Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Chapter Two Government in Colonial America Stanley L. Engerman 1 Government in Colonial America by Stanley L. Engerman Colonial America entailed the movement of settlers from elsewhere into an area previously resided in by Indians. Settlement meant the attraction of free immigrants from elsewhere-mainly the British Isles, the acquisition of slave labor from Africa, and the need to control those already there, or, at least, to work out mutually satisfactory arrangements for coexistence. For free migrants it meant a relocation into an area quite different from that which they had left, while for African slaves it meant a loss of freedom and control. The role of colonial governments was to provide, within the colonies, for defense and protection, laws in regard to property rights for individuals, the provision of certain public goods, and the regulation of activities of private individuals and businesses. Externally, there were regulations regarding trade (though these were often imposed by England) and defense against foreign attack (again generally provided by the English). Governmental rules could be the basis of a laissez-faire economy or a centrally- controlled one. In either case there is a major role played by government. While the thirteen colonies were subject to control by the English until independence, they did have some flexibility in determining who had the right to vote and to hold office, what laws could be passed, and control over financial issues. Those not able to vote could, however, be the beneficiaries of government policy and also were able to bring pressure on the governments to offset losses in the economic and political sphere. 1 Early European Settlement of the New World The nations of western Europe began their colonization movement into, and across, the Atlantic in the late fourteenth and fifteenth centuries. The pioneering nations in settling the Americas were Spain and Portugal. Portugal had first moved onto the offshore African islands, including the Azores, Maderia, the Cape Verde Islands, Fernando Pó, Principe, and São Tome, and Spain settled the Canary Islands, before both crossed the Atlantic Ocean to settle in the 2 Americas. Portugal settled in Brazil, while Spain explored several parts of mainland North America, the Caribbean, and Central and South America, primarily settling in what would be called Latin America (South and Central America), several of the islands in the Caribbean (Cuba, Puerto Rico, and Hispaniola), and a few scattered parts, mainly in the southwest and Florida, of mainland North America. British expansion overseas, first as a trading nation, began with the granting of charters to trading companies, beginning with the Muscovy Company (1553), and, by the end of the sixteenth century there were British companies trading with the Levant, North Africa, and India, and, in the early seventeenth century, West Africa. Spain had a one century lead over the northern nations of western Europe – France, Britain, and the Netherlands – and settled in those areas which had been the wealthiest parts of the Americas and had by far the greatest numbers of American Indians. Spain’s possessions provided great wealth from the use of Indian labor in mining gold and silver for shipment to Spain, from where it was exported elsewhere in Europe and Asia to finance Spanish purchases of consumer and military goods. Native American Populations The British and other Europeans were not, of course, the first to settle in the Americas; they had been preceded by the Native-Americans who had settled throughout North and South America. The locations of Indians at the time of European contact pointed to significant differences in settlement patterns. The areas of Spanish conquest had about three-quarters of the Indian population, mainly in the wealthy and politically sophisticated Inca and Aztec empires, with populations resident in urban areas, military organizations, high agricultural productivity, and large-scale slavery and imperialism. Even with the extreme mortality, primarily due to diseases, after the Spanish contact, these areas continued to have larger Indian populations and, even today, Indians form a large part of the regional population. Mainland North America was 3 quite different. The numbers of Native-Americans were much smaller and the Indians there lived in much smaller political units than those in Latin America. There was a rather mixed pattern of Indian – European contact. In many cases there was conflict and warfare, between Europeans and Indians, but some Europeans formed coalitions with Indian groups in opposition to other Europeans, but peaceful arrangements also persisted. Trading took place, with furs being sold in exchange for foodstuffs, alcohol, tobacco, and other goods. The French in Canada were heavily involved in the fur trade with Indians, and the British, in their colonies, were also able to establish trading relations in furs and other goods with the Indians. Whether trade was peaceful or antagonistic, there was generally a push of Europeans inland, with the Indians often being forced to relocate further inland. Thus, the land base of the British colonists on mainland North America expanded greatly after initial settlement, as did that of the French in Canada before they lost it to the British in 1763. Colonial Organization in the Settlement of North America When the three major northern European nations came to explore and settle in the New World they were left with what were regarded as only limited opportunities relative to Spain and Portugal. Those parts of the Americas left available had had small Indian societies of relatively limited wealth. The overall Indian populations of the settled areas of mainland North America were quite small relative to those of Latin America. Before settling on the mainland, European nations had settled in the generally unoccupied islands of the Caribbean. After an early period of using white indentured labor to produce tobacco, they transformed these islands into major sugar producing areas, using mainly slave labor brought from Africa. Sugar was produced, to be exported to European markets, on large-scale plantations, often of 100 to 200 or more slaves. The rivalries among the British and Dutch, in Europe and in the New World, led to the British introduction of Navigation Acts after 1651, to control export and import markets and shipping 4 patterns, via regulating the trade of their colonies, requiring exports to go to Britain, imports to come from Britain, and goods to be carried in British or colonial vessels. All Europeans pursued similar policies of mercantilism, intended to increase production and trade of the home country at the expense of other nations. It was only at the end of the seventeenth century that the migration from Britain shifted from the Caribbean to go primarily to the colonies of mainland North America. Settlement on the mainland had begun earlier, in the seventeenth century, but these mainland colonies were not yet considered as attractive a location for settlement by immigrants as were those in the Caribbean, and the demand for slave labor to be imported was much smaller. In the seventeenth century there were several other settlements on the mainland: the French, mainly in Canada; the Swedes in Delaware; and the Dutch in what was called New Amsterdam. The means of establishing settler colonies varied among European nations. The Spanish and Portuguese colonies were often state enterprises, with state decision-making and with a strong role played by the Catholic Church. The British pattern differed, however. Its colonies were established under charters and controls by the crown. Yet, they were settled by individuals or groups, not by the government, and they made decisions in their own or the colony’s interests. There were two basic British patterns of colonial establishment and operation. Proprietorships were colonies established by a grant made to specific individuals and groups. Sometimes these colonies were established for particular religious or philanthropic purposes. The second method was the use of a joint stock company to finance settlement and to establish the group controlling the political life of the colony. The earliest attempts to establish settlements by the British in North America, both unsuccessful, were proprietorships for Newfoundland (1583) and Roanoke Island, North Carolina (1585). Both involved small numbers of settlers, and lasted only for a very short period, as also did the joint stock company established for the settlement of Kennebec River, Maine (1607). The first successful settlement was that of Virginia, begun as a joint stock company in 1609, with land 5 grants used to encourage colonization. While the settlement was to be successful, the company was not. It failed financially and, in 1624, Virginia became the first Royal Colony. Joint stock companies were used to settle Plymouth, Massachusetts (1620) and Massachusetts (1629, the Massachusetts Bay Company). The former was an attempt at a communal economic system, but was soon seen as unsuccessful and a financial failure in 1627, and there was a shift to private ownership at that time. This communal system did not work well, as individuals and families were less willing to work long and hard as they would if they had privately-owned property on which they need not share their gains with others. In the case of the Massachusetts Bay Company there was a subsequent shift of political power, by the Puritans, to a representative system of local residents in 1634. In the 1620’s there were several colonies formed by the British in the Caribbean. The first, St. Kitts, was initially settled in 1623, colonized in parts by the French and the British, and came under a grant in 1627. Barbados was first settled after 1624, and was given a grant in 1627 – the same grant that covered St. Kitts and most of the subsequent British Leeward islands in the Caribbean. Barbados was a proprietorship, which led to a series of political disputes in subsequent years. It became a royal colony in 1650, although some financial provisions concerning the sharing of profits with creditors and leaseholders remained in effect for another decade or so. A Puritan joint stock company, following the same laws as the Massachusetts Bay Company, had been established on Providence Island off the coast of Belize, in 1630, but this was neither an economic nor social success, and was captured by the Spanish in 1641. The largest of the British colonies in the Caribbean, Jamaica, was settled after being conquered from Spain in 1655. As such, it was initially treated by the British government as a dependency. The varying patterns of organization in the Caribbean and as the mainland indicate the flexibility of British political controls and settlement arrangements. There were numerous colonies and many different types of political arrangements. The first post-Massachusetts settlements on the mainland (after 1629) were undertaken by the granting 6 of proprietorships to specific individuals or groups by the king. These proprietorships were not all successful, several of the colonies becoming Crown Colonies within several decades of establishment. Maryland (1634) was formed as a proprietorship granted to the Catholic Lord Baltimore, and became a Crown Colony in 1691: New York, in 1664, was captured from the Dutch who had tried to establish a joint stock company in 1613, and became a Crown Colony in 1683; New Jersey (1664), initially settled by the Swedes, Finns, and Dutch, in 1655 became a Crown Colony in 1702. The Carolinas (1670) became Crown Colonies in 1729. The final two colonies settled as proprietorships were a colony including numerous Quakers with the title Pennsylvania and Delaware (1681), which was to become socially and economically successful, and Georgia (1732), initially a philanthropic venture. Georgia was not successful, and in 1751 it was returned to the Crown, at which time it reversed its earlier policy of excluding slave labor. All thirteen colonies were to become economically successful, over time, and whatever the original provisions, became equivalent states after the Revolution. Attracting Labor to the Colonies All colonies had to solve the same set of problems, attracting labor and capital in order to survive economically. While these factors of production were in scarce supply, a third factor, land, was quite abundant and quite fertile. It could be used, after some costs of clearing, in efficient agricultural production. The lower cost of producing food and other agricultural goods in the colonies was offset, due to labor and capital scarcity, by the higher costs of producing manufactured commodities. The Navigation Acts were meant to encourage British manufacturers and limit colonial manufacturers. But, as can be seen by the early nineteenth century production patterns in the United States, these Acts were, at least as far as manufacturing was concerned, unnecessary or redundant. The controls over shipping of colonial commodities were, however, more crucial, and did restrict shipping by the Dutch, raising the cost of the commodities in British and other European markets, and reducing colonial incomes. 7 The colonial governments adopted several different methods in their attempts to acquire scarce labor. Land was given to encourage immigration, whether granted directly to immigrants or else to those who brought them over. It was sometimes granted immediately, sometimes after time needed to establish permanent residence. A system of indentured labor, along the lines of British apprenticeship, was rapidly introduced. Most migrants lacked the funds to cover the cost of passage to the New World and establishing themselves, therefore migrants traded a number of years of coerced labor time for their transportation from the British Isles to the colonies. This system, it is estimated, accounted for about three-fifths of all white migration to the mainland colonies, and was particularly important for the southern colonies. After the indenture period, funds or land were, at times, given to the laborer, an additional subsidy to encourage migration. The colonies regulated the terms of transportation across the Atlantic, and were responsible for the enforcement of the terms of the contracts and disputes between owners and servants. The mixture of land grants and indentured contracts attracted settlers from many areas of Europe, including all parts of the British Isles, Germany, the Netherlands, Sweden, and Finland, while groups, such as English Pilgrims and the French Huguenots, came seeking religious freedom. Nevertheless, the British were the dominant presence on the mainland. Another source of labor, important in the southern states and the Caribbean, was the use of slave labor, initially purchased from Africa. The first slaves were introduced to the North American mainland about 1620. Following Barbados in 1660, most colonies introduced slave codes to define slaveowner rights, including the provision for the inheritance of the slave status by the children born to slave mothers. The relative importance of these forms of labor – free vs. slave – varied by region, based on the profitability of different crops. All colonies, despite their religious or political background, had legalized slavery, and no colony was to end slavery until the Revolutionary War. Attitudes and Political Economic Institutions 8 Some of the basic economic characteristics of the different colonies seemed similar at the start, but over time there developed significant differences in the nature of agriculture production and in the importance of agriculture relative to other economic sectors. The proprietors and investors in the colonies were generally from among the wealthiest and most politically important families in the British Isles. They had generally participated in the political life of England, and were often the recipients of charters and grants from the king which provided monopoly privileges. They had been involved with commercial transactions and trade, both internally and externally, and had contacts with nations on the European continent as well as with Africa and Asia. They had seen the advantages, at least to themselves, of private property and had developed a concern with individual and group incentives, with only limited reliance on government controls and operations or communal activities. They had achieved, by the standard of the time, a relatively high level of living, the outcome of a willingness to labor or to organize labor to achieve that goal. They lived in a British economy in which there was taxation of property, the existence of banks and money exchanges, and a productive agricultural sector on the basis of hired labor and tenants. Therefore, it is not surprising that many of the North American proprietors and settlers with large landholdings sought to transfer these institutions to the New World. A key question for understanding successful long-term growth is how pervasive these commercial attitudes were among the remainder of the free population, and how these general commercial, if not fully capitalist, attitudes were consistent with their religious and cultural attitudes. In general, the desire to seek commercial gains and the willingness to respond to various price and income incentives permitted the attraction of migrants from Europe as well as increased economic productivity and geographic expansion after arrival in the colonies. There was not, of course, a narrow focus on pure financial profit maximization, as seen in choices regarding leisure, family and children, and religion, but obviously enough of a concern to achieve high living standards. 9 Also carried over with earlier settlers was an attitude towards political and legal life that built upon, and, indeed, expanded beyond that in the metropolis. English common law was firmly established in the colonies by the time of the Revolutionary War. While the rules of eligibility to vote, based on property requirements were initially similar to those in Britain, the substantial difference in the shares of the population able to meet these requirements in the colonies did lead to important political differences. The basic requirements to vote generally included minimum amounts of freehold, personal property, tax payments, or income or wealth, and these did vary by colony and over time. In several states there were initially some restrictions on voting by certain religious groups, with limitations on Catholic and Jewish voting introduced after the late seventeenth century. Blacks and Indians were not legally citizens and thus could not vote. There were, also, suffrage restrictions by age, gender, race and ethnicity. Nevertheless, while the percentage of adult males who could vote in early eighteenth-century Britain, was about 15 percent, it is estimated that in the colonies about 50 to 80 percent of white males were qualified to vote. The big difference, with its significant influence on the economic and political behavior of the colonies, was the broader distribution of land ownership and wealthholdings in the colonies than in the metropolis. This difference in voting helps to explain many of the observed policy differences. Unlike in Europe, there were relatively few religious limitations on voting, and the British colonies, unlike the Spanish, had no religious restrictions on immigration. The colonial pattern meant that religious freedom was more developed in the British colonies than in the colonies of other European nations as well as in Europe. That wider holding of land, with its important impact on the economy and the size of the electorate, was not the outcome of the basic policy of landholding introduced in the colonies at the onset of settlement. Many of the original settlers had been landholders in Britain, and wished to adopt the manorial, or feudal, system with which they were familiar. This would have meant the allocation of land in large units, with the minimum acreages sold being greater than the size of farms needed for individual or family production of most food crops. Over time, however, the 10 average size of farms and of landholdings were reduced as a result of the actualities of production methods and political influence. Average farm size in the New England and Middle Colonies was smaller than that in the southern states, although the large holdings of Dutch patroons in the Hudson River Valley of New York were maintained by the British after 1664. This smaller size of landholdings in the North reflected not only the pattern of land sales adopted by the colonies, but also the frequency of more egalitarian laws and/or practices, including inheritance practices and the granting of headrights by colonial governments to encourage immigration from abroad and also the settlement of frontier areas within the colonies. Whereas, in regard to land, England maintained the practice of primogeniture (inheritance by the oldest son) many of the colonies provided for an equal division of land among heirs, and otherwise limited the share going to the eldest son. In the southern colonies, while there were also many small landholdings, the emergence of plantations, to produce rice and tobacco using slave labor meant more large units than in the North, although these plantations were smaller than were the sugar plantations of the Caribbean. The rise of slave-based plantation reflected more the nature of the crops grown than it did any fundamental initial differences in land law or in settler beliefs concerning slavery. The Structure of Colonial Government Each of the thirteen colonies had its own legal and political systems, based initially on their governmental charter, although, in retrospect, most of these differences were relatively minor and inconsequential. This system, resembling what would later be regarded as federalism, did allow for mobility and competition among colonies. Each colony had elective assemblies and a governor, often appointed by the Crown. It set its own suffrage requirements, made its own budgetary decisions, and was responsible for its own fiscal arrangements. The outcomes, however, were often somewhat similar across colonies, as were the legal codes. Yet these thirteen colonies were not able to behave as fully independent powers, since they, and their Caribbean counterparts, were still part of the developing British Empire and 11 subject to metropolitan controls. All were bound by the terms of the metropolitan Navigation Acts, influencing exports, imports, and shipping, and no colony could opt out of its provisions. The Navigation Acts were part of the system of mercantilism, aimed at increasing shipping, ships, production, and incomes of merchants, all to benefit residents of England. While some of the English were to be gainers, the losers were the British colonies, foreign countries, and British consumers of colonial products. Depending on the importance and magnitude of exports and imports, the Acts could, however, have had dramatically different impacts across colonies and generated differing amounts of controversy and debate. Similarly, when most of the settlements became Crown Colonies, decisions made in colonial legislatures were required to obtain final approval from the British parliament, which could overrule colonial decisions. In time of warfare the colonies fought on the side of the British, and colonial militias were often called upon in wars against the French and Indians. The basic army and navy costs were, however, paid for by the British, saving the colonies much of the expense of defense and reducing manpower needs. Colonies were thus a mixture of colonized nation and independent region, with their own leaders and legislatures. Geography’s Impact on Demographic and Economic Structures Despite some basic similarity in patterns of belief and behavior among British settlers, and an early similarity of institutions, there were major differences that soon emerged in economic and demographic structures. This led to sharp differences in institutions and the nature of laboring regimes. Fundamental to these changes were differences in climate, resources, and the ability to grow only certain crops in the different climatic regions. The Caribbean islands were first settled by indentured labor producing mainly tobacco, but generally they soon became sugar-producing islands using mainly slave labor. The populations became 90 percent slave, and the high mortality and low fertility of the slave population meant a continued need to import large numbers of slaves from Africa. Sugar was 12 grown on large plantations, and most of this sugar was exported, first to Britain, and then some re-exported elsewhere in Europe. The total and nonhuman wealth per free capita in the Caribbean was considerably above that in the mainland colonies, and the politically influential planter class was able to get favorable legislation from the British government, including legislation, such as the Molasses Act of 1733, at the expense of mainland colonies, by placing a very high tariff on sugar, molasses, rum, and spirits that the colonies had imported from the French and other foreign sugar colonies. The British mainland is conventionally divided into three areas; the New England states, the Middle Atlantic, and the South. Each had quite different economic and demographic patterns. The New England states were characterized by very high rates of population growth, due to high fertility and lower mortality. There were few indentured laborers and few slaves, the labor force consisting of free members of the population. New England experienced a high rate of natural increase, with only a rather limited immigration from Britain and elsewhere after the initial years of settlement. Agricultural production, mainly of grains, took place on small farms, often owneroperated, and with its relatively limited exports going mainly to the British West Indies. The Middle Atlantic states had somewhat more slaves and indentured laborers than did New England, but it was also characterized by agricultural production of foodstuffs on relatively small units, and with an amount of exports per capita similar to that of New England. These two northern regions were not considered by the British to provide the principal benefits of colonization to the British. They produced crops similar to those of Britain and thus provided a limited basis for becoming a major trading partner. The southern states fit much better into the British mercantilist ideal, specializing in crops that Britain was not able to produce, and exporting them to Britain, for both British consumption and for re-export to the Continent. The major crops were tobacco, from the Chesapeake, and later rice and indigo from South Carolina and Georgia. Exports from the southern colonies per free capita were about seven times that of the northern regions at the start of the eighteenth century, 13 and roughly three times greater just prior to the Revolution. The early settlement of the southern colonies was by whites, as indentured laborers and free workers, but in the eighteenth century there was a sharp growth in the slave population, from about 6 percent of total population in 1680 to 41 percent in 1770, with slaves of particular importance mainly in export production of rice and tobacco on units larger than the family farm. The southern natural rate of population growth, both free and slave, was unusually rapid, but the growth of the Southern population also benefited from large migrations from England and from Africa. The mainland colonies had roughly similar nonhuman wealth per capita (free and slave), a crude index of overall productivity. More useful, as a measure of differential political influence was the total (nonhuman and human, the latter only valued for slaves) wealth per free capita, the South’s being more than twice that of the North, or the nonhuman wealth per free capita, with that of the South being about 1.5 times that of the North. The mainland’s wealth per free capita was considerably below that of Jamaica and the Caribbean. The distribution of wealth among wealthholders was similar in New England and the South, but the Middle Atlantic states were somewhat more equal than the other regions, a point that, possibly, influenced its subsequent economic and political development. The relative equality of incomes and wealth led to a larger number voting, and this, in turn, influenced the decisions made as to education, land distribution, and chartering of banks and businesses. Although most mainland colonies become crown colonies, there were provisions permitting British officials to limit the rights of colonial governance. Each colony remained responsible for certain key political decisions. Colonies had legislative bodies and governors often appointed by the crown to rule internally, and there were generally elective offices. There were usually property requirements for voting, as was the case in England and elsewhere, but, as noted above the broad distribution of landholdings meant a higher share of the population was eligible to vote than in Britain and elsewhere on the European continent. It has been estimated that by 1776, 50 to 80 percent of white adult males in the various colonies were eligible to vote, 14 whereas only about 15 percent had been qualified to vote in England in the earlier part of the eighteenth century. Important Colonial Government Policies Key decisions made by each colony pertained to rules regarding property rights; the allocation of land, including the size and price of holdings made available for grants or for purchases; the controls over labor-free, slave, and indentured labor; regulations regarding shipping and trade, including tariffs, taxes, quality controls, and the use of product trademarks; the issuance of paper money; the provision of state militias; and the general policies towards taxations and expenditures. The functions performed by the colonial governments did not differ dramatically from those later undertaken by state and local governments. Unlike the Caribbean, with its large percentage of African slaves, and Mexico and South and Central America, with large numbers of native-Americans, mainland. North America was predominantly populated by the British. European settlers were about 60 percent of the population in the southern colonies, with higher shares elsewhere. Because of the nature of the settlement process set by the crown, there were thirteen colonies making decisions about laws, taxes, and finances, although subject to the overriding power of the British government. Certain aspects of economic and political structure, such as the basic Mercantilist rules controlling export and import trade and shipping arrangements, were binding on all colonies, but the specifics of tax and expenditure policies remained within colonial discretion. As part of the empire’s currency union, there were constraints on colonial financial and monetary policies, as they would be for the rest of the world in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, with gold standards and currency unions. The role of gold and silver specie and basically fixed definitions of colonial and British rates of exchange did not allow for substantial and persistent, as contrasted with temporary, variations in colonial monetary laws and money issues. The British Currency Acts of 1751 and 1764 restricted issues of paper money by colonies, as they were not considered legal tender, 15 although a 1773 act allowed the use of paper money to pay provincial taxes. But a land bank was established in Massachussetts, and more than one-half the colonies issued paper money, the latter being particularly important as a means of temporary wartime finance to be retired at the war’s end. The range of legislation in the colonies was rather broad and, as J.R. T. Hughes pointed out, during the colonial era virtually every aspect of economic life was subject to nonmarket control “and there is very little in the way of nonmarket control of the economy that does not have a colonial or English forerunner.” That being said, the colonies were able to experience relatively rapid economic growth by the standards of those times, and to achieve levels of per capita income similar to that of Britain, while receiving large number of immigrants and sustaining an exceptionally high rate of natural population increase. This reflected, in part, the relatively stable monetary situation, with no prolonged periods of price inflation, so that loans of foreign capital, mainly from Britain, continued throughout the period. Further, colonial rates of taxation, even with some allowance for the burden of the Navigation Acts, were relatively low compared to rates in Britain and much of Europe. The British government imposed tariffs on the external trade of the colonies, but not until the Stamp Act of 1765 (soon repealed in part) was there a major internal tax introduced. There were a rather mixed set of taxes imposed by different colonies- property taxes, faculty or income taxes, poll taxes, import and export duties, excise or internal taxes, and land taxes, based on improved acreage, total acreage, or assessed value. Tax rates did vary with circumstances, such as wars, but in the absence of a standing army or navy, and with the primary defense shield provided by the British, overall military expenditures were generally small. And while the local governments in the colonies were responsible for bridges, fences, roads, and schooling, these were often financed by tolls and fees, by the granting of land or of monopoly franchises or by taxation paid in labor time. Political conflicts - between proprietors and settlers, between large and small landholders, between landholders and the landless, between 16 merchants and farmers, between tidewater and frontier populations – did occur at periodic intervals, but did not lead to dramatic overhauls of the political system even though these pressures led to measures that indicated the flexibility of the colonial political system. These basic legal provisions and regulations seemingly did not interfere with economic growth or, at the least, were consistent with what developed – economic growth at a relatively high rate for the time. Of major importance were the granting of unconstrained rights to private property, with a general absence of government confiscation or of the other forms of failure to maintain these property rights. The Quebec Act of 1774 limited the ability of the colonists to expand westward, as the British government took control of the western lands from those colonies that had rights to them. Land rights were sold or given as grants by proprietors, and often included a requirement that the land be used or improved within a limited number of years before title was final, foreshadowing the Homestead Act of 1862. In some states Indians were not permitted to own land. The purchasers or grantees had rights to own, use, pass on property via inheritance (although primogeniture was not abolished until the Revolutionary War), or sell the land, as long as the taxes (quitrents) were paid. Given the great amounts of land available and the great importance of agriculture in national output, this security of land title played a key role in economic growth. While early in settlement the intent was to have land be made available in large units, over time the minimum size of units was reduced, with more land in units of 50 to 100 acres was granted to encourage population growth and relocation. Most free males were able to acquire land. The colonies adopted the English system of common law with great attention paid to lawyers and legal matters, as seen in the numerous volumes of state law codes and published legal decisions. Important sets of laws controlled black slavery, indentured labor, and apprenticeship, and there was no serfdom or, for whites, slavery. At times colonies imposed wages and hours regulations, as well as regulations imposing control over occupations. The English poor laws, with local controls regulating vagabonds and vagrancy, with workhouses and 17 poor relief as well as various terms regarding settlement, were carried over. Controls over exports were introduced to provide for better marketing, including inspection systems and quality controls, and colonies could introduce their own tariffs. License hours for stores and inns were set, among various types of business regulations. Thus, within the basic framework of property rights and free markets, the economies of the colonies were regulated, in terms of law if not by actual enforcement. The colonists may have benefited from the seeming certainty of transactions and behavior, but complications due to having thirteen colonies and legal systems may have introduced some costs to society. The establishment of thirteen colonies did lead to some competition and choice in settlement decisions, which may have had some influences on policies. The Colonial Legacy Some guide to the attitudes of the times regarding mercantilist regulations may be seen in the aftermath of the successful Revolutionary War. One basic set of policies introduced by Alexander Hamilton was the introduction of mercantilistic rules on shipping, imports, etc. suggesting that there was no conceptual opposition by colonists to mercantilist policy. Rather the issues of concern were whose mercantilistic policies to choose and whether it would be possible to force the British to behave appropriately. Hamilton’s various proposals regarding manufacturing, a national bank, the distribution of public lands, and the assumption of the colonial state and national government debts were also changes that formed a basis for postRevolutionary economic policy, and were carried forward for many years. In other matters, the Revolution led to an increase in taxation, due to the states absorbing the military expenditures previously paid for by the British, but the basic commitment to property rights and free markets, as well as the continuation of slavery and indentured labor, were carried forward into the New Nation. Nevertheless, the Revolutionary War did not lead immediately to economic success. It took about two decades before the new system became economically successful and its per capita income rose above the pre-Revolutionary level. 18 The colonial legacy for the new nation was one that permitted an early establishment of some characteristics needed for economic and political success. The mix of centralized power and decentralization established with the Constitution provided for flexibility in decision-making. Federalism meant an ability to have policy differentials among states, useful for the most part, but something which permitted the contribution of slavery in parts of the nation. Many important legal and political features were carried forward from earlier years. Some, such as the common law and the belief in protection of property rights, were vestiges of the British background; others such as a broad franchise, a state-determined banking system, and some relative generous policies of land dispersal, reflected adaptations made by the colonists. 19 REFERENCES John Butler, 2000. Becoming America: The Revolution Before 1776. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Nicholas Canny (ed.), 1994, Europeans on the Move, Studies on European Migration, 1500-1800. New York: Oxford University Press. Essays by Canny and Cullen. Robert J. Dinkin, 1977. Voting in Provincial America. A Study of Elections in the Thirteen Colonies, 1689-1776. Westport: Greenwood Press. Marc Egnal, 1998. New World Economies: The Growth of the Thirteen Colonies and Early Canada. New York: Oxford University Press. Stanley L. Engerman and Robert E. Gallman (eds) 1996. The Cambridge Economic History of the United States, Volume I, The Colonial Era. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Particularly the essays by Salisbury, Galenson, and McCusker. Stanley L. Engerman and Kenneth L. Sokoloff, 2002. “Factor Endowments, Inequity, and Paths of Development among New World Economies,” Economía. 3 (Fall), 41-88. Robert E. Gallman, 1964. Developing the American Colonies, 1607-1783. Chicago: Scott, Foresman. Paul W. Gates, 1968. History of Public Land Law Development. Washington; Government Pricing Office. Jack P. Greene, 1986. Peripheries and Center: Constitutional Development in the Extended Politics of the British Empire and the United States, 1607-1788. Athens: University of Georgia Press. Jonathan R. T. Hughes, 1991. The Governmental Habit Redux: Economic Controls from Colonial Times to the Present. Princeton, Princeton University Press. Alice Hanson Jones, 1980: The Wealth of a Nation to Be: The American Colonies on the Eve of the Revolution. New York: Columbia University Press. John McCusker and Russell Menard, 1985. The Economy of British America, 1607-1789. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press. Richard Middleton, 1996. Colonial America: A History, 1585-1776. Oxford: Blackwell. Curtis P. Nettels, 1938. The Roots of American Civilization: A History of American Colonial Life. New York: Appleton-Century-Crofts. Douglass C. North, 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 20 Edwin J. Perkins, 1988. The Economy of Colonial America, 2nd Edition. New York: Columbia University Press. Gary M. Walton and James F. Shepherd, 1979. The Economic Rise of Early America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ENDNOTES 1 The New World was not the first part of the westward expansion of England, politically or demographically. In 1541, the Irish Kingship Act established the English king as the king of Ireland, and also tried to establish English Protestantism rather than Irish Catholicism as the state religion. By the start of the seventeenth century England established the plantation system, to shift land ownership to settlers from England and give rise to a landlord-tenant pattern rather than either large or small-scale ownership. The size of lands granted was larger than the prior units, but were small enough to be available to many settlers. It is estimated that in the seventeenth century about 180,000 English went to Ireland (most after Cromwell’s triumphs after 1649), about equal to the numbers that went to the West Indies, slightly greater than the numbers going to the mainland colonies, and greater than the overall outflow from Ireland. The Act of Union in 1801 permitted Ireland to increase its numbers in Parliament, but more complete economic and political integration was later, if at all, in coming. 21