Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
The Costly Transition from Stabilization to Sustainable Growth: Israel's Case Michael Bruno Sc Leora (Rubin) Meridor t Discussion Paper 90.01 Januarv 1990 expressed in the discussion paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Bank of Israel . Any views series 91007 ירושלים.780 .ד.בנק ישראל ת מחלקת המחקר של Research Department. Bank of Israel. P.O.B. 780, Jerusalem. 91007. Israel M. Bruno and L. (Rubin) Meridor The Costly Transition rfom Stabilization to Sustainable Growth: Israel's Case* Abstract Two years after Israel's successful stabilization of July 1985 and aftex a considerable onetime increase in consumption and in business sector output and productivity the economy went into a deep twoyear slump, leading to a substantial irse in unemp loyment in the course of 1989. While some special unanticipated events may have contirbuted to the depth of the recession its main cause is shown to be rooted in the slow recuperation from the distortive effects of the inflationary era and from the effect of rising labour costs, high initial real interest rates and a heavier taxation burden. These were in large part endogenous to the poststabilization process. A similar delayed poststabilization cycle is known from other histoircal episodes, notably in Europe in the 1920s. In addition to the detailed analysis of these events the paper discusses the restructuring process going on in the economy as well as vairous financial aspects of the stabilization process. Finally the paper analyzes the reasons for the persistence of the 1520 percent inflation rate. The analysis concerns structural factors as well as credibility issues having to do with general macro policies and in particular the slow learning process in the wage and exchange rate policy game. We would like to thank Mordechai Fraenkel, Nissan Liviatan and Zalman Shitfer for illuminating comments on an earlier draft, and Galit Gonen for research assistance. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 1 I. Introduction and Overview of Main Developments 198789 By mid1987, two years after the start of the July 1985 stabilization program, Israel looked as if it had managed to extricate itself from the worst economic crisis in its history at minimal cost. Not only did inflation come down from 500 percent to 1520 percentper annum. The Government deficit came down from an average of around 15 percent of GNP through the preceding decade to a complete balance and even a slight surplus in 1986. The external financial position of the country improved dramatically, as is shown by the fall in the foreign debt and the substantial increase in foreign exchange reserves. After a short initial recession with higher unemployment in the second half of 1985 (phase I of the program) output in the business sector went up by 6 percent on average in 198587 and unemployment quickly fell to below its preJuly 1985 rateof 6 percent (for summary data see Table 1). Although many obvious adjustment problems remained, this second phase (198687) seemed at the time to heralcfthe almost complete successof the program in not only enabling the economy to stabilize at relatively low real transition costs but also lay the foundation for sustainable growth.1 In the second half of 1987 a recession developed which deepened into a real slump in economic activity in 1988 and 1989, with GDP growth falling to around 1 percent per annum and unemployment gradually rising to 9.5 percent by the second half of 1989, while inflation has apparently been stuck at a 1520 percent annual rate. Given the excessive private consumption boom of 198687 (average annual growth rate of over 11 percent!) it was only natural to anticipate a subsequent cyc'hcal downturn which in itself was expected to lead to a lower growth rate for 1988. Two other factors played a role. One was the beginning of the uprising in the Adminis tered Terirtoires (Intifada) in December 1987, which temporairly reduced inter national touirsm and disrupted trade in goods and labour services with the terirtoires. Another factor had to do with the policy disruptions and uncertainties of an election year (the national election took place in November 1988, and municipal elections 4 months later). A major manifestation of that was the postponement of a decision to * The detailed developments in the peirod until mid1987 were analyzed in Bruno and Piterman's (1988) paper for the Toledo volume and the subsequent Bank of Israel Annual Report for 1987, published in May 1988. A longerterm view of the cirsis and the reform process was recently given in Bruno (1989(. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 2 adjust the exchange rate. The last adjustment had taken place in January 1987 and growth in unit labour costs continued to erode export profitability. A seires of speculative waves took place and reached their height after the elections, in December 1988. . Shortly after the entry of a new government (wjth Mr. Peres as Minister of Finance) two consecutive devaluations of 5 percent and 8 percent took place in December 1988 and January 1989 as part of a new policy package that accompanied the 1989 budget, also involving further reform steps in the money and capital markets. An agreement with the Trade Unions was signed in February 1989 which again (as in the 1985 and 1987 devaluations) temporairly suspended the existing COLA agreement to partly neutralize the inflationary consequences of the devalua itons. A new agreement, to cover the peirod April 1989 to April 1990, was simul taneously signed, by which 85 percent compensation would be paid twice a year and only for pirce increases exceeding a monthly threshold of 1/2 percent (6 percent annual inflation). The fall in revenues from touirsm and the delayed exchange rate adjustment contirbuted to a real fall in total export receipts of 2 percent in 1988 (compared to an 11 percent increase the year before see Table 1). Together with the fall in investment and pirvate consumpiton expenditures (see above) total expenditures dropped and a substantial slowdown in GNP growth took place. This slowdown as well as the moderaiton in wage adjustments accompanying the devaluation must have contirbuted to the fact that 1989 for the first time since 1985 has shown substanital real wage restraint and a fall in unit labour costs especially in manufactuirng (see line 8 of Table 1and line 1 of Table 2). The ongoing recession caused a fall in tax revenues which explains the opening up of a government deficit during 198889. If one applies a cyclical correction for the deficit (cf. Table 1, lines 10 and 11), fiscal policy seems to have kept a restrained stance through 1989. Monetary restraint could accordingly be relaxed. This tendency was further strengthened bymid 1988 as the depthof the domestic recession became apparent. Only towards the end of 3 988, when the speculative foreign exchange wave heightened, did domestic interest rates irse again substantially, though only for a short peirod. From January 1989 onwards the Bank of Israel resumed its downward pres Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilizaiton to Growth p. 3 sure on interest rates (and on the Banks)2 which ifnally dropped to almost inter national levels by the second half of 1989. A similar pattern can be observed for longterm rates which followed the sharp fall in yields on indexed government bonds. The pirvate mortgage market, in particular. which was largely liberalized, exhibited a dramatic fall in real interest rates (from 1112 percent in the previous two years to 56 percent by October 1989). The fall in real interest rates and in unit labour costs tends to have a considerably delayed effect on output supply. Only in the second half of 1989 (after another 4 percent devaluation in June 1989, thus making for a cumulative 18 percent exchange rate adjustment since December 1988) did exportsstart growing again. Domestic consumption demand seems to have gradually picked up at a few months' delay and investments are recovering even more slowly. The year 1989 as a whole has been a second low growth year. The protracted recession, together with a process of restructuirng and labour shedding and an unprecedented increase in labour force participation rates led to a steep irse in unemployment rates from a previous average of 6 percent to over 9 percent in the third quarter of 1989 (see Figure 3). This development in itself temporairly shifted the focus in the political arena to shotrterm employment issues at the possible expense of longerterm reforms. With the recent upturn in economic activity in the second half of 1989, the increase in unemployment seems to have come to a halt* The fall in imports due to the drop in the rate of economic activity and the recovery in expotrs in 1989 have produced a sharp fall in the trade deficit. In fact, for the ifrst time since 1986, the year 1989 has shown a surplus in the current account (to the tune of 1 billion, after inclusion of unrequited foreign exchange transfers). Thus the foreign debt both in absolute terms and relative to GDP (see line 14 of Table 1) has continued its decline since 1985. In retrospect, the protracted slump may have had structural explanations which will be discussed in the next section. The cumulative experience of stabilization in Latin Ameircan countries as well as a closer look at the 1920s hypeirnflation Given the highly concentrated Israeli banking system (5 banking groups comprising the bulk of banking activity) strong direct 'moral suasion' had tobe applied by the Bank of Israel in May 1989. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabiltaiton to Growth p. 4 experience of Germany and Central Europe point to an almost universally observed poststabilization cycle with similar attributes. In the case of Israel, at any rate, this third phase is a manifestation of slow structural adjustments that are in large part endogenous to the poststabilization process, in which the business sector has to recuperate not only from the distortive effects of a 12year cirsis but also from the effect of rising real labour costs, high initial real interest rates and a heavier taxation burden. The next section (II) will accordingly attempt to disentangle, in greater detail, the exogenous and endogenous components of the 198889 slump as well as the rising open unemployment, partly replacing the previously disguised unemployment. Evi dence will be given of the restructuirng process going on in some major sectors of the economy. The subsequent section (III) will take up the main developments in the capital and financial markets. On the one hand, some major reform processes are going on in both markets, following on the improved fiscal position and a determined effort to reduce segmentation and liberalize money markets, and leading to a drastic fall in both long and shortterm interest rates. On the other hand, there has developed a substantial poststabilization overhang of financial entanglements in some major sectors of the real economy, which have required substantial debt relief and re scheduling arrangements in which both the banking sector as well as the government have been involved. Section IV returns to a key macroproblem which has also characterized the earlier stabilization phases the size and timing of exchange rate step adjustments in the faceof irsing, though gradually decelerating, loss of export competitiveness due to real wage overshooting. While there is a definite learning process going on in the labour market as well as in entrepreneuiral response, the problem of government credibility and reputation building has been accentuated due to the effects of more frequent adjustments of the exchange rate necessitated since the 1988 election. The latter discussion naturally leads to another key question to be taken up in section IV why the inflation rate remained seemingly stuck in spite of the sharp recession. While there is no one good explanation for this development (an exper ience which is apparently sharedby. some other recent successful stabilization Bruno and Meirdor: From Stabilization to Growthp. 5 experiences, such as in Chile and Mexico) a number of real structural as well as nominal inertia arguments will be given, not the least of which have to do with the ongoing processof government induced relative pirce and exchangerate adjustments. The last section (V) will try to assess where the economy is heading in the near future. II. Explaining the 198789 Recession: Unanticipated Shock or Inherent Adjustment and Restructuring Process? The recession that had developed in mid 1987 marks the beginning of a new (third) phase after the stabilization program. Until that point in time, economists have considered the stabilization to be a very successful one, both in substantially reducing inflation and in creating only a temporary and slight irse in unemployment.3 Only when the first figures of economic developmentin 1988 were revealed did it become evident that a real slack is building up. The recession had deepened and reached its peak by mid1989, output decreased and unemployment surged to a post1985 record of 9.4 in the second quarter. The question that emerges is whether the recession was caused by exogenous factors that have nothing to do with the stabilization of inflation or whether it is an inherent outcome of the process of the stabilization. We argue that both types of factors were active in building up the slump in the economy. On the one hand there existed exogenous factors of a shortterm nature and in particular the consequences of the events in the West Bank and the Gaza Stirp. These factors generated a slowdown in growth of a temporary nature. On the other hand, one can detect other factors that are connected to the stabilization of inflation and to the way it was implemented. Such factors can be deduced from theo retical exante considerations and some of these can be found in other countires that had undergone similar disinflation processes. This section is organized as follows. First, we present the exogenous factors and try to quantify their effect on output. Then, we point at developments that can be attirbuted to factors stemming from the stabilization and characterize post stabi lization processes which can cause output losses. Lastly we address the question of 3 See among others, Bruno and Piterman (1988) and Cukierman (1988(. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 6 why these losses became evident only with a twoyear lag. Economic developments were also influenced by the interactions between the two above mentioned types of factors. Such interaction deepened and prolonged the recession. The upirsing in the territories that began in December 1987 affected the Israeli economy both through its contractionary effects on the supply of labour to the business sector (mainly concentrated in the construction industry) and on the output demand side (mainly a decline in touirsm and Israeli export to the terirtoires). The 1988 annual report of the Bank of Israel estimated the above mentioned contirbu tions to the business sector's product as a loss of 1.5 percent in 1988. By the same token one can estimate the further, much smaller, effect of the aggravation of the Intifada on the 1989's product and come up with an estimate of 0.3 percent for that year. However, the Intifada with its implications on future developments may have a greater effect through firms' expectations and investment plans: It seems that at least part of the pessimistic perception of firms (as evidenced in the Bank of Israel Company Surveys) and the low investment especially duirng 1989 can be attirbuted to the uncertainty generated by the political situation. Estimating the effects of expectations on investment is of course a very hard task. A likely order of magnitude may be obtained by compairng actual investment with the estimated demand for aggregate net investment in the business sector based on an investment function which involves output levels and increments as well as changes in profitability and real interest rate levels (Lavi, 1989).4 Such compairson yields an investment shortfall which would have caused an outputdemand loss of 0.2 and 0.8 percent, respectively, in 1988 and 1989. < ( During 1988, when inflation remained as high as 16 percent, the public had built expectations for inflation that affected in turn the behaviorof wages and pirces. (See Section IV for a detailed discussion.) The gap that had developed between traded and nontraded goods pirces was not sutstainable and a devaluation became neces sary. We believe that such a devaluation somewhere duirng the first half of 1988 4 This study is based on annual observations for the period 196288. An additional longrun effect on the output supply side is that coming rfom reduced potential capacity due to a very high real interest rates in the prestabilization period. This is estimated by Lavi (1989) at 0.5 percent per annum, but is ignored here. BrunoandMeridor:From Stabilizationto Growthp. 7. would have prevented relative prices rfom further worsening and thus would have prevented part of the exports decline. Around 4 percent change of the real exchange rate erosion duirng the second half of 1988 can be attirbuted to the postponement of the devaluation. By using standard elasticities (see Litvin and Meirdor, 1977) we end up with 4 percent loss in exports, or an annual loss of two percent of exports. This in turn would have accounted for 0.5 percent shortfall in business sector product in 1988.5 The following table sums up the exogenous part of output contraction:6 1988 1989 198889 Direct effect of Intifada 1.5 0.3 1.8 Investment shortfall 0.2 0,8 1,0 Delayed devaluation 0.5 .. 2.2 1.1 3.3 3.9 3.1 7.0 1.7 2.0 3.7 Subtotal Difference between actual and hypothetical)596( growth Unexplained residual ., ..;.... 0.5 The actual shortfall (compairng actual business sector growth rates in Table 2 with a hypothetical 5 percent growth rate each year) amounted to 3.9 (51.1) and 3.1 (51.9) in 1988 and 1989, respectively, thus leaving 1.7 and 2.0 percent (or a cumula tive 4 percentage point) attirbutable to the other, presumably 'endogenous', structural factors. Let us turn to these now. 5 By 1989 relative again... prices changed in the opposite direction and exports eventually started growing ., Ignored here are the mutliplier effects of aggregate demand which given the openness of the economy, are very smail. Likewise we ignore the effect of the postponement of the devaluation on imports, since the elasticity of imports with respect to relative prices is very small. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growthp. 8 Experience from stabilization programs reveals two possible patterns of adjust. ment processes from high to low inflation rates. The first involves an initial cost in terms of output loss because of irgidities in wage and pirce adjustment stemming from initial lack of credibility and/or backward linkages in wage contracts and the like (as Fischer, 1977 and Taylor, 1979). When credibility is built up and expectations adjust, the economy should move to a sustainable growth path, provided, of course, that the fundamentals have been taken care of.7 The second pattern involves a peirod of expansion both in outpfut and consump tion after the first small loss due to irgidities, and then the boom ends up in another recession. Such a pattern was evident in many of the Latin Ameircan countires' stabi lizations of the 1960s and 1980s. Kiguel and Liviatan (1989) (see also Liviatan, 1989) distinguish between the two different patterns, and argue that the latter characteirzes stabilization based on the exchange rate. The recession along this lineof argument isa necessary outcome of the slow buildup of credibility with a pegged exchange rate. In order to build up such credibility the economy has to go through a path of real appreciation. The real appreciation teaches the pirvate sector a lesson: not to increase pirces or wages relying on the authoirties to accommodate by a devaluation. However, this process inevitably results in a loss of output We will argue here that a 'second' recession of some delay can occur also when credibility has been builtup.8 The Israeli stabilization program has so far not succeeded in reducing inflation to the Western level, rather to an annual rate of 1520 percent. Such inflation is not sustainable without realignments in the exchange rate. Indeed, since July 1985 until December 1989 the exchange rate had been cumulatively devalued by about 32 per cent against the dollar (54 percent against the basket of Israeli major trading currencies). Discrete devaluations took place at the beginning of 1987, at the end of 1988 and the beginning of 1989, and (a small one) in June 1989. The real appreciation which was led by wage increases has eroded profitability 7 This stage of adjustment can be rather short as is testified by the orthodox stabilizations of European hyperinlfations in the 1920s (Sargent, 1982). The whole exchange rate and wage formation credibility issue is taken up in greater detail in Section IV. p. 9 Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth in the business sector as can be seen in Table 2. Real labor costs per unit of output have increased by 20 percent from before the stabilization until 1989,9 and in the manufactuirng sector it was even higher (28 percent for the same period). Although the effect of irsing real wages was the most prominent one, aggregate supply and profitability were also negatively affected by two other components: taxation and costs of finance (seeTable 2), to be taken up in turn. Stabilization processes are often followed by a sharp increase in tax collection. Such an increase stems from the disinflation effect (the inverse TanziOlivera effect). In Israel, gross tax collections increased from an average of 43 percent ofGNP during the high inflationary peirod (38 percent in 1984) to 48 percent in 1986. Such an increase encompasses a sharp increase inboth direct effective tax rates and indirect ones. Direct effective rates on the business sector increased from a low rate of 18.4 percent during 1984 (25 on average duirng 19821984) to a peak of 33.3 in 1986 and stayed more or less stable ever since. The sharp increase in indirect rates from 4 percent of GNP in 19801984 to 10 percent in 19861988 should be divided between ifrms and households but it too contirbuted to the squeeze in firms9 profitability. The high effective rates that are the outcome of statutory rates set duirng the inflationary peirod, (which at the time were translated intolower effective rates due to the inherent lags) became "too" high (from a growth inducement point of view) and^are now subject to a reduction.10 The development of interest rates completes the profitability picture. High real interest rates are a common feature of post stabilization peirods. They either stem from a deliberately tight monetary policy to supportthe disinflation process, from an unintentional outcome of the interaction between expected and actual inflation or from the problematic situation of conducting monetary policy duirng disinflation 9 We compare the average real labor cost per unit of output during 198284 to an estimate of the labor cost in 1989. The gap between real age increases and productivity growth has, however, fallen gradually between 1986 and 1988(the annual figures being, respectively, 6, 4 and 1 percent). In 1989 real unit wage costs have actually faiien. Thus a gradual learning process has occurred. See also Section IV. Indeed, the Finance Ministry is now reducing company taxes and is also extending the reform in income taxation, at the cost of a Wo higher Value Added Tax. The more general longrun problem of the high tax burden can, of course, only be handled through a protracted decrease in the share of public expenditure in GNP. * Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 10 peirods.11 Moreover, high interest rates are an important ingredient of monetary policy that supports a fixed exchange rate facing occasional and temporary speculative attacks. Real interest rates which were record high duirng the first few months after the July 1985 stabilization decreased later on but remained at a high level (the marginal real rate was about 35 percent on average during 19861987). Since 1988 these rates came down significantly and by mid1989 they were not much higher than in the industiralized countires. However, the difficulties arising from the 5 year cumulative financial burden are far more marked than the mere effect on production costs. While they were not the dominant cause of financial cirsis they did contirbute to the financial difficulties in a number of sectors. It should be stressed that such high rates did not prevailin all the sectors. Manufactuirng, for example, faced relatively lower rates due to a large component of subsidized export credit. For a detailed discussion of financial issues, seethe next section (III). Lastly we come to the most significant development that has been taking place in the business sector since stabilization: the structural adjustments and the forced rise in efficiency (through restructuirng and labour shedding) in face of the new macroeconomic environment. The July 1985 program dramatically changed the economic environment in Israel. The drastic decline in inflation called for a pattern of firm conduct that is very different from that prevailing before. During the inflationary era firms could overinvest (due to cheap government credit) and also easily ignore inefifcient real activities. The process of high inflation enables firms to achieve high profits mainly through successful financial manipulation. Low inflation brought to light a set of real inefficiencies necessitating a structural adjustment. Moreover, the government's new attitude towards fiscal balance meant not only a reduction in current public activities and expenditures, but also a sharp decline in'the government's willingness to bail out unsuccessful pirvate firms,12 thus gradually forcing firms to take responsibility for their own activities. Although on a macro level there is so far only slight evidence of 11 See Fischer (1986) and Bruno and Piterman (1988(. 1Z Only in major financial crises such as in the agircultural sector did the government step in. See Section Ill below. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilizaiton to Growth p. 11 the efifciency process, on the disaggregated level of subbranches and some major conglomerates we can distinguish a substantial real productivity increase after 1986. Table 3 presents productivity figures for the total business sector as well as for the manufacturing sector. We have chosen to analyze the manufacturing sector as it represents about 1/3 of the business sector, and because its data are the most readily available. In the aggregate business sector there is an increase in productivity after the stabilization but it disappears duirng 1988 and 1989. In the total manufacturing sector we can note the increase in productivity already in 1989, some of its sub branches are particularly marked by higher rates and in two major conglomerates (the trade union owned Koor industries and in the Israel Aircraft Industry) which encompass 16 percent of manufacturing we can trace the accelerated increase in productivity throughout the peirod 19861989. The case of the Israel Aircraft Industry (I.A.I.) is of particular interest since the cancellation of the Lavi aircraft project at the end of 1987, which was a very painful government decision taken after a bitter debate, signalled a major turning point in government policy. LA.I. subsequently fired 5,000 of its 21*000 employees but managed to recover its 1986 output by the end of 1989 while the share of exports in total output increased from 60 percent to 80 percent. Koor reduced its 1985 work force of 34,000 by over 10,000 while increasingits productivity by 20 percent over the peirod 198689. The reduction in employment of these two conglomerates alone accounts for almost half of the total reduction in manufactuirng employment during 198789 (which amounted to 10 percent Figure 9 see Table 3). presents the number of bankruptcies and liquidations13 during the last few years. It shows the increases after the disinflation andthe. following decrease duirng 19861987. It also demonstrates the sharp irse in 19881989. It seems that the firms' response to the changes that followed the stabilization vaired among different sectors, subbranches and individual ifrms. On the one hand, many ifrms got into major difficulties that in certain cases necessitated bankruptcy proceedings or major restructuirng using mass ifirng of labour.14 On the other hand, the average ifgures 13 The data collected here do not distinguish between the size of different ifrms. 14 We have data suggesting that the number of firms in difficulties increases sharply, but do not present it here since its method of estimation is somewhat inconsistent over time. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 12 imply that other firms were at the same time expanding both their employment and output. The above mentioned restructuirng process has very little to do with the slow credibility buildup and the difficulties airsing rfom real appreciation. Moreover, the adjustment to other changes such as the increase in effective tax rates and high interest rates are also independent of the credibility issue. Furthermore, other countires whose stabilizations have been very successful and achieved credibility rather fast had also gone through a structural change causing a recession, which usually lagged a couple of years after the disinflation stage. Each country has its specific restructuring features resulting from the specific change in the macro conditions that accompanied the stabilization programs. Garber (1982), for example, has pointed out the emergence of a sharp recession in Germany two years after the 1923 stabilization. In May 1925 output began to slow down, the number of bankrupt cies surged, and unemployment expanded.15 In 1920s Germany, unlike Israel, infla tion declined instantaneously and the exchange rate remained unchanged for a long peirod with no substantial real appreciation (lack of inflationary inertia could be a major factor). Similar recessions were recorded in other European stabilizations.16 The extent of financial dififculties in Israel became apparent only gradually, At the ifrst stage after disinflation, vairous ifrms had managed to rerfain rfom major changes and adjustments by relying on more and more credit (see Piterman, 1989).17 It may be the case that some of them were expecting government help at some point in time and the abstention rfom intervention which would have been typical in the 1970s became apparent only with the passage of time. For a more extensive discus sion see section III. On top of the above mentioned factors, it seems that in the Israeli case there 15 Between May 1925 and the low pointof April 1926 industrial production dropped 17 percent and the unemployment rate rose from 3.5 to over 20 percent [see Garber (1982), Tables VIII and X]. 16 In Austria and Poland of the 1920s we find a similar recession a few years atfer the successful stabilization [see Wicker (1986)]. See also Siklos (1989) for Hungary in the 1940s. 17 Koor industries, for example, used an illfated foreign loan of over $100 million (lfoated through Drexel Burnham at over 13 percent interest) only to postpone its crisis from; 1986 to 1988. In spite of considerable progress in output and employment restructuirng Koor has not yet recovered from its financial difficulties. Brunoand Meridor: From Stabilization to Growthp. 13 prevailed favourable conditions during 19861987 both internally and externally that temporairly postponed the need for the restructuring. The consumption boom duirng this peirod accelerated domestic demand on the one hand and on the other hand, there has been an increase in foreign demand both due to an acceleration in world trade and a change in the exchange rate of the dollar against the European cur rencies in a way that made Israeli exports to Europe the major market more competitive. The external conditions are of course exogenous but the internal development in consumption demand is often mentioned as characterizing poststabilization peirods. Kiguel and liviatan (1989) attirbute this phenomenon to an initial lack of credibility of the program. They view the consumption increase as advanced pur chases to forestall the bad times expected to come in the immediate future. We would argue that the consumption surge can be given a different and more optimistic interpretation. When a stabilization program succeeds in correcting fundamental factors which were out of control before, there will be an increase in perceived permanent incomeaird wealth which in turn will manifest itself in an increase of both consumption and investment. It seems that in the Israeli case the signs of success at the beginning of 1986, i.e., the dramatic decline of inflation, the elimination of the government deficit and the other reforms that were on the agenda to be implemented in the near future were responsible for the increase in current consumption (excluding nondurables), and the increase in investment both during 1986 and the first half of 1987. Part of the increase in consumption and investment could also be a response to a cyclical downturn which started already in October 1983. However, in the second half of 1987 and the beginning of 1988 negative signs began to show, some of them related to the postponed effects of the stabilization and some of them due to the political developments.18 There followed a decline in consumption, to a smaller extent in current consumption and a larger decline in nondurables (which tend to fluctuate more anyway). Finally, let us repeat the observation made in the previous section on the steep irse in unemployment which lagged behind the drop in output growth. This was the .1 o It is also possible that the public realized that the government was not as determined as before to proceed with the planned reforms, as the election peirod was approaching. Bruno and Meirdor: From Stabilization to Growth . p. 14 combined effect of the labourshedding process as well as an unprecedented increase in labour participation rates. m. Financial Factors in the Stabilization and Restructuirng Process The period since 1985 has witnessed considerable changes in the real cost, compo sition and financial burden of credit in the economy.19 As Table 5 shows average real shortterm interest rates were quite high both before and shortly after stabi lization, particularly on free market credit whose share has been growing steadily.20 While there was quite a sharp drop in 1986, real rates climbed quite sharply in 1987 (due to considerable monetary restraint that temporairly accompanied the January 1987 devaluation) and then came down again in 1988 and 1989, with the gradual relaxation of monetary restraint. By 1989 both nominal and real rates have come down drastically. As columns (4) and (5) of Table 5 show, development of the real cost of credit differed across sectors in the economy with Agirculture facing a much steeper irse than the average for the economy the reverse being the case for the Manufactuirng sector [compare 1985 or 1987 with 1983 in col. (1), (4), (5)]. Comparison of the interest rates on directed credit as compared id the free market rate [col. (2) and (3)] and analysis of the differential change that has taken place in the share of free credit by sector [col. (6) to (8)] provide an explanation of this development. Piror to 1985 both Agirculture and Manufactuirng as well as Services and Trade (not shown here) were allotted substantial amounts of credit at low (negative real) interest rates from the public purse, for both export as well as domestic consumption use. Since 1985 only production for exports has continued to obtain credit at subsidized rates while the subsidy on this type of credit has also been substantially cut. With Manufacturing being a relatively more exportbased sector (nearly 50 percent of its output is 19 For analysis of the first phase see Bruno and Piterman (1988). For a more detailed and updated analysis of financial factors in the stabilization process see also Piterman (1989). M Additional disaggregation into Shekel and foreignexchangelinked credit shows particularly high real interest rates right after stabilization an average rate of 82 percent in the second half of 1985. (See Bank of Israel, Annual Report 1988, Table VIII9.( Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growthp. 15 exported compared to only 2025 percent for Agirculture), both its relative reliance on directed credit has been higher and the drop in its share has been less than for Agirculture. The real interest burden on a sector is the product of the interest rate and the ratio of credit to output. As col. (9) to (11) show this ratio has been fairly stable over time both for Manufacturing and for the economy as a whole but has risen steeply in Agirculture (while for Services and Trade, not shown here, it has fallen steadily after stabilization, presumably due to economies in inventory requirements). In Agirculture, more than in Manufactuirng, there has been a long term increase in the credit to output ratio since the early 1970s, one of the main results of inflationary distortions in the economy. Excessive investments in the 1970s were financed by cheap longterm credit (at highly negative real interest rates21) rather than from own accumulated profits which in turn were squandered on alternative current uses (including pirvate consumption). By the beginning of the 1980s the government stopped the practice of handing out unindexed loans. With the 1985 stabilization public longterm lending was virtually stopped. While the growth in net real capital stock in Agirculture, for example, came to a halt already in the early 1980s the existing debt had to be recycled increasingly in the form of shortterm debt at high real interest rates, a familiar 1970s phenomenon reminiscent of the third world debt problem. The financial leverage ratio of total outstanding debt to the net capital stock in Agirculture rose over the 1970s from around 20 percent to 50 percent and subsequently increased to reach 90 percent by 1987 [see Kislev et at, 1989). At the first stage of stabilization the mere sharp reduction in nominal interest rates creates a onetime automatic 'debtrescheduling' effect coming from the fall in the relative interest payment burden or the irse in the average 'loan repayment peirod'.22 But once this adjustment has been made, the real financial burden starts 21 Litvin and Meirdor (1983) have estimated the average rate for the 1970s to be minus 17 percent, which implies a grantequivalent amounting to one half of investment. 22 יAs recently pointed out by Piterman (1989): On the assumption that the principal is roiled over while interest payments arc paid on a current basis the average repayment peirod of shortterm debt (i.e., the ratio of pirncipal to the interest rate) rose from 5.5 months in the first half of 1985 to 10.6 in the second half and to 31.9 in 1986. It has stayed more or less the same in 1988 (29.2 months). In other words this interest rate illusion is a onetime effect. Such 'rescheduling' can be effective in the long run only if the real rate of interest is lower than the proift rate. Bruno and Meirdor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 16 to bite. In agriculture the ifrst major ifnancial crisis occurred in the Moshav (cooperative) movement, and subsequently in the two biggest Kibbutz (collective) movements. Both types of organizations have so far been marked by highly diffused mutual responsibility for individual credit creation. In the (cooperative) Moshav centralized credit and bookkeeping arrangements relieved the burden of strict accountability from the individual farming unit. In the Kibbutz movement this type of a 'soft budget constraint' marked the relationship of individual Kibbutzim (collectives) to the central bodies of the whole umbrella movement which got its funds rfom the government or the banks. In the Kibbutz movement, the internal mutual reliance systems helped to delay the crisis but also magniifed the size of the cumulative debt. This reached an order of magnitude of more than 10 percent of GNP while their share of GNP is only half of that25 In both cases the government participated in a debtrelief and debt rescheduling scheme worked out jointly with the banks and the respective borrowers. The Moshav movement debt amounted to 1 billion dollars, of which 40 percent was to be wirtten off by the banks and vairous other agencies and the rest to be re scheduled pirmairly by the government. This scheme is still being gradually imple mented on an individual Moshav basis. The Kibbutz debt relief program finally signed only recently involves a 1 billion dollar wirteoff, twothirdsof which was taken up by the banks and one third is taken up by the government. In addition 1.5 billion dollars will be rescheduled through government floating of bonds. The remaining 1.5 billion is borne by the Kibbutz movement which has also undertaken to take severe internal restraining measures. Part of the program involved a radical change in the mutual reliance system and a shift to individual Kibbutz financial planning with a link to a commercial bank which will henceforth enforce the control of credit. We have concentrated our discussion on agirculture, but it is important to stress that some restructuirng and debt rescheduling schemes between banks and enter pirses have taken place with the manufactuirng sector, the most marked one being a The share of interest rates that are above 'normal' longterm rates in the increase of the debt between 1984 and 1988 is estimated to beonly 30 percent, while the rest is to be ascribed to past investments (which in part have to be wirtten off) and collective consumption uses (such as improved housing conditions). It should be pointed out that the Kibbutz movement deirves only 45 percent of its income from agirculture, the rest coming from manufactuirng and services. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilizaiton to Growthp. the case of the abovementioned Histadrut (tradeunion) 17 owned Koor industrial conglomerate. Here, too, the government participated in the recovery program but so far only with a relativelysmall component of 50 million dollars. We end this section with a biref mention of the reform process that has been taking place in the financial markets in recent years. The process of disinflation increased the relative demand for unindexed shortterm assets whose share in total pirvate assets quadrupled during the period 198487. This in itself increased the liquidity of the banking system since the liquidity (reserve) ratios on unlinked assets were lower than on other assets. The drop in the government deficit also enabled a substantial increase in domestic credit expansion, which took place through a sharp reduction as well as unification of mandatory liquidity ratios on unlinked assets (see Table 6).u This process as well as a parallel relaxation of limitations on foreign exchange linked credit, have brought about the reduction in interest rates. Similar developments have taken place in the capital market. Mandatory reserves on long term linked assets traditionally had to be invested in longterm government bonds or nonmarketable government deposits. Capital market reform has taken the form of a reduction, since 1987, in these reserve ratios, a gradual increase in the marketability of the domestic national debt25 and the opening up ofthe capital market to the free floating of pirvate bond issues. The real yields on government secuirties havedropped sharply, from 67 percent in 1985 to below 2 percent in 1989, while a parallel process has taken place in the cost of pirvate bond issues. Likewise the market for mortgages has been opened up and as a result the real cost of mortgages has halved, from 1142 percent in 1987 to 56 percent in 1989. While this liberalization and reform process in the financial markets is not yet complete, the economy has come quite a long way since 1985. The real cost of capital is now much closer to international levels. It also seems that debt wirteoffs26 and reschedulings have passed their peak. The table and discussion are based on Piterman (1989). ■'' ^ The share of marketable bonds in the total new government indexed bond issues has increases from 4 percent in 1984 to 63 percent in 1988 [see BenBassat (1989)]. The substantial writeoffs have eliminated proifts in the commercial banks rate for 1989 is likely to remain low at 4 percent on average. in 1988. The proift Bruno and Meirdo.r From Stabilization to Growth p. 18 IV. Inlfation and the WageExchange Rate Policy Game The relatively low inflation attained in consequence of the stabilization program was maintained at a more or less stable rate, through 19861989, thus consolidating one principle achievement of the program. However, no real further progress was made in closing the gap between domestic pirce inflation and that prevailing in the Western economies. While CPI inflation remained more or less the same, other pirces, in particular wages and the exchange rate behaved differently. During the last four years wages increased at much higher rates causing the real wage to cumulatively increase by about 30 percent and thus substantially reducing profitability. Only during 1989 when unemployment reached 9.5 percent do we see a turning point: wages increased at a lower rate than pirces, resulting in a mild reduction in real wages and a more substantial one relative to labour productivity. (See Figure 4.) As for the exchange rate, with the July 1985 Program a stable exchange rate regime was announced. However, no absolute commitment to an exchange rate peg was made, and duirng the last four years a number of devaluations took place.27 At the beginning of 1987 a devaluation was carired out, at the end of 1988 there was another (twostep) devaluation and finally a small one in June 1989. Table 7 shows the average change in the exchange rate over the peirod. In particular, it demon strates the varying behavior over time. Table 7 presents data for the inflation rates, breaking down the consumer pirce index into tradable and nontradable goods and services. The rate of change of nontraded goods pirces was much higher, 25 percent on average per year and slightly decreasing over time, while the inflation of traded goods remained more stable at about 12 percent per year independent of the timing of the devaluations. This is one measure28 of the decline in the comparative advantage of production for exports From the introduction of the stabilization program until August 1986, the exchange rate remained fixed against the dollar resulting in an unplanned depreciation of the shekel against a wider basketof currencies. Therefore, since August 1986 the exchange rate was pegged to a basket of Israel's pirncipal trading countries' currencies. ^ This index relates only to CPI, whereas a more adequate index should relate to the GDP deflator. However, we do not have a disaggregationof GDP prices to tradables and nontradables. For an alternative indicator of unit labor costs, see Table 1. It rose 9.5 percent in 1988 and subsequently declined 4 percent in 1989. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilizaiton to Growth p. 19 (and import substitutes) largely accounting for the poor export performance in 1988 (see section II). Two intirguing questions emerge: (1) Why did the inflation rate remain seemingly stuck throughout the last four years in spite of the varying conditions? In particular, exchange rate behavior vaired duirng this peirod, and the macro conditions differed over time: an expansion of aggregate demand in the first two years and a recession in the last two. (2) Why did wages increase so much, was it an unintentional overshooting reflecting mistakes of inflationary expectationsof workers and employers? or was it,rather, an exogenous intentional increase and if so what could be the reason? It seems that these questions are related and at least part of the answer to both of them lies in the roleof expectations. We believe that inlfationary expectations play an important role in the explanations of the'wageexchangeratepirce' complex. They affect wage behavior through their role in wage contract negotiations and they also affect the pirce setting mechanism in particular for nontraded goods and services.29 Tradable goods and services areless affected by expectations since competition is probably higher in that sector, in spite of impediments to free imports. The rate of inflation can be viewed as the outcome of a 'game' played by the public 'against' the government.30 The rules of the game allow for government dec larations with regards to its future policy, in particular the exchange rate when the economy operates under a pegged exchange rate regime. The public assesses the ere dibility of these declarations and forms its inflationary expectations accordingly. The expectations will in turn affect the setting of pirces and the negotiations for wage contracts, while the government has to assess this behavior and to determine its future policy. It should be noted that such a game does not determine relaitve pirces, rather the average inflation rate itself, while the former are related to macro conditions and the like. However, as expeirence and theory show, in the wake of exchange rate based stabilizations such a game will usually result in a real appreciation as government ~ Those that are uncontrolled by the govenrment. ^ See for example Cukierman (1988) and Horn and Persson (1988(. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 20 expectation and credibility are gradually built up. We believe that such a model is appropirate in explaining the Israeli inflation, though we are aware that this is a mere hypothesis. We will try in what follows to support it with a few theoretical considera tions and some empirical evidence. Let us now present the background for this game after the July 1985 stabilization program. A major component was the government declared policy with regards to the exchange rate. With the implementation of the stabilization program, a stable exchange rate was announced. However, there was no stirct commitment to a fixed exchange rate. On the contrary, the behavior of the exchange rate was tied to future development in wages, i.e., it was announced that the exchange rate will not remain absolutely fixed if wages do not behave "properly." Indeed, after the 1986's upsurge in real wages a devaluation was carired out in January 1987. The devaluation was part of a broader policy package involving an agreed wage concession (see Bruno and Piterman, 1988). After January 1987, a somewhat tighter announcement was made stating that devaluations would not automatically accommodate to future wage increases (see The National Budget 1988); however it1 was understood that realign ment, though rare, would occur if the circumstances (e.g. sharp loss of competitive ness) necessitated such action. The idea of the Bank of Israel was to gradually lengthen the peirods between step alignments and reduce the size of devaluations until nominal wages and pirces stabilize. Rather than adopt an extreme onceandforall pegged exchange rate stance and at the same time avoid the other extreme image of automatic accommodation to wage behavior, such intermediate strategy was expected to induce wage discipline through the gradual buildup of government credibility and reputation. According to this scheme the Bank of Israel advocated another alignment of 67 percent in March 1988, 14 months after the preceding one. However, with the coming election, the Minister of Finance adopted a wait and see attitude. Unfortunately this ambiguous policy stance, fell between two stools at no stage duirng most of 1988 was it made clear to the business sector that there would be no devaluation. At the same time no alignment was in fact made until after the election, in December 1988, 23 months after the previous alignment, and only after very heavy capital outflows. The postponement dictated this time a larger devaluation than in January 1987, thus the Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 21 previously planned gradualist exchange rate adjustment scheme was not followed, creating a setback to the credibility of exchange rate announcements. In January 1989 a ±3 percent band around the new exchange rate was intro duced to enable greater flexibility for monetary policy. That, too, may have been misinterpreted by the strong and rather vocal exportlobby to signal a more flexible exportoriented exchange rate policy. Moreover, there were inconsistent announce ments by various policy makers, since some advocated more flexibi'hty and others advocated a harder stance, makingthe public's task in evaluating the government intentions even more dififcult. A large part of the reason for the inconsistency of declarations over time lies in the underlying differencesof views among policy makers (and their pirvate advisors). There is an obvious conflict between the key role of a stable nominal exchange rate as a nominal anchor and between the timehonored pledge to keep the real exchange rate from appredating. The first got a much larger weight by the Bank of Israel while the second has usually directed the exporters' lobby and gained a greater weight with the Ministry of Finance. There are other factors, besides the exchange rate, in government's po'hcy and actions that affect the process of expectations and credibility formation In particular, fundamentals such as the budget deficit or government willingness to bail out firms in dififculties. Indeed, since July 1985 government policy with regards to such fundamentals has changed considerably. Another important factor affecting infla tionary expectations is government's actions with regards to subsidy cuts and to other prices under its control. After the implementation of the program and until the end of 1988 the government refrained from pushing up those pirces, and their average annual increases were lower than the average inflation. However, since January 1989, their rates have exceeded other rates of change (excluding housing, see Table 8a).31 After the implementationof the stabilization program, the public assessed the new conditions and formed its new inflationary expectations. It seems that funda mental factors and the evaluation of government's declarations and actions together 31 In Israel controlled prices encompass a fifth of the CPt index. However, empirical studies suggest that they have a significant signaling effect [seeMelnick (1989)]. Moreover, when a budget deficit emerges there is a strong internal political incentive to cut subsidies rather than get into a ifght with individual ministries over a cut in their share of the expenditure pie. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 22 . with the tight monetary policy were sufifcient in birnging inlfation down to about 20 percent but no less.32 Thus helping keep inlfationary expectations at about the same level. Vairous studies33 suggest that,a major element in determining expectations may be lagged inflation, thus indicating that the process of expectation formation has a partial adjustment element. Since inlfation remained more or less stable, it also had a reinforcing stabilizing effect on expectations. A moderate inlfation rate that remains more or less stable after a stabilization program, is not a unique Israeli phenomenon, rather it is sharedby other recent successful stabilization expeirences, such as in Chile and Mexico there too a pegged exchange rate regime had been implemented with stabilization. It seems that in those countires too the inlfation rate can be the outcome of a similar game along which the credibility of the government is tested and inlfationary expectations adjust gradually (see Kiguel and Liviatan,1989). Only after full credibility is achieved, in particular . when fundamental factors are consistent with a fixed exchange rate with no align ments, will inlfationary expectations converge to Western rates. The steady and gradual decrease in velocity of circulation of deposits (see Figure 10) suggests that the credibility build up was rather slow and the tightening of declarations after 1987 together with other fundamental government policies con tirbuted to this trend. However, the new declaration of January 1989by the new Finance Minister and the apparent shift in targets (more export oirented than before, resulting in an additional small realignment in June 1989 and a different attitude towards controlled pirces) may have hampered credibility of the exchange rate as a nominal anchor. The expectations argument and the slow credibility buildup can only partially explain why wages increased as much as they did duirng the peirod 19861988. Since the exchange rate policy declared in July 1985 signalled thatif wages were to increase excessively, a realignment would sooner or later take place, it could very well be that 32 As often mentioned [see Bruno and Piterman (1988)] it may very well be that the unplanned devaluation that took place duirng the ifrst half of 1986 (due to the pegging of the shekel to the dollar) caused inflation to go down to 20 percent and not to a lower rate. 33 See, for example, Gottlieb et al. (1985) and Offenbacher (1985(. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 23 ifrms did yield to workers' demands more than they would have had the declaration been a somewhat 'harder' one.34 Indeed, after the tighter declaration of January 1987 there were lower nominal wage hikes although higher than pirce increases. One could also interpret the fall in real wages in 1989 as a sign that the gradual learning process is ifnally beginning to bear fruit. In spite of the previous argument the explanation of nominal wage behavior since 1987 remains incomplete. An additional explanation of the real wage surge has to do with institutional structure of wage contracts in Israel on the one hand and the restructuring process on the other hand. The institutional factors include economy wide arrangements, such as acrosstheboard wage increases stimulated by wage hikes in the large public sector (see Figure 4),^ too slow an adjustment in COLA arrangements or the minimum wage law which compelled ailing ifrms to raise wages above the level warranted by market forces. The restructuirng process together with downward irgidities in the labor market make it dififcult to reduce wages in ifrms that have run into dififculties whereas the ifrms that are doing ifne can increase real wage according to productivity. The two together result in a ratchetlike increase in average wages.36 We end this section pointing out one positive feature of the inflation proifle that seems to be emerging from the data for 1989. If we exclude the housing sector from the pirce index, the wage and pirce increases in nontraded goods and services seem to be gradually converging towards that of tradable goods.37 The latter has been The role of govenrments' tying their hands as in the European Monetary System (EMS), has certainly helped birng about a faster convergenceof inlfation in traditionally inflationprone European countries (Italy, France). It is important to note that in that case,too, substantial real appreciation took place and the process of inflation convergence took several years. See Giavazzi and Giovannini (1989). ^ For example, the LAI which ran into trouble in 1987 was forced to increase wages due to insti tutional arrangements (in particular, the link between the I.A.I.'s wages and the public sector wage agreements). For a more detailed analysis of wage policy and wage behaviour duirng the first and second phase of the disinlfation see Artstein and Sussman (1988). The relative convergence of wages can be seen in Table 7 by compairng wages in the service and commerce industires with the total for the business sector. For prices compare, for example, columns (3) and (5) in Table 8. The absolute gap between the two has been gradually falling from about 20 percent in 198687 to 15, then 10 and 6 percent by the third quarter of 1989. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth more or less stable for the last three years, p. 24 in spite of the irregularity of devaluations. These developments suggest that with an ongoing slack in the labor market, the inflation rate, outside of the housing sector, is possibly heading downwards, provided controlled goods prices are kept within the bounds of average inflation. However, housing prices are most likely to continue rising at higher rates due to the immi gration wave from the Soviet Union. The role of controlled prices and of housing in fact suggest room for another incomes policy package that will ensure wage modera tion. This could be assured, for example, by suspension of housing pirce increases from compensations according to COLA agreements,on the one hand, and on the other hand the government adopting a stronger position on the exchange rate and other controlled pirces.38 V. What Lies Ahead? We have discussed in great detail the causes of the Israeli recession duirng the last two years and emphasized that it can at least in part be attirbuted to the restructuirng process that the economy is undergoing. In this concluding section we will try to assess where the economy is heading in the near future. The most recent economic indicators suggest that somewhere around the third quarter of 1989 the economy started very slowly to move out of the depth of the recent recession. There are good reasons to believe that 1990 will be a year of considerably higher activity, estimates ranging from3to 5 percent growth in the. business sector. A higher growth rate could be expected on the basis of the improved aggregate supply conditions the sharp reduction in real interest rates and the reduction in per unit labour costs. The latter trend could continue given the slack in the labour market. To this one should add a likely cyclical upturn in pirvate con sumption and housing demand, as well as a planned increase of investment in * We assume that the exchange rate will remain the main nominal anchor in the near future. This assumption is based on our strong belief that the exchange rate is a better anchor for the Israeli economy than traditional monetary aggregates which tend to be less stable, due to Israel's openness, on the one hand, and the segmentation in the financial markets, on the other hand. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 25 infrastructure, a longneglected area. On top of the improved supply and demand conditions there is an important additional factor an increasing wave of immigrants from the Soviet Union. The rate of immigration has recently jumped to 3,000 per month. This rate is likely to continue and possibly accelerate. Past expeirence has shown that in the first yearof absorption an immigrant contributes mainly to a net increase in aggregate demand (mainly for housing) and only later participates in the increased supply to the labour market. A large immigration wave is about to stimulate economic activity. However, such higher Tate of activity may be a temporary phenomenon and does by no means ensure move ment to sustainable growth. The latter depends on the continued restructuring process as well as systematic pursuit of the various reforms that have been mentioned not the least of which has to do with a further cut in the size of government expendi ture and the extent of its involvement in the economy. One problem that may still occupy policy makers' (and politicians') minds is the recent sharp increase in unemployment. While its increase may have come to a halt, a relatively high level of unemployment is likely to linger on as the increased output growth may well be accompanied by a substantial increase in productivityand there are structural reasons that are likely to remain in the future (e.g. the irse in participation rates due to entry of the baby boom's baby in the labour force and other reasons for unemployment mentioned in Section IV that are likely to be removed only slowly). ■/ Another issue that has already emerged in 1989 and is likely to intensify with the advent of large immigration is the pressure on the housing market. While conditions exist for a further reduction in inflation in the rest of the economy, acceleration of housing pirces, given present COLA agreements on wages, may causean upward push to wages and pirces if proper moderating measures are not undertaken. In one major respect it should be easier to birng down inflation further and that is the more comfortable foreign exchange position that Israel finds itself in now. The external debt/GDP ratio has been falling consistently since 1985 (see Table 1). Moreover the current account has shown a surplus in 1989 after two years of a slight deficit, and under reasonable assumptions is likely to remain in the black also in 1990 and 1991. (The probable large immigration wave is about to temporarily worsen the Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 26 foreign currency exchange position before causing an increase in output.) Together with the ongoing slack in the labour market it suggests that a tougher stand on exchange rate stability may be less irsky now. A surplus on the current account has another angle to it. It imp'hes, because of the lower trade balance, that total domestic savings now exceed investments which in turn have fallen substantially duirng the 1980s from around 27 percent of GNP on average duirng the 1960s and the 1970s to 22 percent during 198084 and 18.5 duirng 198588. An important indicator of sustainable growth is the level of new capital forma tion taking place so as to ensure that capacity at least keeps up with output growth. For some time,1 output can draw up on unutilized capacity, but ultimately, the surest guarantee of renewed growth is a suitable flow of investment spurred by the producer's own profit incentives and not by excessive government support, as was the case in the 1970s. . The aging of capital stock, part of which is now obsolete, indicates the existence of an even more seirous problem in terms of net investment (after discards). This is even more disturbing in view of the fact that technological innovation usually gets embodiedin new tangible capital formation. A rough estimate of the gross investment necessary for capital stock to keep pace with a 56 percent in growth in business sector GDP suggests that within the space of a few years, investment should irse from its current level of 18.5 percent to at least 2123 percent of GNP. What is holding back investment today? In the past, it could be argued that limitations oh domestic savings and on foreign borrowing were the effective limits on investment. This, we have seen, is no longer the case. Nor do the present lower rates of interest constitute ahinderance to new investments. The reasons for the sustained lower rate of investment in the business sector has to do with the low profitability and higher effective tax rates already mentioned (see section II and Table 3) as well as with economic and political uncertainty. There has recently been a surge of interest on part of some large foreign investors but so far it has taken the form of financial portfolio investments rather than in new real capacity buildup. Renewed economic activity and improved profitability are likely to birng about an endogenous increase in investment but that still remains to be seen. . Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 27 References Artstein, Yael and Zvi Sussman (1988). "Wage Policy During Disinlfation: The Israeli Stabilization Program of 1985," Bank of Israel, Research Department, Discussion Paper No. 88.07. Bank of Israel 11988). A Plan for the Resumption of Growth and the Loweirngof Inflation, Jerusalem (Hebrew). BenBassat, Avraham (1989). "Capital Market Reform, Goals and First Results," Bank of Israel, Research Department, Discussion Paper No. 89.08.. BenBassat, Idit (1989). "Price Indexes for Tardable and Nontradable Goods," Bank of Israel, Research Department, Discussion Paper No. 89.11. BenRawe, Yoram (1989). "The Interest Rate Burdenof Short Term Credit on Industires, 19831988," Bank of Israel, Research Department, Discussion Paper No. 89.07. Bruno, Michael (1989). "Israel's Crisis and Economic Reform: A Histoircal Perspective," N.B.ER. Working Paper No. 3075. and Sylvia Piterman (1988). "Israel's Stabilization: A Two Years' Review," in Inflation j Stabilization, Bruno et al (eds.), pp. 147. Cukierman, Alex (1988). "The End of the High Israeli Inflation An Expeirment in Heterodox Stabilization," in J/i/ofiron Sattfj/izairon, Bruno et a£ (eds.), pp. 4894. Fischer, Stanley (1977). "Long Term Contracts, Rational Expectations, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule," Journalof Political Economy, 85, (No. 1, February), pp. 191205. (1986). "Exchange Rate Versus Money Target in Disinflation," in Indexing, Inflation and Economic Policy, Fischer (ed.), MIT Press. Garber, Peter M. (1982). Transition from Inflation to Pirce Stability," in CarnegieRochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 16, pp. 1142. Giavazzi, Francesco and Alberto Giovannini (1989). Limited Exchange Rate Flexibility: The European Monetary System (Cambirdge: The MIT Press), Chapters 1, 2. Gottlieb, Daniel, Rafi Melnick and Sylvia Piterman (1985). "Inflationary Expectations in Israel: A Multiple Indicators Approach," Journalof Business <Sc Economic Statistics, 3 (No. 2, April), pp. 11217. Horn, Henirk and Torston Persson (1987). "Exchange Rate Policy, Wage Formation and Credibility," European Economic Review, 32 (No. 8), pp. 162136. Kiguel, Miguel A. and Nissan Liviatan (1988). "Inlfationary Rigidities and Orthodox Stabilization Policies: Lessons from Latin Ameirca," The World Bank Economic Review, 2 (No. 3, September), pp. 27398. (1989). "The Business Cycle Associated with Exchange Rate Based Stabilization," mimeo. Kislev, Yoav, Zvi Lerman and Pinhas Zusman (1989). "Expeirence with Credit Cooperatives in Israeli Agirculture," The Center for Agircultural Economic Research Working Paper 8902. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 28 Lavi, Yaacov (1989). "Interest Rate Effect on Investment in Israel: 19621988," Bank of Israel, Research Department, Discussion Paper No. 89.08. Litvin, Uri and Leora Meridor (1977). "Policy Measures and Their Effect on Exports and Real Exchange Rates,", in Israel Economic Papers, N. Halevi and Y. Kop (eds.). (1983). "The Grant Equivalent of Subsidized Investment in Israel," Bankof Israel Economic Review, No. 54 (April), pp. 530. Liviatan, Nissan (1989). "Israel's Stabilization Cycle with Some Reference to Latin American Expeirence," mimeo. Melnick, Raif (1989). "Forecasting Short Run Inflation in Israel 198387: An Evaluation," Bank of Israel, Research Department, Discussion Paper No. 89.06. Offenbacher, Edward K. (1985). "Empiircal Research on Money Demand in Israel," Bank of Israel Economic Review, 60, pp. 316. Pitennan, Sylvia (1989). "Economic Stabilization in Israel: Financial Diiffculties in the Adjustment Process to Low Inflation", mimeo. Sargent, TJ. (1982). The End of Four Big Inlfations," in Inflation: Causes and Effects, R.E. Hall, ed. (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 4196. Siklos, Pierre L. (1989). The End of the Hungairan Hypeirnflation of 19451946," Journalof Money, Credit and Banking, 21 (No. 2), pp. 13547. Taylor, John (1979). "Staggered Wage Setting in a MacroModel," Ameircan Economic Review Papers , and Proceeding, 69, pp. 10813. The NationalBudget 1988, Jerusalem (Hebrew). Wicker, Elmus (1986). Terminating Hyperinlfations in the Dismembered Habsburg Monarchy," American Economic Review, 76 (June), pp. 35064. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 29 Table 1. Major Indicators, 19801989 8084 Rate of growth (percent) in: 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989* Average )1( Business sector GDP 2.8 5.3 5.8 7.0 1.1 1.4 )2( Pirvate consumption 5.5 0.5 14.2 8.4 3.0 1.0 )3( Gross domestic investment 2.7 10.6 10.4 3.3 2.1 5.2 )4( Exports 4.4 8.7 5.6 10.8 2.1 4.2 Consumer pirces (percent rate of change) 189.2 304.6 48.1 19.9 16.3 22.0 (6) Unemployment (percent) 5.1 6.7 7.1 6.1 6.4 8.8 (7) Real interest arteb 23.0 100.0 33.0 39.0 25.0 15.0 (8) Unit labour costsc (index, 1984 = 100) 100.2 89.7 109.3 114.6 125.5 124.0 1.7 1.2 1.6 .:1.0. 0.7 13.6 2.6 1.9 1.3 4.6 4.7 1.3 1.5 Other indicators (5) (9) Current account surplus (billions of S( . ■' 1.0 Percentof GNP (10) Total public sector deficit (11) Deficit corrected for cyclical downturn (12) Tax revenue 41.4 43.8 46.8 45.8 44.5 41.1 (13) Internal debt 128.8 144.6 128.2 124.2 123.6 125.4 (14) External debt 65.2 80.7 64.3 54.1 45.8 42.6 Estimates. b Average shortterm rate. c In the business sector. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilizaiton to Growth p. 30 Table 1 Indicators of Business Sector Proiftability,8 19821989 1982 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989" Indexes, 1986 = 100 Labor cost per manhour in the business sector, product pirces Manufactuirng )1( Labor cost per unit of business sector product Manufactuirng (2) 91.0 87.5 88.5 95.0 90.3 911 89.2 89.2 100.0 100.0 105.3 106.9 109.3 112.1 108 110 100.0 100.0 102.3 102.9 105.8 106.5 104 10 105 Percent Rate of return to gross capital in business sector* of which: In manufacturing )3( 13.6 12.7 10.3 8.6 10.1 7.8 9.3 6.6 17.5 11.7 6.9 1.4 16.2 10.1 11.6 6.3 25.1 94.7 34.7 38.4 25.4 14 6.3 6.4 5.3 4.5 1.5 Taxation rate on nonwage income 24.9 27.5 33.3 31.9 312 28.2 Net ratee of taxation on nonwage income 10.9 19.5 26.5 24.7 25.6 22.4 12.8 13.2 Real interest rate on shortterm in business sector11 Manufacturing (4) aedit Real marginal interest rate on overdratf facilities (5) Real yield to matuirty of 10year bonds (6) (7) (8) 8 8.5 3 11 Source: 19821988 Bank of Israel, Annual Repotrs. a The b share of labor in GDP is 2.4 times that of capital, and has tended to irse in recent years. Estimated c Includes imputed labor input of selfemployed in each sector, at hourly wages equal to those of wage earners in the same industry. d The differences between interest rates reflect the differences in the shares of the vairous kinds of credit in the same industry. After deduction of credit subsidies and capital transfers to business ifrms; includes taxes on salaires of managers, which are classified as nonwage income. e Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 31 . Table 3. Rate of Increase of Productivity 1985 1986 1987 1988 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.2 Business Sector Product Labor inpur Labor productivity Manufacturing (diamonds excluded) Product Labor input Labor productivity Food Product Labor input Productivity 1989a 2.9 4.1 0.1 2.2 7.0 3.8 2.8 1.8 3.1 2.9 0.0 4.9 4.6 3.1 3.7 2.0 1.7 1.0 9.0 0.4 13.7 8.8 4.5 12.8 1.5 1.6C 6.2 6.3 0.1 13C 0.3 3.9 12.6 9.6 3.3 5.5C 9.QF 4.9 5.2 3.7 1.6 0.2 4.9 0.2 3.1 1.6 1.5 0.5 2.8 5.3 15 o.r Textiles Product Labor input Productivity Metal Products Product Labor input Productivity Electronics and Transport Equipment Product Labor input Labor productivity Chemical and Oil Products Product Labor input Productivity Transport Equipment Product Labor input Productivity Miscellaneous Product Labor input Productivity 4.5 17 1.1 3.5C 0.9 0.9 1.3 3.4 6.6 1.7 3.2 5.1 4.2C 3.6C 4.3 0.5 10.7 3.6 0.5c 10.1 5.1 4.7 33 3.2 0.8 3.9C 3.4 4.3 3.5 0.1 1.2 4.4 19C 1.0c 1.8 11.4 0.8 0.2 0.6 4.0 19.9 17.0 3.5 1.9 13 0.7 6.0 0.0 19 3.6 3.5 4.9 9.6 1.0 . 3.7 5.5 13 9.1 9.1 10.4 1.3 10 1.4 16.8 0.0 16.8 3.6 10.7 2.2 8.6 6.1 14 IJLI. Product Labor input" Productivity 4.6 7.2 3.3 7.4C 7.7 9.6C 5.2C 7.1 0.9 5.6 1.6 14.8 4.6 15.8 11.8 7.7 6.5 16.1 3.0 10.2 8.0 6.8 Koor Product" Labor input* Productivity11 2.6 0.2 13 Source: Central Bureau of Statistics, I.A.I. and Koor. a Estimates. b Working days. c Rate of change 19891/198911. d Change of products is measured by a change in sales. e Number of workers. 10.0 2.1 8.1 7.1 0.6 11.5 Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 32 Table 4. Productivity and Wages 1986 1987 1.8 3.1 7.2 1988 1989s Business Sector Labor productivity Realb wages 6.1 0.2 ■,.■. 3.9 0.5 0.3 . Manufacturing Labor productivity Realc wages 1.7 4.9 1.6 2.5 9.3 . 1.4 9.2 5.3 Labor productivity Reald wages 4.5 12.2 6.3 14.1 1.5 7.7 2.5 1.6 15.6 3.3 3.5 14.6 8.1 S.5 10.0 10.7 9.3 3.6 0.4 0.5 7.7 0.1 6.9 1.2 4.4 2.2 1.0 5.4 9.1 0.8 0.6 5.4 Food 0.7 Textiles Labor productivity Reald wages 1.1 " ' Metal Products Labor productivity Realc wages 0.5 Electronics and Transport Equipment Labor productivity Realc wages 1.8 Chemical and Oil Products Labor productivity Realc wages 1.0 6.7 Source: Central Bureau of Statistics. a Rate of change 19891/198911. b Nominal wages deflated by GDP prices. c Wages deflated by wholesale prices. d Wages deflated by the corresponding component of pirces. 7.4 0.3 Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 33 Table 5. Real Interest Rates, Changes in Directed Credit and Credit Ratios, 19831989 Real interest artes on total shortterm credit Percentage share of directed credit Total shortterm credit per output Whole economy Total credit Free Directed Agir Manu credit credit cultuer fact Agir culture Manu fact uirng Whole uirng Whole eco nomy (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11( Agri eco culture nomy Manu fact. uirng (1) (2) (3) (4) 1983 6.2 10.7 1.0 0.4 4.7 36.8 51.2 75.0 31.2 30.5 30.8 1984 28.9 32.9 23.8 27.6 33.8 39.8 56.5 76.8 36.1 26.2 28.3. 1985 16.4 28.1 1.5 24.0 11.7 40.3 51.7 76.1 25.8 28.8 28.1 1986 8.2 16.4 6.5 12.1 1.4 33.0 34.9 66.4 23.4 35.8 27.5 1987 18.8 25.8 0.1 20.1 10.1 26.9 28.3 59.8 27.5 49.1 30.2 1988 13.8 18.0 2.8 14.2 6.3 21.6 23.2 54.7 30.9 66.2 34.5 1989" 11.5 18.8 Sources: Col. (1) Bank of Israel Annual Report, 1988. C0L (2) Ben Rawe, 1989. Cols. (6)(8) Ben Rawe, 1989. a Estimates based on ifrst half of 1989, Bank of Israel's data. 33.5 BrunoandMeridor:From Stabilizationto Growthp. 34 Table 6. Selected Liquidity Ratios for NonLinked and Linked Assets, 19841989 (Percentages( ShortTerm NonLinked Assets Demand deposits CDs Time deposits (23 mths( LongTerm Linked Assets Index linked Pension funds Provident funds saving schemes 1984 45 17 14 75 92 92 1985 60 43 38 75 92 92 1986 48 38 20 75 92 78 1987 38 38 20 5565 92 78 1988 26 26 16 5565 92 78 1989 21 21 12 Size of asset in 1988 )'£< of GNP( )31(, )6.8( Source: Piterman (1989) and Bank of Israel's data. a This includes life insurance. )36.6( )11.1(* Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 35 Table 7. Wages, Pirces and Exchange Rates (average percent change( 19S6 1987 1988 19893 Business Sector 65.0 32.6 24.7 18.9 Manufacturing 65.3 30.6 16.0 17.6 hotels 78.6 36.6 26.4 17.6 commercial services 67.8 30.5 30.0 23.9 89.8 47.2 33.0 15.7 CPI 48.1 19.9 16.3 21.8 Wholesale pirces 45.1 18.5 17.5 23.8 Tradables" 42.6 14.5 11.4 13.0 Nontradablesb 46.1 25.6 21.1 28.1 Nontradables excluding housing )A.\ 34.2 24.0 24.6 Exchange ratec 45.0 143 2.4 13.8 Nominal Wages Commerce, restaurants Financial Sc St. Personal and other services Source: Central Bureau of Statistics. a b First 8 months of 1989 compared to 1988 average figures. Excluding fruits, vegetables and controlled goods and services. c Veirsus currency basket. . Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilization to Growth p. 36 Table 8. Selected Pirce Indexes, 19861989 (annual percentage change) (Last 4 quarters inflation) CPI (1) Non Controlled Nontradeda Housing Whole sale prices Traded8 (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) 36.41 39.61 19.20 16.46 17.00 Weight in Index 100.0 traded3 excluding ■.. :. housing 1986 III 19.2 20.2 17.6 20.3 35;0 8.7 12.8 1986 IV 19.6 15.1 14.5 17.1 35.1 3.6 15.4 19871 22.8 19.1 16.5 26.3 37.9 16.4 18.9 1987 II 19.5 17.0 15.3 25.5 35.3 16.7 1987 III 18.8 18.8 12.3 26.5 32.8 20.3 1987 IV 16.1 20.9 14.3 23.1 30.7 15:7 19881 15.8 17.2 12.0 21.7 26.1 16.5 13.2 198811 16.2 18.3 11.3 20.8 25.0 15.0 15.4 in 16.3 17.0 11.2 20.0 217. 15.8 1988 IV 16.4 15.6 9.1 223 21.2 23.0 16.9 19891 19.5 22.0 11.7 23.4 24.0 22.6 27.5 1989 II 20.1 21.1 11.5 26.3 21.3 33.9 29.3 1989 III 21.0 21.4 12.5 26.8 18.4 39.5 31.2 1988 : :. ■\. 13.9 ■ . 14.9 15.2 . . 13.9 Source: Central Bureau of Statistics and BenBassat (1989). a Based on the CPI index and excluding fruits, vegetables and controlled goods and services. Bruno and Meridor: From Stabilizaiton to Growth p. 37 Table 8a. Selected Pirce Indexes (percent of change each quarter compared to previous quarter, annual rates( Excl. vegetables, fruit CPI (1) Weight in Index Whole sale pirces (2) 100.0 Sc (3) Non traded (4) tradeda (5) (6) (7) Con trolled (8) 41.96 58.04 39.61 36.41 16.46 17.00 Traded Non controlled Traded Housing 19861 5.1 19.1 8.4 3.5 26.7 8.1 13 3.3 1986 II 29.3 20.6 22.7 33.6 39.4 24.8 35.8 34.2 in 12.6 13.9 13.3 123 42.1 12.9 15.4 11.4 1986 IV 29.0 12.1 12.1 40.5 29.0 14.7 20.2 11.5 19871 22.7 25.3 12.0 29.3 42.1 14.3 15.9 18.6 1987 II 18.0 18.2 16.7 18.7 32.2 18.8 20.2 17.1 1987 III 9.3 18.1 65 10.9 27.2 6.1 15.9 12.6 1987 IV 17.5 19.7 14.4 19.2 24.4 15.1 14.3 12.6 19881 17.7 18.7 11.0 23.5 22.1 11.2 16.1 13.1 1988 II 21.8 16.3 163 25.6 27.7 15.5 10.4 18.6 1988m 73 15.0 4.9 9.0 19.4 2.8 17.4 13.9 1988 IV 22.0 143 11.4 29.5 17.1 10.8 45.0 21.2 19891 30.7 41.3 21.3 37.2 33.2 17.0 19.4 56.8 1989 II 19.2 16.4 13.6 215 19.9 14.8 47.0 1989 HI 12.8 15.9 7.8 14.8 12.5 7.4 32.2 1986 Source: Central Bureau of Statistics and BenBassat (1989(. Excluding housing. ; 24.0 25.5 38 Figure 1. Supply of Consumer Goods via LargeScale Retail Trade 90 II III N 111 11 1989 1985 Figure 2. Industrial Production 110 108 3 106 ■ . . a> 104 © □> ■ 2 § 102 'i I ■ ^ 1 100 1 1/ V 98 J 1 1 II III 1985 1 1 ii 111 1986 n in 1987 i , 1 in 11 1988 1 IV ! 11 111 1989 39 Figure 3. Employment and Unemployment 440 / 430 b. Public sector employment ס. C 420 CO tn g 410 400 I II III 1985 IV I II III 1986 IV I II III 1987 IV I II III 1988 IV I II III 1989 40 Figure 4. Real Wage per Employee 130 Real wage per output in industrial exports 8 J J L 19B5/I 1986/1 1987/1 J L J L 1988/1 L 1989/1 Figure 5a. Foreign Trade 800 Merchandise Imports Merchandise expotrs . Trade deficit. 600 in o = 400 2 200 ?!:!' I II III N I II III IV 1985 1986 Excluding ships, aircraft, fuel and diamonds. I II III 1987 IV I II HI 1988 W I II III 1989 W 41 Figure 5b. Relative Prices of Industrial Production 130 y\ nis/u.s.$ /.. \ 120 8 110 11 .. NIS/Eurobasket \\ v 100 1 '■■ .''■..■ / .* / / 90 V / / NIS/5currencle3 80 I I 1 1 II III 1 IV I 1 1 III I 1 IV I 1 I II 1986 1985 1 1 IV 1 1 I II 1987 1 1 IV III 1988 I (I 1989 Figure 6. External Debt / GNP 80 0. 60 ^ " y \ 1 5 £ . y" I 40 20 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 198.6 1987 1988 42 Figure 7. Interest Rates and Inflation ח 4 ! n nfi jjn n Interest on overdraft <' pi Rate of inflation ■ : : :: ;J \ 1PIn t 7| A | V/ y 2 " 1 /; illlli I J 1 \ f \y ull ' :: VI /I l | ■ 1QAA I9OO I 1 J ■■ 1 1 t A 7/" n r ' uj f\'^ i 1 ][ n : /I J 'no : ;M /I/Is ! //// I 1 J\\ W ;* ■) < 1 Iff 1987 1 VII 1988 II VII n I, r / ff m I [ /7 /7 ח י M : 1989 11 VII VII Figure 8. Public Sector Cash Flows 600 " 550 | 500 CO z 450 *.* 400 .a 10 Domestic publicsector deficit O 5 i £ Tax revenues . 5 0 II III 1985 IV I I I II III 1986 IV I I I II III ?987 IV I IV I 1988 I I II III 1989 IV 43 Figure 9. Bankruptcies and Liquidations 197884: Annual data 1 98589: Quarterly data Quartan I I 1978 80 '82 I I I '84 '85 '86 '87 '89 '88 Figure 10. Velocity of Circulation Second helf 0f1986 . 450 i 400 / y 350 ■r o 300 \ . 250 ■ 200 ■ 150 i 1984 1985 i IV | I I II III 1986 I I IV I I I I in iv 1987 I 1 I I III IV 1988 I I I II 1989 44 Figure 11. Selected PriceIndexes, 19861989 )Annual percentage change) 50 40 ,'' Housing /' . 30 CPI 8 / .* 20 ... 10 / Controlled prices / 1 / 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 40 ......... _ :......_ Nontraded excluding housing* 30 ■ Wholesale prices "r '"'" ..._._ ♦.* 20 Traded* * 10 1986/111 .^*^ i ! 1987/1 1988/1 * Excluding fruit, vegetables and controlled ._ goods and services. *.I, : I 1989/1 r ■■ 45 סדרות מאמרים לדיון 1986 86.01ל) .רובין( מרירור. מימון הוצאות הממשלה בישראל .19831960 86.02מ .ברנתן .המימון הציבורי לדיור מיבסוד .מימון 86.03 86.04 86.05 Announcements and א .מרום . Monetary תרומת האינפלציה לגודלו Prices in Israel: 19701983 86.06מ .ברון .השפעות כלכליות 86.07 ש. של , ופרוגרסיביות. L.Leidevman, and E. Of f enbacher Stock Prices in Israel של ענף הבנקאות בישראל. Wages. and Import Prices, Melnick R. גורמים דמוגרפיים :היבטים נוספים. התפתחות הפרשי השכר בין גברים יהודים מארצות מוצא שונות אמיר. בשנות השבעים. 86.08ע .לויתן בחינת עצמת השיבושים ביחסי העבודה בעת שינויים בלתי צפויים בקצב האינפלציה. 86.09ד .אלקיים .י .טל .ד .יריב השפעת החוב הפנימי והחוב החיצוני על הצריכה הפרטית בישראל בשנים 1971עד ,1984 Crisis. 86.10 Anatomy of a Debt 86.11ד .יריב .אמידת הצפיות לאינפלציה בישראל וניתוח תכניות 86.12ד .אלקיים. כלכליות ■. Mexico Katz, התפתחותן לדיסאינפלציה. ההצע והביקוש לעבודה בסקטור העסקי בישראל. על M. רקע 46 1987 M. BarNathan, J. Baruh. Determinants of the Tariff Structure of 87,01 the Israeli Industrial Sector 19651977. R. Melnick, A Inflationary Expectation Formation in Israel: Specification Test. 87.02 L. (Rubin) Meridor, Trying to Cope With Large Government Deficits M. Bruno, S. Piterman Israeli Experience. :The .חוב חיצוני מול אינפלציה 87.03 :הממשלה Israel's מימון גירעון , )רובין( מרידור.ל Stabilization. a Twoyear Review. 87.04 87.05 1988 R. Ablin The Logic of "Ricardian Equivalence" and the DeficitInflation Debate. . לויתן.ע 88.02 . מדדים לרווחיות היצוא, פסח.ש 88.03 , הגורמים המשפיעים על הרכב תקציב הממשלה הערך 88.01 פרסום מדד המחירים לצרכן ובחינת יעילות שוק ניירות . יריב.ד 88.04 .בישראל A, Cukierman. Meir, in Israel העבודה על Y. כוח Artstein, The של Sokoler, Monetary Policy and Institutions Past. Present and Future. השפעת שינויים במבנה הותק, קלינוב. ר,אמיר . גישת הקבועים והזמניים:19721983 ,השכר Policy Durimg Disinflation: Israeli Stabilization Program of 1985 Z. 88.05 Sussman, Wage .ש 88.06 88.07 47 Fiscal And Monetary Dynamics Of Israeli Inflation: A Cointegrated Analysis 19701987 M. Beenstock. R. Melnick. M. Beenstock, Mishel Kahanaman The Trade Balance Ratio and the Real Exchange Rate in Israel 1955 1986 A. Offenbacher, M. Beenstock, 88.08 BenGad The M. The Demand for Liquid Assets in Israel. ShortRun Monetary Control in A 1970 1985 88.09 88.10 Israel 88.11 Democratic Model of the "RentSought" Benefit 88.12 Cvcle 1989 הריבית הריאלית והנומינלית על החוב הפנימי ,פיטרמן .ס ,אורבך .צ 89.01 .והחצוני M. Beenstock. The Factorial Distribution Union Bargaining Model of Income in the Erosion of the Real Exchange Rate; R. Ablin. Growth A. Bregman. M. A 89.02 89.0? Demand and Diagrammatic Clarification Fuss, and Haim Regev HighTech Firms in Israeli 89.04 Industry. . סקר החברות של בנק ישראל בחינה מחודשת.פישר R. Melnick, Forecasting Short An 1983 Run . י,גבע Inflation in Israel .ד"ר ד 19831987 89.05 89.06 Evaluation .על האשראי הבנקאי לזמן קצר בענפי המשק נטל הריבית. בןרוה.י .1988 עד 89.07 48 ,הסקטור העסקי משק של השפעת שערי הריבית על ההשקעה בענפי. לביא.י .1987 A. Bregman, 1962 הישראלי 89.08 במשק . הרפורמה בשוק ההון יעדים ותוצאות ראשונות, בןבסט.א 89.09 Technological Progress, Structural 89.10 Productivity in Industry: The Case Change, and of Israel. . מדדים למחירי מוצרים סחירים ובלתי סחירים, בןבסט.ע Leora (Rubin) Meridor and Shula Pessach, The BalanceofPayments Offset to Monetary Policy: An Examination of The Israeli 89.11 89.12 Case. 1990 Costly Transition from Stabilization to Sustainable Growth: Israel's Case. Michael Bruno £c Leora (Rubin) Meridor, The 90.01