UK should be made perishable after 2 years, with a reactivation requiring a super majority...) Uncertainty in emerging markets 55 50 Public Debt (in percent of GDP) Emerging Market G-20 Countries 45 Lower growth and contingent liability shock 40 35 Baseline Scenario 30 2007 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 Uncertainty in advanced countries 150 Public Debt (in percent of GDP) Advanced G-20 Countries 140 130 120 110 100 Baseline 90 80 70 2007 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 Conclusions Rules that are perceived to be excessively “rigid” may not be sustainable Appropriate amount of flexibility can enhance credibility Contours of flexibility need to be decided beforehand, be transparent, and reflect country-specific circumstances Increasing reliance on rules Response to recent shocks reflected inbuilt flexibility, credibility, and existing space Large uncertainties ahead need to be taken into account in the design, and timing of implementation Type of Country Rule Changed? Industrial No Need 21 72 No but Conflict 1 3 Yes 7 24 No Need 17 50 No but Conflict 9 26 Yes 8 24 No Need 6 25 No but Conflict 18 75 Yes 0 0 No Need 44 51 No but Conflict 28 32 Yes 15 17 Emerging LIC Total Number of Countries In percent