Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Do consumers’ behavior and producers’ efficiency move in consistent patterns? Paul E Waggoner and Jesse H. Ausubel The Connecticut Agricultural Experiment Station, New Haven and Rockefeller University, New York. October 2002 A population may have more or less income to spend and spend more or less of it on objects. Producers may affect the environment more or less as they make the objects. In quantities and with balanced dimensions, the identity ImPACT* connects the actors’ to environmental impact, showing the leverage each can exert. I = P A C T where I or Im = environmental impact, P = population, A = income, as GDP per person, C = consumers’ behavior, as product use per GDP, and T = producers’ efficiency, as impact per product. Sometimes C is called intensity of use, A affluence and T technology. We call falling C dematerialization. Despite ImPACT’s implication of independence among variables on the right, an income elasticity of (b-1) connects C to A, a relation which we explored in an earlier paper.* In this supplement on line, we explore whether another pair of variables, C & T, move in consistent patterns from product to product. Exploring 6 diverse impacts in the U.S. -cropland, nitrogen, irrigation water, carbon emissions, building materials, and life expectancy -we check to see whether joint trajectories of C & T show a family resemblance. We also look to see whether they move in tandem or independently. Along the way we revisit the power of the ImPACT identity to compare the environmental leverages of consumer behavior and producer efficiency, quantitatively. * Waggoner, P.E., and Ausubel, J. H. 2002. A framework for sustainability science: A renovated IPAT identity. Proc. National Acad. Sci. (US) 99:7860-7865. On line at http://phe.rockefeller.edu/ImPACT/ImPACT.pdf Four decades of U.S farm experience set the stage for exploring patterns of consumers’ behavior and producers’ efficiency. Clearing and tilling cropland to feed a population P impact the environment. In addition to depending on P, the impact’s extent also depends on income A, on consumption of crops/GDP C, and finally on producers’ cropland/crop T. To ease comparison among crops and other products we shall examine, we refer values to the first year of the record, which is 1961 for crops. On the logarithmic coordinates of our graphs, ten percent more C or T moves points up by 0.1; doubling moves them up by 0.7. During almost four decades, workers more than doubled income A. At the same time, U.S. consumer behavior cut C by just less than half. And producer efficiency halved U.S. land/crop T by doubling yields. Over the span of four decades, both C and T generally moved down. But sometimes for short periods they moved in opposite directions. Income A and Crop C and T per 1961 1.5 ln A, C or T 1.0 A 0.5 C 0.0 1960 -0.5 T 1970 1980 1990 2000 -1.0 ImPACT Patterns Waggoner Ausubel page 2 Focus on their joint patterns by graphing behavior C directly against efficiency T. Although graphing T vs. C below rather than T vs. time as before shifts coordinates, efficiency T still changes up and down. A 0.7 lower T means half as many acres/bushel because bushels/acre double. Now, however, consumer behavior C changes from right to left. C moving 0.7 leftward means the fraction of GDP expended on crops halves. Two patterns stand out. In brief periods as near dry 1983 the data points moved diagonally left and up. When the U.S. crop fell as during the 1983 drought, cropland/crop T rose. At the same time because GDP changed little, crop/GDP C decreased leftward. Thus the zigzagging. Over the span of four decades and several zigs and zags, alarms and excursions however, a general trend carried C leftward and T down. Consumer behavior generally dematerialized consumption leftward, and producer efficiency generally lowered land/crop T by greater yields. Over the span, producer efficiency lowered land/crop T by 0.8, a bit more than consumers’ 0.6 dematerialization of C leftward. So relating C & T did not reveal a single consistent pattern. Rather it revealed two patterns: 1) Short zigzags and 2) a long trend left of dematerialization combined with a long trend down of less land/crop. And the trends quantified the leverage of behavior and efficiency. Crop T vs C annual per 1961 1961 0 -0.7 -0.6 -0.5 -0.4 -0.3 -0.2 -0.1 0 -0.2 1983 ln(T) -0.4 -0.6 2000 C -0.6 T -0.8 -0.8 -1 ln(C) ImPACT Patterns Waggoner Ausubel page 3 The rise and maturing of new technology cause another pattern of C & T. Following World War II, inexpensive, synthetic nitrogen fertilizer appeared in farming as a new technology, relieving the mining of guano deposits and also relieving depletion of the nitrogen in farm soil. When C vs. fertilizer/crop T is graphed, crop/GDP C, of course, still dematerializes leftward as in the previous graph. In the new graph below, however, nitrogen fertilizer/crop T rose for decades as U.S farmers exploited the new technology. Then about 1983 an opposite trend of falling T started. With the maturing of fertilizer technology from 1983 onward, farmers began using less fertilizer to grow the national crop. Experience taught producers to apply the new technology of fertilizer more efficiently. To the previous patterns of zigzags and continuing fall of T while C dematerializes, new technology adds a third pattern of a rise followed by the start of falling T. Nitrogen fertilizer T vs C annual per 1961 1 1983 0.8 ln(T) 0.6 0.4 2000 0.2 0 -0.7 -0.6 -0.5 -0.4 -0.3 ln(C) -0.2 -0.1 0 1961 ImPACT Patterns Waggoner Ausubel page 4 Improvements can slow as well as start. In addition to land and nitrogen, crops need water. In the graph below crops/GDP C remains as defined before and dematerializes leftward as before. In the new graph, however, efficiency T becomes the irrigation water drawn per all U.S crop production. Higher yield per water withdrawn from wells and canals and applied to irrigated acres would cut water/crop T, obviously. A smaller role of irrigation in national crop production also could cut our T of water/all crops . The graph of C vs. T shows the familiar, leftward dematerialization of C. The newly defined T for irrigation displays a new pattern: An episodic decrease from 1970 to 1985. A likely cause is the sharply less withdrawal of ground water in 1985 than 1980, ending progressive increases in withdrawals. After that sharp decrease, the irrigation-water/all crops T held steady as more efficient water use compensated for a small expansion of irrigated acreage. The episodic fall of T for irrigation water during the 1980s adds still another to our growing collection of different C vs. T patterns. Irrigation T vs C 5-yr per 1960 1960/61 0.1 1970 -0.6 -0.5 -0.4 -0.3 -0.2 ln(T) -0.7 0 -0.1 -0.1 0 -0.2 1995 C -0.5 T -0.4 -0.3 1985 -0.4 -0.5 ln(C) ImPACT Patterns Waggoner Ausubel page 5 Slow improvement of one of the pair C & T needn’t constrain improvement in the other. For a new subject, we explore the consumption of energy and emission of the greenhouse gas, carbon dioxide to produce the energy. Consumer behavior levers emission with less energy/GDP C. Producers lever emission with less emission/energy T. The graph of C vs. T shows that U.S consumers dematerialized energy/GDP C about 2% per yr, moving C leftward 0.36 during the 18 years of 1980/98. During the same 18 years, U.S. energy producers were able to improve or lower carbon dioxide emission/energy only about one-tenth as fast. The good news from this pattern of C & T is that consumers can improve behavior despite producers’ slow progress improving T. Alternatively, producers could presumably improve efficiency even if consumers were unable to dematerialize. Carbon T vs C annual per 1980 1988 -0.4 -0.3 -0.2 1980 0 -0.1 -0.01 ln(T) -0.02 -0.03 1998 C -0.36 T -0.04 -0.04 -0.05 -0.06 ln(C) ImPACT Patterns Waggoner Ausubel page 6 0 Producers’ efficiency may display little trend while consumer behavior goes through tumultuous changes Consider buildings and the cement and lumber to produce them. For building, we defined C as value of new construction put in place divided by the GDP. During 1965/97 building went through cycles of boom and bust, which sped, slowed and even reversed dematerialization of C. How did producers’ efficiency T fare during the tumult of building? One can define a cement/building T by dividing the tons of cement consumed in America by construction value. Or a lumber/building T from the volume of lumber plus plywood. The two T’s declined a bit 1965/80. They then wobbled until 1990. During the 1990s while C scarcely changed, T cement went up a bit while T lumber fell a bit. Unlike the pattern of regular dematerialization of energy in the preceding graph, building changed irregularly. Like efficiency in carbon emission, the T for cement or T for lumber resisted change. But adding a new pattern, dematerialization of building C was unsteady, while T for its materials changed little and erratically. Cement & lumber T vs C annual per 1965 0 -0.6 -0.5 -0.4 -0.3 -0.2 -0.1 0 -0.05 ln(T) T cement -0.1 -0.15 T lumber -0.2 ln(C) ImPACT Patterns Waggoner Ausubel page 7 C may move right as well as dematerialize left. With the exception of some zags among zigs in the preceding graphs of C vs. T, C always dematerialized left. Is dematerialization universal? An income elasticity of (b-1) connects C to A. The b is the income elasticity of per capita consumption. For a necessity like food, b is less than 1, making the C’s elasticity (b-1) negative. That is, if b is 0.7, raising income A by 10% dematerializes C leftward by (0.7-1.0) times 10% or 3%. So the income elasticities less than 1 of such necessities as we have examined combined with rising income to dematerialize C leftward in our graphs of C & T. To show C moving right in a graph of C & T, we must find a b greater than 1. From 1987 to 2000 U.S. health-care expenditure per capita rose faster than income A. The ratio of health-care to income change corresponds to an income elasticity of per capita health-care expenditure of 1.4. The b of 1.4 makes the elasticity (b-1) of health-care/GDP C a positive 0.4 instead of the negative elasticities that dematerialized C in the previous examples. Thus, C may move right as well as dematerialize left. To complete a C & T graph, we need a T. Although one can hope health care improves quality of life, we don’t know how to quantify it. On the other hand, we can quantify national life expectancy, the product of population times life expectancy. More than medicine extends life, and we go to the doctor for more than life-threatening complaints. But we definitely go to the hospital if our life is threatened, and much will be spent on us then. So to illustrate something that does not dematerialize in a C & T graph, we define health-care expenditure/GDP C and national life expectancy/health-care expenditure T. T declined because national life expectancy extended although not as fast as health-care expenditure increased. For our exercise, one significant result is showing dematerialization is not a universal pattern. Some parts of the economy, such as health care and education, are capturing more expenditures while food and water win relatively less. Little thought has gone into how the materializing sectors affect the environment. Health T vs C annual per 1987 ln(T) Life/Health care cost 1987 0.0 -0.1 0.0 0.1 -0.2 0.2 0.3 1992 -0.3 -0.4 -0.5 2000 ln(C) Health care cost/GDP ImPACT Patterns Waggoner Ausubel page 8 Consumer behavior and producer efficiency move on diverse paths--graphically. Referring our examples to the first year of their record and superimposing them on a single chart of C & T, draws a synoptic chart of their diverse patterns. With zigs and zags of good years and bad, crop consumption C dematerialized and producers’ use of land shrank. With the same dematerialization, fertilizer per crop rose rapidly and then started down, and irrigation water used per all crops fell in a dramatic episode. The slow change of carbon dioxide emission per energy T did not keep consumers from cutting energy/GDP C. Changing C irregularly, building cycles cause irregular—even reversed-time-lines along the C axis and draw confused courses of efficiency T. The dematerialization of C may typify necessities, but health care demonstrates dematerialization is not universal. Diverse paths 1 0.5 ln(T) Fertilizer Cement Lumber -0.7 -0.5 Irrigation CO2 0 -0.3 -0.1 0.1 -0.5 Health Cropland -1 ln(C) ImPACT Patterns Waggoner Ausubel page 9 0.3 In the End. With C, consumers reveal their behavior as they spend their income A. With T, producers show their efficiency avoiding impact to fill consumers’ wants. Graphing behavior C vs. efficiency T shows diverse patterns in the U.S. It highlights the lack of a general connection between C & T. Thus neither consumers nor producers need wait for the other to mitigate impact. When consumers’ behavior lifts income elasticity over 1 and income rises, C increases. Commonly, as for necessities, however, consumers’ behavior causes an income elasticity of consumption/capita less than 1 and thus negative elasticity of C. So commonly, C dematerializes. Graphing C vs. T shows the relative leverage that consumers & producers exert on impact. Consumers’ improvement of behavior C challenges producers to improve efficiency T. By levering C & T differentially rather than in a set pattern, the actors demonstrate the merit of ImPACT separating A, C & T--quantitatively. ImPACT Patterns Waggoner Ausubel page 10