* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Document
Economic planning wikipedia , lookup
Fei–Ranis model of economic growth wikipedia , lookup
Economic democracy wikipedia , lookup
Edmund Phelps wikipedia , lookup
Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup
Non-monetary economy wikipedia , lookup
Austrian business cycle theory wikipedia , lookup
Nominal rigidity wikipedia , lookup
Production for use wikipedia , lookup
Economic calculation problem wikipedia , lookup
Keynesian economics wikipedia , lookup
LECTURE NOTES ON MACROECONOMICS ECO306 SPRING 2014 GHASSAN DIBEH Chapter 7: New Classical Macroeconomics and Economic Fluctuations Rational Expectations became the springboard for new ideas on how to reconcile the classical doctrine that the capitalist economy is stable and at full employment with the empirical facts of economic fluctuations. The new business cycle theory initiated by Nobel laureate Robert Lucas (1975) attempted to revive the age old project of embedding the business cycle into equilibrium theory and making economic fluctuations compatible with competitive equilibrium; a project that was largely abandoned with the triumph of Keynesian economics. Lucas and Sargent (1978) said that, "increased attention and respect are accorded to the theoretical casualties of the Keynesian revolution, to the ideas of Keynes's contemporaries and of earlier economists whose thinking for years has been regarded as outmoded" (p. 57). The New Classical Macroeconomics revived albeit in rigorous formulation the old Classical school of macroeconomics. The two main tenets of the new theory are: 1- Markets always clear: The flexibility of prices and rational expectations ensure that the economy is always at full employment equilibrium (the natural rate) 2- Policy is ineffective: Only monetary surprises will have an effect on output albeit transitory. The main task that confronted the New Classical School was the explanation of economic fluctuations and unemployment that Keynesian theory well explained. If Keynesian theory is to be discarded, how can market clearing and rational expectations be reconciled with the empirical facts of fluctuating output and employment in capitalist economies? Two main market clearing approaches were developed to provide an alternative to the Keynesian explanation of the business cycle: the Lucas equilibrium business cycle and the Real Business Cycle model (RBC). The equilibrium business cycle The building blocks of the basic Lucas (1975) model consist of rational optimizing agents that are geographically separated in an island-type economy. These individuals lack the ability to obtain perfect information on prices. If a certain general price increase (inflation) is perceived by the agents as an increase in the relative price of the commodity they are producing, then their immediate rational reaction would be to increase the production and supply of the commodity. Once the agents discover their error--the error being that they confused a general price level for a relative price increase--which should have no effects on their production plans, they scale back production. The equilibrium business cycle Hence, the business cycle is a result of misperception on the part of rational optimizing agents because of imperfect information. In addition, since the equilibrium state is maintained throughout time, the cycle is perfectly compatible with economic theory. Formalizing the model, the model gives the following equation for cyclical output: 𝑦𝑡𝑐 = 𝑏 1 − 𝛽 (𝑝𝑡 − 𝑝) Where b=constant 𝛽 = a measure of reaction of agents to price changes and 0 ≤ 𝛽 ≤ 1. 𝑦𝑡𝑐 =cyclical real output 𝑝𝑡 = price level at time t 𝑝=mean price level The equilibrium business cycle The parameter 𝛽 is central to the model. In the presence of imperfect information (0 ≤ 𝛽 < 1), (𝑝𝑡 − 𝑝) will push agents to increase production in a cyclical manner i.e., 𝑦𝑡𝑐 > 0. Given that the price level 𝑝𝑡 deviates from the mean 𝑝 as a result of unanticipated demand shocks then the cycle in the capitalist economy is generated by unanticipated demand shocks that are transmitted into real output cycles. 𝛽 then measures the belief of economic agents of a change in the relative price level If output is a function of lagged output also, then the complete model becomes: 𝑐 𝑦𝑡𝑐 = 𝜆𝑦𝑡−1 + 𝑏 1 − 𝛽 (𝑝𝑡 − 𝑝) Where 0 < 𝜆 < 1. The equilibrium business cycle The iterative solution of the model becomes 𝑦𝑡𝑐 = ∞ 𝑗 𝑗=0 𝜆 𝑏 1 − 𝛽 (𝑝𝑡−𝑗 − 𝑝) Thus, the cyclical component of output at any time t is a function of all past shocks to the economy realized in real output. Moreover, since economic agents are on their supply function then the economy is at equilibrium at all times. We can represent graphically the dynamics of the economy in this model. Figure 17 shows the dynamics of output if there is perfect information (𝛽 = 1). The economy experiences no fluctuations and output converges to potential output at all times. The equilibrium business cycle Figure 18 shows the fluctuating output under imperfect information 𝛽 ≠ 1. The sum of the aggregate demand shocks in the past are transformed into real output changes as economic agents misperceive price changes resulting from those shocks as relative price changes. Figure 18. Stochastic fluctuation under imperfect information and demand shocks Real business Cycles [Robinson Crusoe + max U) Plosser (1989b) motivates the Real Business Cycle models by providing a methodological introduction to RBC modeling which criticizes Keynesian economics on two grounds: (1) (2) the absence of a consistent foundation based on a choice theoretic framework of economics the static nature of the Keynesian model that contains none of the dynamic elements found in the earlier business cycle research of Mitchell and Von Hayek. According to Plosser, the introduction of dynamics into the Keynesian system was at best done in an ad hoc fashion such as the accelerator mechanism and the wage and price adjustment equations (the Phillips curve). Real business Cycles [Robinson Crusoe + max U) The basic building block of the RBC model is an aggregate production function that is shocked by technology shocks that shift the marginal product of labor (MPL) causing fluctuations in output. Again, given that workers are on their labor supply function then the economy is in equilibrium. The economy is represented by a dynamic aggregate production function The capital accumulation equation is given by 𝑦𝑡 = 𝜙𝑡 𝐹(𝐾𝑡 , 𝐿𝑡 ) 𝐾𝑡 = 1 − 𝛿 𝐾𝑡−1 + 𝐼𝑡−1 which says that capital increases as a result of additional investment minus depreciation (𝛿). Real business Cycles [Robinson Crusoe + max U) If there are serially correlated technology shocks such that 𝜙𝑡 = 𝜂𝜙𝑡−1 + 𝜖𝑡 or ∞ 𝑗 𝑗=0 𝜂 𝜖𝑡−𝑗 Substituting in the production function, we get 𝜙𝑡 = 𝑦𝑡 = ∞ 𝑗𝜖 𝜂 𝑡−𝑗 𝑗=0 𝐹 𝐾𝑡 , 𝐿𝑡 The production function is shifted continuously through shocks causing shifts in output. Then given a savings rate out of output, capital accumulation will also be a function of the technology shocks. Hence, given random shocks generated by coin tosses for example, both output and capital accumulation will show random fluctuations. Real business Cycles [Robinson Crusoe + max U) Figure 19. Capital stock and output fluctuations in RBC model Real business Cycles [Robinson Crusoe + max U) In the labor market, such shocks cause shifts in the marginal product of labor 𝑀𝑃𝐿𝑡 = 𝑀𝑃𝐿𝑡 = 𝜕𝑦𝑡 𝜕𝐿𝑡 𝜕𝐹𝑡 ∞ 𝑗𝜖 𝜆 𝑡−𝑗 𝜕𝐿 𝑗=0 𝑡 Figure 20. MPL fluctuations in RBC model