Download Fisheries, Chaos and Ethics. A Note on India Status

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Habitat conservation wikipedia , lookup

Theoretical ecology wikipedia , lookup

Overexploitation wikipedia , lookup

Fisheries management wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
365
Int.JLatestTrendsFin.Eco.Sc.
Vol‐3No.1March,2013
Fisheries, Chaos and Ethics.
A Note on India Status
José António Filipe#1, Manuel Coelho*, Manuel Alberto M. Ferreira#2, Selvarasu Appasamy Mutharasu+
#
Instituto Universitário de Lisboa (ISCTE-IUL), BRU – IUL, Portugal
1
[email protected]
2
[email protected]
*
ISEG/UTL & SOCIUS, Portugal
[email protected]
+
Annamalai University, India [email protected]
Abstract – Historically in the world, since last century,
fish stocks of many species have been overexploited. A
good management of fisheries became essential to permit
the preservation of species. Managing fisheries got
increasingly complex, once many interests, often
contradictory, are always involved. Moreover, through
time, political will has not been enough to change things
in many places around the world and overexploitation
has remained for many species. In India, with a strong
population density in many coastal areas depending on
fishing, the situation is very severe for many species and
new requirements for preservation are now being tried.
In literature, fisheries have been analysed in contexts of
uncertainty. Chaos theory is one of the theories that have
been used to explain fisheries. This work intends to
represent a reflection about fisheries overexploitation,
considering the utilization of chaos theory and the
understanding of the related problems taking into
account ethics setting. The India situation is showed.
Keywords ‐ Chaos, Fisheries, Ethics, Overexploitation.
1. Introduction. The General Problem
States, governmental organizations, private
organizations are involved in fisheries. They interact,
and often they cooperate but not unusually they also
show to exist conflicts in the relationships they have
with each other (see, for example, Filipe et al, 2012a).
One of the big questions involving fisheries is how to
manage fisheries in order to guarantee sustainability of
wild fish and to guarantee a financial rent to private
organizations, especially to those profiting from the
exploitation of sea resources, particularly the ones
involving the coastal populations. Companies have to
assure profitability and a hard work has to be done
aiming that.
____________________________________________________________________________________
InternationalJournalofLatestTrendsinFinance&EconomicSciences
IJLTFES,E‐ISSN:2047‐0916
Copyright©ExcelingTech,Pub,UK(http://excelingtech.co.uk/)
In the recent decades, there are many
developments and writings in theoretical and empirical
literature about this subject on fisheries management.
Wild species have often been overexploited. National
and international authorities rule fisheries in order to
maintain balances. However these balances are very
unstable and that is why authorities have large
difficulties to manage fisheries in a sustainable way
(see, for example, Filipe, 2006, Filipe et al, 2007,
Filipe et al, 2008).
Considering that, many solutions may be
presented to solve overexploitation problems and to
preserve live sea resources. One of them is the
approval of aquaculture projects that permit
simultaneously to reduce the exploitation of live sea
resources and allow organizations to find out an
alternative way to guarantee interesting profitability
levels for their activities. Often cooperation exists
among organizations but also conflict is frequent to
exist. And one of the reasons for this conflict in the
sector of fisheries, in a large sense, is the divergent
objectives existing for governmental agencies and
private companies (Filipe, 2006). Another one is the
delay of aquaculture projects approval due to many
reasons. One of them has to be particularly highlighted
in this paper: the bureaucracy (see for details, for
example, Filipe et al, 2008; Filipe et al, 2008b; Coelho
et al, 2009; Filipe et al, 2012b).
Evidently, ethic questions rise. And many
problems result whichever they are for companies, for
live sea resources, for governmental organizations.
The existing interrelationships among the involved
entities conduct also to the emergence of ethical
questions. These matters are, for example, the
overexploitation of live resources, companies losses,
projects unapproved or loss of financial resources. If a
366
Int.JLatestTrendsFin.Eco.Sc.
project is not approved in aquaculture area, it may
work as a factor stressing the need of keeping the
exploitation of sea resources (see Filipe et al, 2011).
Consequently sometimes a single factor may represent
the difference between the sustainability of a specie or
its eventual extinction. In consequence, chaos theory
may be also presented in this analysis to explain such
kind of phenomena (for illustration, see, for example,
Filipe et al, 2005; Filipe et al, 2008a; Filipe et al, 2009;
Filipe et al, 2010; Filipe et al, 2010a; Filipe et al,
2010b) .
In effect, it is interesting to see that,
historically, it is possible to find many simple facts,
considered unimportant and irrelevant in the moment
they happen but that would come to have big
consequences in future developments (Ferreira et al,
2012; Ferreira et al, forthcoming; I Font and Régis,
2006). In fact in a completely unexpected way, they
may have huge impacts that could not be guessed at
the very initial moment and permit to see how often
output is not directly proportional to the input. Chaos
theory will be used in this paper to understand better
some problems of fisheries exploitation.
2.
Chaos and Fisheries
This section is based on Filipe et al (2010a). As
can be seen in the mentioned paper, some
characteristics associated with some species support
strategic survival features that are exploited by the
chaos theory. Its aim is to find the reasons and the way
in which these strategies are developed and the
resulting consequences. The species use their
biological characteristics resulting from evolutionary
ancient processes to establish defence strategies.
However, given the emergence of new forms of
predation, species got weaker because they are not
prepared with mechanisms for effective protection for
such situations. In fisheries there is a predator, man,
with new fishing technologies which can completely
destabilize the ecosystem. By using certain fisheries
technologies, such as networks of siege, allowing the
capture of all individuals of the population who are in
a particular area of fishing, the fishers cause the
breakdown of certain species, particularly the pelagic
ones, normally designated by schooling species.
To that extent, with small changes in
ecosystems, this may cause the complete deterioration
of stocks and the final collapse of ecosystems, which
in extreme cases can lead to extinction. These species
Vol‐3No.1March,2013
are concentrated in high density areas in a small space.
These are species that tend to live in large schools.
Usually, large schools allow the protection
against large predators. The mathematical theory,
which examines the relationship between schools and
predators, due to Brock and Riffenburgh (see Clark,
1974), indicates that the effectiveness of predators is a
reverse function of the size of the school. Since the
amount of fish that a predator can consume has a
maximum average value. Overcoming this limit, the
growth of school means a reduction in the rate of
consumption by the predator. Other aspects defensive
for the school such as intimidation or confusing
predators are also an evidence of greater effectiveness
of schools.
However this type of behaviour has allowed the
development of very effective fishing techniques.
With modern equipment for detecting schools (sonar,
satellites, etc.) and with modern artificial fibers’
networks (strong, easy to handle and quick
placement), fishing can keep up advantageous for
small stocks (Bjorndal, 1987; Mangel and Clark,
1983).
As soon as schools become scarce, stocks
become less protected. Moreover, the existence of
these modern techniques prevents an effect of stock in
the costs of businesses, as opposed to the so-called
search fisheries, for which a fishery involves an action
of demand and slow detection. Therefore, the
existence of larger populations is essential for
fishermen because it reduces the cost of their detection
(Neher, 1990). However, the easy detection by new
technologies means that the costs are not more
sensitive to the size of the stock (Bjorndal and Conrad,
1987).
This can be extremely dangerous due to poor
biotic potential of the species subject to this kind of
pressure. The reproductive capacity requires a
minimum value below which the extinction is
inevitable. Since the efficiency of the school is
proportional to its size, the losses due to the effects of
predation are relatively high for low levels of stocks.
This implies non-feedback in the relation stockrecruitment, which causes a break in the curves of
income-effort, so that an infinitesimal increase on
fishing effort leads to an unstable condition that can
lead to its extinction.
However, considering the fisheries as a broader
issue, we may consider the modelling of the stocks of
367
Int.JLatestTrendsFin.Eco.Sc.
fish on the basis of an approach associated with the
theory of chaos instead of considering the usual
prospect based on classical models. Indeed, the issue
can be placed within this framework from two
different prisms: the traditional vision and the vision
resulting from theories of non-equilibrium. Around the
traditional Newtonian view, the facts can be modelled
in terms of linear relationships: involving the
definition of parameters, identifying relevant variables
and using differential equations to describe the
processes that change slowly over time. For a given
system, it should then carry out measurements in a
context that remains stable during various periods.
Moreover, we may have models based on the theory of
chaos. These models are based on non-linear
relationships and are very close to several disciplines,
particularly in the branch of mathematics that study the
invariant processes of scale, the fractals, and in a huge
range of other subjects in the area of self spontaneous
creation of order: the theory of disasters or complex
systems, for example.
The first way is largely used by the majority of
biologists, economists and environmentalists,
scientists and technical experts that conduct studies in
marine search and senior technicians from state and
transnational agencies in the area of fisheries. It treats
nature as a system, which has a regular order. But
today there are many responsible for fisheries
management who also base their decisions on models
of chaos. The classical models highlight a particular
system and depend on a local analysis, studying
several species, age, class, sub-regions of the marine
eco-niche, the various ports and their discharges,
depending on the account of an even wider range of
other factors. Probably, the classic expression of
linearity on the dynamics of the population (the
principle that nature is orderly, balanced and that has
a dynamic balance) is due to Maynard Smith (1968),
which argues that the populations either remain
relatively constant or regularly vary around an alleged
point of balance. In the specific case of commercial
fisheries, biologists believe that the fishing effort is
often relevant to explain the deviations of actual
populations’ values for the model. They say that,
specially based on studies made in the last decade, fish
stocks sustainability should be ensured by the control
made through fisheries regulation.
Moreover, some people see nature as not casual
and unpredictable. The natural processes are complex
and dynamic, and the causal relations and sequential
patterns may extend so much in time that may seem to
Vol‐3No.1March,2013
be non-periodical. The data appear as selected random
works, disorderly, not causal in their connections and
chaotic. The vision provided by nature leads to
consider the fish stocks, time, the market and the
various processes of fisheries management as likely to
be continuously in imbalance rather than behave in a
linear fashion and in a constant search for internal
balance. It is this perspective that opens the way for
the adoption of the theory of chaos in fisheries.
However, the models of chaos do not deny, for
themselves, some of the linearity resulting from the
application of usual bionomic models. What is
considered is that there are no conditions to implement
all significant variables in a predictive model.
Moreover, in finding that a slight change in initial
conditions caused by a component of the system may
cause major changes and deep consequences in the
system itself. So, the application of the theory of chaos
to fishing is considered essential, by many researchers.
The theory of chaos depends on a multitude of factors,
all major (and in the prospect of this theory all very
important at the outset) on the basis of the wide range
of unpredictable effects that they can cause.
3.
About Fisheries in India
India’s fish exports reported $2.8 billion in
2010-11. The proposed target for 2015 is to raise to $6
billion, supported by 15 million people dependent on
marine fisheries with 25 percent of discarded fish
catch (Nandi, 2012). Over-capacity of marine fishing
boats leading to over-fishing, an over-reliance on
destructive fishing techniques such as bottom
trawling, and continued government subsidies for
mechanized fisheries are the main causes for overexploitation. The use of unsuitable fishing gears result
in a high level of wasteful bycatches and destruction
of egg bearing and juvenile fish (Vijayan, 2000).
Central Marine Fisheries Research Institute of India
has proposed measures to preserve fisheries resources
such as:



banning the fishing activity during breeding
season from September to February;
banning the usage of gears with 30 mm mesh size
to avoid exploitation of under sized clams;
Restricting the grade of export of frozen clams
meat to 1400 Nos./kg and above, and semi-culture
or relaying of small clams by the fishers.
Besides, the sea ranching of pearl oyster spat in
the pearl beds contributed to repopulate the stock to a
certain extent viz. resource utilization, resource
conservation, and marketing.
368
Int.JLatestTrendsFin.Eco.Sc.
It can be demonstrated that fisheries in India are
not easy to manage and there is a visible
overexploitation of stocks for many species. By the
other side, many coastal populations depend on
fisheries. This situation contributes for a unstable state
for many species and to reverse this state may be very
difficult. This requires that not only considerable
studies are required as measures of protection are
urgently needed. A single step overpassing a specific
situation may conduct to the destabilization of the
ecosystem and may provoke a rupture on the species
stocks. Chaos is evident once one single factor or
incident may have huge consequences for the species.
In India, fisheries are managed by bringing the
sector under state government control and all schemes
are managed for fishers’ folks across states of India by
state governmentality.
Is the scenario of over-exploitation in India
expected to be maintained in the future? In truth, there
is now a scheme in vogue to try to reduce the pressure
on some fish stocks. In the month of May a season of
Fishing Holiday is declared with financial assistance
scheme for fishermen for about Rs.4000 (73 USD) per
family. In addition there is a scheme to facilitate
fishermen and fisher-women co-operatives to help to
create common resources for grouping fishing
activities. This is a step in the direction of pursuing
new mentalities that may also contribute to new
sustainability requirements of many species fish stocks
in India.
Also for the ornamental fishes, especially for
wild and exotic fish varieties, a preservation scheme is
also in operation. For example, the anemone and
clown fish production in the aquatic lab is also
promoted by National Fisheries Board in India. There
is also a Rainbow scheme to promote ornamental
fishes in the fresh water.
4.
Ethics and Fisheries
Some of the ethical questions that are raised
from the fisheries analysis come from overexploitation
of resources. Some others result from the relationship
among the stakeholders in the area of fisheries. Some
others may result yet, for example, from the existence
of conflicts in the approval processes of aquaculture
projects. Many divergent interests are involved.
Some ethical issues may be expressed
considering the conflicts that result from the
relationship among private agents and public agents or
Vol‐3No.1March,2013
also some others resulting from environmental policies
that deal with the rights of individuals versus the rights
of the state and that deal also with the rights of
property owners versus those of the community.
The ways of dealing with the environmental
issues may vary according to the organizations that
intend to protect the environment and some conflicting
situations may result from the way environment is
faced.
Often, a private agent intending to exploit a
resource for self interest may be contributing also with
the project for the public good. This fact for itself
permits, on these cases, to solve some ethical issues.
When a private agent intends to implement an
aquaculture project his interest it to make profit.
Anyway, this will allow that sea live resources may be
preserved (Filipe et al, 2011). Aquaculture fish offer
in the market has increased, given an existing demand.
This means that aquaculture can give a strong
contribution for reducing sea fisheries.
Law is fundamental to conserve and to protect
environment and so it is in this area of fishing
resources. Rules should be precise and simple enough
to be implemented and to be fulfilled. In aquaculture
projects law often seems to arise too many procedures
and to generate too many public agents involved in the
decision process that complicate the final decision
(and evidently bureaucracy is present). An anticommons problem can emerge from this complex
situation. In consequence, the multiple agencies and
their work frequently frustrate worthwhile projects and
economic growth (see, for details, Coelho et al, 2012).
5.
Conclusions
Fisheries have been a much debated matter in
the sequence of the overexploitation of wild sea
species. A way to reduce fish catches may result from
the process of fast approval of aquaculture projects.
This will allow to increase the quantity of aquaculture
fish in the market. Anyway, projects approval may
depend on several entities and very often it also
depends on arbitrary and discretionary decisions of the
official entities. This implies that frequently many
projects that are viable and profitable are not approved
timely and are lost. A strong loss of value may be
provoked by the project approval delay. It results from
the so called “anti-commons”. But the delay of
approval of such kind of projects may imply
significant and huge consequences for the future of the
company that has proposed the project. There are also
369
Int.JLatestTrendsFin.Eco.Sc.
significant consequences in terms of the impact on the
exploitation on sea species that would be produced
through the aquaculture project. The resulting
situation may be the persistent exploitation of the
species on the sea and consequently a significant
problem of overexploitation of the species may
remain. A problem of chaos may be also involved. And
this has to continue to be studied very carefully.
Acknowledgments
This work was financially supported by FCT
through
the
Strategic
Project
PEstOE/EGE/UI0315/2011.
References
[1] Bergé, P., Y. Pomeau, C. V. (1984), Order within
chaos. New York: John Wiley.
[2] Berliner, L. M. (1992), Statistics, Probability and
Chaos. Statistical Science, 7 (1), 69-122.
[3] Bjorndal, T. (1987), Production economics and
optimal stock size in a North Atlantic fishery.
Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 89 (2), 145164.
[4] Bjorndal, T. and Conrad, J. (1987), The dynamics
of an open access fishery. Canadian Journal of
Economics, 20(1), 74-85.
[5] Campbell, D. K., Mayer-Kress, G. (1997), Chaos
and politics: Applications of nonlinear dynamics
to socio-political issues. In Grebogi, C. and
Yorke, J. A., The Impact of Chaos on Science and
Society. United Nations University Press.
[6] Capra, F. (1996), The web of life: a new scientific
understanding of living systems. New York :
Anchor Books.
[7] Clark, C. W. (1974), Possible effects of
schooling on the dynamics of exploited fish
populations. Journal du Conseil Internatinal
pour L'Exploration de la Mer, 36 (1), 7-14.
[8] Coelho, M., Filipe, J. A. e Ferreira, M. A. M.
(2009), Coastal development and bureaucracy:
Aquaculture in Portugal. The possible emergence
of an ‘anti-commons tragedy’. 3rd Congress of
Nature Management
and
Conservation.
Proceedings. Cidade da Praia. Cabo Verde.
[9] Coelho, M., Ferreira, M. A. M., Filipe, J. A.,
(2012), Entrepreneurship, Innovation and
Bureaucracy: The Possible Emergence of an
“Anti-commons Tragedy” in the Portuguese
Aquaculture Sector. 15th Uddevalla Symposium
2012 on Entrepreneurship and Innovation
Networks.
Vol‐3No.1March,2013
[10] Farazmand, A. (2003), Chaos and transformation
theories: A theoretical analysis with implications
for organization theory and public management.
Public Organization, 3 (4), 339-372 December.
[11] Ferreira, M. A. M., Menezes, R. (1992),
Equações com Diferenças – Aplicações em
problemas de Finanças, Economia, Sociologia e
Antropologia. Sílabo. Lisboa
[12] Ferreira, M. A. M., Filipe, J. A., Coelho, M.,
Pedro, M. I. (2010), Fishing Policies and the
Contribution of Chaos Theory for Fisheries
Management. International Conference on
Technology and Business Management.
Proceedings.
[13] Ferreira, M. A. M., Filipe, J. A., Coelho, M.,
Pedro, M. I. (2011), Chaos Effect in Fisheries
Management. Journal of Economics and
Engineering, 2 (1), 36-43.
[14] Ferreira, M. A. M., Filipe, J. A., Coelho, M.,
Pedro, M. I. (2011), Modelling the Dissipative
Effect of Fisheries. China-USA Business Review,
10 (11), 1110-1114.
[15] Ferreira, M. A. M., Filipe, J. A. (2012), The
‘Drop of Honey Effect’. A Note on Chaos in
Economics, International Journal of Latest
Trends in Finance and Economic Sciences 2(4),
350-353.
[16] Ferreira, M. A. M., Filipe, J. A., Coelho, M.,
Pedro, M. I. (2013), Managing Fisheries in Light
of Complexity and Chaos Theories. In Banerjee,
S. (2013), Chaos and Complexity Theory for
Management: Nonlinear Dynamics.
[17] Ferreira, M. A. M., Filipe, J. A., Coelho, M.,
Pedro, I., Chaos Theory in Politics: A Reflection.
The ‘Drop of Honey Effect’, in Banerjee, S.
(Ed.), Chaos Theory in Politics, Springer,
Germany. Forthcoming.
[18] Filipe, J. A. (2006), O Drama dos Recursos
Comuns. Um caso de aplicação da Teoria dos
Jogos aos comuns da pesca. PhD thesis. Lisboa:
ISCTE.
[19] Filipe, J. A., Coelho, M., Ferreira, M. A. M.
(2005), Sistemas Dinâmicos, Caos e os Comuns
da Pesca. Revista de Economia Global e Gestão.
N.º 2/2005. Lisboa: ISCTE.
[20] Filipe, J. A., Ferreira, M. A. M., Coelho, M.
(2007), O Drama dos Recursos Comuns nas
Sociedades Actuais: à procura de soluções para
os Ecossistemas em perigo. Edições Sílabo.
Lisboa.
[21] Filipe, J. A., Ferreira, M. A. M., Coelho, M.
(2008a), The Relevance of Chaos Theory to
Explain Problems of Overexploitation in
370
Int.JLatestTrendsFin.Eco.Sc.
Fisheries. Working Paper, WP/24/2008/DE/
SOCIUS. ISEG. Lisboa.
[22] Filipe, J., Ferreira, M., Coelho, M. and Pedro, M.
(2008b), Anti-Commons: How tragedies happen.
Some cases and the evidences on Fisheries,
China - USA Business Review, Volume 7,
Number 11, pp. 9-13.
[23] Filipe, J. A., Ferreira, M. A. M., Coelho, M. e
Andrade, M. (2008), “Anticommons Destroy
Value. Portugal’s Aquaculture Case”. Aplimat Journal of Applied Mathematics, 1(2).
[24] Filipe, J. A., Ferreira, M. A. M., Coelho, M.,
Pedro, M. I. C. (2009), Complexity, Theory of
Chaos and Fishing. In Porath, D. and Bayer, A.,
“International Suplement” special “update”. FH
Mainz, University of Applied Sciences. Mainz,
Germany.
[25] Filipe, J. A., Ferreira, Coelho, M., Pedro, M. I.,
(2010a), Chaos, Anti-chaos and Resources:
Dealing with Complexity. Aplimat-Journal of
Applied Mathematics, 3 (2), 83-90.
[26] Filipe, J. A., Ferreira, M. A. M., Coelho, M.,
Pedro, M. I. (2010b), Managing Complexity: a
Problem of Chaos in Fisheries Policy. ChinaUSA Business Review. David Publishing
Company, 9 (3), pp 15-23.
[27] Filipe, J. A., Ferreira, M. A. M., Coelho, M.,
Pedro, M. I., Andrade, M. (2010), Analysing
Fisheries Management through Complexity and
Chaos Theories Framework, Journal of
Mathematics and Technology, 1(2), pp 5-12.
[28] Filipe, J. A., Ferreira, M. A. M. e Coelho, M.
(2011) An ethical issue in anti-commons
management. Aquaculture case in Portugal.
International Journal of Academic Research.
Baku. Azerbaijan.Vol.3 (1), Part I, pp. 243-245.
[29] Filipe, J. A., Coelho, M. , Ferreira, M. A. M.
(2012). Modelling the sustainability of natural
resources. Journal of Economics and
Engineering; 3(2), 13-17.
[30] Filipe, J. A., Ferreira, M. A. M., Coelho, M.,
Pedro, M. I. (2012a) Cooperation on Stocks
Recover, International Journal of Latest Trends
in Finance and Economic Sciences 2 (1), pp. 7479.
[31] Filipe, J. A., Ferreira, M. A. M., Coelho, M.,
Pedro, M. I. (2012b) Anti-Commons: Fisheries
Problems and Bureaucracy in Aquaculture, 11th
International
Conference
on
Applied
Mathematics - APLIMAT 2012. Slovak
University of Technology in Bratislava.
Proceedings, 1 (1), 669-676.
[32] Galtung, J. (1975), Entropy and the general
theory of peace. Peace: Research Education
Action, Essays
Copenhagen.
Vol‐3No.1March,2013
in
Peace
Research,
1,
[33] Geyer, R. (2003), Europeanisation, Complexity,
and the British Welfare State. Paper presented to
the UACES/ESRC Study Group on The
Europeanisation of British Politics and PolicyMaking, Department of Politics, University of
Sheffield, September 19, 2003.
[34] Grabinski, M. (2004), Is There Chaos in
Management or Just Chaotic Management?.
Complex Systems, intelligence and Modern
Technology Applications. Paris.
[35] Grabinski, M. (2008), Chaos – Limitation or
Even End of Supply Chain Management. High
Speed Flow of Material, Information and Capital.
Istanbul.
[36] Hastings, A., Hom, C. L., Ellner, S., Turchin, P.,
Godfray, H. C. J. (1993), Chaos in Ecology: Is
Mother Nature a Strange Attractor?, Annual
Review of Ecology and Systematics, 24 (1), 1-33.
[37] I Font, J. P. P., Régis, D. (2006), Chaos Theory
and its Application in Political Science. (Draft),
IPSA – AISP Congress, Fukuoka.
[38] Kauffman, S. (1993), The origins of order: selforganization and selection in evolution. New
York: Oxford Univ. Press.
[39] Lansing, J. S. (2003), Complex adaptive systems.
Annual
Review
Anthropology.
http://www.ic.arizona.edu/lansing/GompAdSys.
pdf.
[40] Lévêque, G. (2002), Ecologia: do ecossistema à
biosfera. Lisboa: Instituto Piaget.
[41] Levin, S. (2003), Complex adaptive systems:
exploring the known, the unknown and the
unknowable. Bulletin of the American
Mathematical Society, 40.
[42] Mancel, M., Clark, G. (1983), Uncertainty,
search and information in fisheries. Journal du
Conseil International pour L’Exploration de la
Mer, 41.
[43] Maynard Smith, J. (1968). Mathematical ideas in
biology. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
[44] Michelman, F. I. (1982), Ethics, economics and
the law of property. In J. R. Pennock and J. W.
Chapman (Eds.), Nomos XXIV: Ethics,
Economics and the Law, New York: New York
University Press.
[45] Mohan, J., Jayaprakash, A. (2003), Status of
exploited marine fishery resources in India,
CMFRI, ICAR, India.
[46] Nandi, J. (2012), India's fish resources overexploited: Report, Times of India, TNN Jun 8,
371
Int.JLatestTrendsFin.Eco.Sc.
2012,
05.13PM
IST
http://articles.
timesofindia.indiatimes.com/2012-06-08/
developmental-issues/32123502_1_fish-exportstrawling-estuarine (Visited on 15-01-2013).
[47] Narasimha,
G,
Raghavan
(2004),
Governmentality: Panacea From Chaos Why the
fisher folk of Kolavai Lake want the Government
to
regulate
them,
CCS
RESEARCH
INTERNSHIP PAPERS, Centre for Civil
Society, K-36 Hauz Khas Enclave, New Delhi.
[48] Neher, P. (1990), Natural Resource Economics:
Conservation and Exploitation, Cambridge
University Press.
[49] Olsen, L. F., Degn, H. (1985). Chaos in
biological systems. Quarterly Review of
Biophysics, 18(2), 165-225.
[50] Ostrom, E. (1990), Governing the Commons. The
Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action,
Cambridge University Press.
[51] Parisi, F., Depoorter, B., & Schulz, N. (2005),
Duality in Property: commons and anticommons, International Review of Law and
Economics 25(4), 1-25.
[52] Polinsky, A., Shavell S. (2000), The Economic
Theory of Public Enforcement of Law, Journal
of Economic Literature, Vol. 38, pp. 45-76.
[53] Rasband, N. S. (1990), Chaotic dynamics of
nonlinear systems. New York: John Wiley.
[54] Schlager, E., Ostrom, E. (1992), Property-Rights
Regimes and Natural Resources: A Conceptual
Analysis, Land Economics, Vol. 68, Nº 3, pp
249-262.
[55] Scones, I. (1999), New ecology and the social
sciences: what prospects for a fruitful
engagement?, Annual Review of Anthropology,
28.
[56] Scott, A. (1979), Development of Economic
Theory on Fisheries Regulation, Journal of the
Fisheries Research Board of Canada, Vol. 36,
pp. 725-741.
[57] Seabright, P. (1993), Managing Local Commons:
Theoretical Issues in Incentive Design, Journal
of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 7, Nº 4, pp 113134.
[58] Sumaila, U., Alder, J. & Keith, H. (2006), Global
Scope and Economics of Illegal Fishing, Marine
Policy, Vol 30, pp. 696-703.
[59] Tietenberg, T. (2003), Environmental and
Natural Resource Economics, sixth edition,
Addison Wesley.
[60] Williams, G. P. (1997), Chaos theory tamed.
Washington, D. C.: Joseph Henry Press.
Vol‐3No.1March,2013
[61] Vijayan, V., Edwin, L., Ravindran, K. (2000)
Conservation and management of marine fishery
resources of Kerala State, India. Naga, the
ICLARM Quarterly, 23(3), pp. 6-9.