* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Luis Currais From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition: Contemporary research and beyond V. II N. 3 JUNHO pp. 75-101 Luis Currais * 1. Introduction The effects of economic factors on fertility and mortality were a central element in development for Malthus (1798). Other economists such as Adam Smith (1776), Schumpeter (1954, pp. 163-164) and David Hume (Rostow, 1990) also discussed the link between population and subsistence resources. According to their predictions, rising prosperity would yield a greater increase in population growth until a food supply limit was reached. Although the findings of empirical studies do not support the Malthusian paradigm (Shultz, 1985, pp. 1126-1154; Kremer, 1993, 681-716) its impact meant that population began to be treated as an endogenous element derived from economic and social conditions. This work is restricted to studies which are related to the problem of population and growth. We analyze the evolution of fertility and mortality rates and other important facets of population growth literature. It can be observed that the changes in reproductive behavior, which occur during the economic development process are strongly linked to the transformation of traditional agricultural economies with rudimentary technology, into modern societies. Before this transition takes place fertility rates are high and the use of contraception is virtually absent. Conversely, the vast majority of couples in developed * We are especially grateful to Jordi Caballe, Howard Carter, Berta Rivera and Manuel Gomez, and to participants at the Annual Congress of the German Economic Association for discussions and valuable comments. We thank the financial support from La Coruña University, N. 64902-25507.Correspondence to: Luis Currais, Department of Economic Analysis, Faculty of Economics, La Coruña University, Campus da Zapateira, 15071, La Coruña, Spain. Tel: (981) 167000; Fax: (981) 167070. e-mail: [email protected]. Econômica, nº 3,pp. 75-101, junho 2000 75 From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition 76 societies limit their family size, which evolves according to the altruism of parents. There are several factors that have crucial effects on fertility levels and their trends. Several authors have studied the relationship between fertility, population and economic growth and its consequences for development and well-being. Recent literature considers the mortality rate as an endogenous variable that depends fundamentally on health care. A genuine understanding of the economic growth process should contemplate the extent to which fertility and longevity affect the population growth rate, when considered as endogenous variables related to the socio-economic process. Our analysis follows the evolution of the main paradigms contained in the literature on population and growth literature and their contribution to our understanding of demographic phenomena. We examine the historical evolution of the relationship between population growth, technological change and standard of living. The way in which this evolution takes place is presented through the progressive treatment of key variables as endogenous to the growth process. We cite various studies, which identify some key variables that act either exogenously or endogenously and which provide us with a variety of insights into government policy. This paper is organized into six sections. In the following section we briefly review Malthusian population theory and later refinements of it, which incorporate a more formal analysis of its static and dynamic components. Section three presents the most important references on endogenous population growth. This section focuses on the effects of child rearing costs and their importance for fertility models. This literature reflects the relationship between economic variables and population as a complex web of factors related to the incentives to have children and which depend on the cost of quantity and quality of children. Section four explores a relatively new line of research followed by some authors. These works stress the role of health, and study the multiple implications of improved health on morbidity and longevity. Economic development and health status influence the population growth rate through their impact on fertility and mortality rates. The relationship between the endogenous mortality rate, productivity and Econômica, nº 3, pp. 75-101, junho 2000 Luis Currais growth is also analyzed in this section. In section five we analyze the different demographic regimes and the demographic transition. We discuss social and economic changes, beginning with the Malthusian paradigm and examining transitional demographic dynamics and the modern demographic evolution of societies through different economic models. Section six concludes with the main remarks and their relevance for both economic and population growth process, whilst discussing areas of potential future research. 2. Malthus and the classical theory of population and growth The main thesis within Malthusian population theory is the dependence of population growth on the material conditions of the economy. Human biological capacity to reproduce would surpass the physical capacity to produce. In this context the food supply would be not sufficient to accompany increasing demand. In Malthuss view, the perfection of a human society free of coercive restraints was utopian, because the capacity for threat of population growth would always be present. When population size is small, the standard of living will be high, and population will grow as a natural result of passion between the sexes. Without constraint, population would rise geometrically, but food production rises only arithmetically. Malthus reversed the arguments of mercantilists whose posited that the number of people determined the nations resources, adopting instead the stance of the Physiocrats who stated that the resource-base determined the number of people. Population growth would be checked by the growth of food production and the Mathusian trap would emerge as a result of a dismally low level of per capita consumption. Deviations from this trap would be only possible by negative or preventive checks on the birth rate, giving special emphasis to the characteristic late marriage pattern of western Europe, which he called moral restraint or by positive checks on the death rate through the periodic outbreak of wars, malnutrition, pestilence, disease and famine. The other preventive checks which he mentioned were birth control, abortion, adultery and homosexuality, all of which as an Anglican minister he considered immoral. Econômica, nº 3,pp. 75-101, junho 2000 77 From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition 78 The Malthusian model implies that the source of possible short run deviations from the populations equilibrium level is related to the motive of parents for having children. Once children are considered as capital goods, which are produced at constant costs, an increase in the labor demand would raise the expected returns of having children and increase the fertility rate. In the absence of changes in technology or in the availability of land, population would be stable around a constant level. Those improvements in technology, which occur in the long run, would be offset by increases in the size of population. The assumptions of the Malthusian model are consistent with the historical evolution of technology, population and per capita output for most countries. Economic development allows us to infer, in Malthusian terms, that the emergence process from the Malthusian trap was slow and the positive check was being weakened whereas the preventive check was being progressively enforced. Although economists before Malthus made some of the observations which Malthus made, it was the work of Malthus which had the greatest influence on the major classical economists that followed him.1 Perhaps the most important legacy of Malthus has been the treatment of population growth as endogenous to the economy as a result of both economic conditions and the motives for having children. These and other aspects of the classical theory are discussed in contemporary economic literature in models that emphasize the existence of multiple equilibria, including a poverty trap, and the importance of both fertility and mortality in economic growth. 3. Endogenous population growth: The role of fertility models and child rearing costs Prior to the 50s, apart from the Malthusian theory of population change, economists paid scarce attention to questions related to family Before Malthus, see for instance Botero (1589), Adam Smith (1776), Schumpeter (1954, p. 255) and David Hume (Rostow, 1990). The influence of Malthus may be noticed first in the works of Ricardo and John Stuart Mill and his propositions remain on the development of modern population and growth theory. 1 Econômica, nº 3, pp. 75-101, junho 2000 Luis Currais and its consequences for fertility and the economic development process. Firstly Long (1958) and later Mincer (1962), argued that the participation of married women in the labor force is determined not only by their potential earnings, but also by their husbands earnings, the number of children they have and other family characteristics. A modern economic analysis of fertility began to replace the Malthusian analysis, and the parental demand for children has been shown to depend on family income, how parents value their time and the quality of children (Becker, 1960; Easterlin, 1968). Alternatively, several researchers looked at human capital investment, taking into account the relationship between parental investment in their childrens education and the childrens productivity (Schultz, 1963; Becker, 1994). Following the work of Becker (1960) in which he analyses the behavior of demographic and economic changes in developed countries and the role of fertility, several authors have studied the feedback between population growth and development. Economists generally assume that there are two basic reasons to have children: the provision of material benefits to the family unit, and the consideration of children as pure consumption goods which implies the pleasure parents derive from their childrens existence. In both cases the specifications which are used can be viewed as an expression of parents altruism. The material benefits of having children might include the contribution of labor services to a family business or even in looking after parents in their old age. We therefore review the studies that have attempted to determine the extent to which these affect fertility rates and what this implies for population levels and growth. The hypothesis which puts forward exogenous population growth as inherent in the neoclassical models of Solow (1956, pp. 6594), Cass (1965, pp. 233-240) and Koopmans (1965), which neglect interactions between the economic growth process and demographic trends is clearly unsatisfactory. These models are unable to capture the observable diversity of population growth through the variance in the behavior of fertility and mortality rates among different countries. We might make a similar observation for a single economy over time and around the development process. Econômica, nº 3,pp. 75-101, junho 2000 79 From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition 80 Endogenous population growth literature has progressed along two basic theoretical lines of research. On the one hand, we find those studies that follow the neoclassical growth model where the economic growth rate is exogenously determined and, on the other those models based on endogenous economic growth. The neoclassical model offers a comprehensive, rigorous treatment of population and income variables, although per capita income growth is exogenously determined. In this context, our study focuses on some of the models that treat population growth as an endogenous variable. The analysis of endogenous population growth along with the analysis of several economic factors in different static and dynamic environments yield distinct results. In the literature of population and growth we can highlight the importance of certain factors like the quantity and quality of children and the effects of the social security system, and the role of intergenerational transfers. These factors are considered in either endogenous or exogenous economic growth research. The first systematic analysis of the interaction between quantity and quality of children is offered in Becker and Lewis (1973, S279S288). This is a static model, which stresses the role played by the desired human capital of children. The model therefore, does not allow us to analyze the dynamic aspects of the interaction between quantity and quality of children. Parents maximize a utility function where both quantity and quality enter as distinct elements, which are subject to a specific budget constraint. The problem they study is formalized as max U = U ( x , q , y ) , subject to I = xqP + yPy , where x is the number of children, q is their quality, y is the consumptions rate of other commodities, I represents income and P is the price of a unit of child quality. The model offers a simple explanation for the observation that when income increases the fertility rate decreases. The shadow price of the number of children x is greater the higher their quality q and the shadow price of q is higher the greater x is. The income elasticity of demand for quality is higher than that for quantity. Thus, when Econômica, nº 3, pp. 75-101, junho 2000 Luis Currais income increases the shadow price of quantity increases more than the shadow price of quality. The work of Eckstein and Wolpin (1985, pp. 93-106) focuses on the role of the stock of human capital of working adults. The cost of children is a function of parents income, which affects the cost of child rearing. They assume that per capita income is a function of human capital accumulation, and that they are positively correlated. In their model the fertility rate first rises and then falls, thus explaining a basic feature of the demographic transition. We may consider the models of Becker and Barro (1988, pp. 1-25) and Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995) as extensions of the previous two models. Although Barro and Sala-iMartin (1995) use a continuous time approach and Becker and Barro (1988) use an overlapping generations framework in two time periods, the general results are quite similar. Parental decisions about numbers of children are made jointly along with choices about consumption and intergenerational transfers. The choice of the number of children interacts with the determination of their quality, which depends on consumption and the quantity of capital stock allocated to each person. The fertility rate depends on the marginal utility attached to children, which diminishes with their number. Intergenerational transfers and more specifically the social security system have potentially important implications for fertility behavior. Leibenstein (1963) was one of the firsts to argue that social security policies may reduce fertility. Weight was given to this assumption by various studies, some of which we highlight here. Nugent and Gillapsy (1983, pp. 809-830) and later Entwisle and Winegarden (1984, pp. 331-354) carry out similar empirical studies based on a cross-section analysis of groups of less developed countries. They also obtained similar results. Changes in the fertility rates are negatively related to the social security proxy variable, after controlling for other explanatory variables. For Cadwell (1976; 1982) in any society and at any stage of economic development the fertility rate is fundamentally determined by the direction of the intergenerational flow of wealth. In the less Econômica, nº 3,pp. 75-101, junho 2000 81 From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition 82 developed societies children contribute to their parents wealth, while in developed societies it is the parents who leave bequests or invest in childrens human capital. This process increases the cost of having children and consequently decreases the fertility rate. A different approach is considered by Willis (1989). In order to analyze the role of old-age security on fertility he considers the existence of uncertainty with respect to ones longevity and imperfect annuity markets. He concludes that within this context fertility increases in comparison to a perfect market situation. Cigno and Rosati (1992, pp. 319-341) develop a three-stage finite horizon model in order to analyze the effect of social security on fertility. They compare the strength of parents self interest and the intergenerational altruism through the impact of the social security system. The model considers that young working parents support their parents and lend resources to their children at a given interest rate, and then collect on these loans for old-age support, so childrens utility is specified as a part of the parents utility. Using Italian time series data they present three sets of results that depend on the relative strength of the selfish old-age security motive and the intergenerational altruism motive. Ehrlich and Lui (1991, pp. 1029-1059) realize a cross-section analysis for 65 countries, which includes both poor and rich countries. They find that, after controlling for GDP and measurements of both young-age and old-age longevity, social security benefits as a percentage of GDP in 1960 had a significant negative impact on the birth rate in 1965 and on the total fertility rate in 1975 in poor countries. For relatively rich countries however, they do not obtain the significant effects observed for poor countries. An important conclusion can be derived from these studies. The quantity of children is not the only important variable within parental control. When we consider the quality of children and the availability of savings opportunities as complementary choice variables, the effect of the reduction on fertility due to the provision of old-age social security is not clear (see Wildasin, 1990, pp. 414-428; Ehrlich & Lui, 1998, pp. 390-409). Econômica, nº 3, pp. 75-101, junho 2000 Luis Currais In the last few years research has contributed important new results to the literature on population and growth as endogenous variables. We take a look at some of the studies which are based on models where economic growth and population growth rates are endogenous and simultaneously determined as a result of distinct initial conditions or changes in the parameters of the model that yield economic growth. The work of Becker, Murphy and Tamura (1990, pp. S12-S37) represents an important reference point, since they have been the first to offer an endogenous population and growth model based on explicit micro-foundations that provide an explanation for some of the features of the demographic transition. In their model, the time parents spent on investing in the human capital of their children, and the number of children, are choice variables. The rates of return on investment, in both the quantity of children and their human capital, depend on both the level of human capital of the dynasty head and the chosen number of children. The per capita income growth and consumption are endogenous variables that depend on human capital, which is considered to be the engine of economic growth. The optimal solution of the model presents three steady-state equilibria: a stable state, which is a low-level state, with a low level of human capital and zero growth, an intermediate but unstable state of development, and a stable state of perpetual growth with higher human capital. If the initial level of human capital is higher than a threshold level, which is linked to the unstable development equilibrium, then human capital investment becomes more worthwhile, the fertility rate is lower than other equilibria, and growth is persistent. If the initial level of human capital is lower than this threshold level, the economy moves towards a Malthusian regime characterized by high fertility, no investment in childrens human capital and no economic growth. Ehrlich and Lui (1991; 1998) develop a three period overlapping generations model where young parents decide on the number of children, the amount of human capital investment per child and the expected material compensation from their children in old-age. The existence of intergenerational trade allows for implicit contracts Econômica, nº 3,pp. 75-101, junho 2000 83 From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition 84 between parents and children, and eliminates the multiple equilibria of outcome and the problem of potential intergenerational externalities of the Becker, Murphy and Tamura model. In their model the optimal solution is unique at any particular point in time. The motive for having children depends on the rate of return to parents which is a function of the life expectancy of children and parents, their time preference, the human capital technology and the optimal rate at which children compensate their parents investment in them. The latter two models share some key features. In both models the engine for growth is human capital and fertility behavior is a consequence of the relationship between quantity and quality of children. In a dynamic context there is a feedback effect between population and growth, which also depends on other factors that jointly determine the process of economic development. Although these dynamic relationships give us some insights into the association between income, education and fertility across economies, there are some aspects of the demographic transition that are not considered. The role of mortality, which is an important part of the demographic transition is not explicitly modeled. This gap in research might be filled by more fully analyzing the implications of human capital and health investment on longevity and fertility pointed out by various authors and supported by various studies which have been carried out by the World Bank and the World Health Organization, and which we discuss in next section. 4. The mortality rate, health spending and economic growth Human health and its relevance to population growth is one of the great themes of human history. Although demographic changes and trends with respect to health are closely linked, they are often considered separately. The relationship between health and population is a two-way process that yields feedback. Each can be a determinant as well as a consequence of the other. The way in which they influence each other may be a fundamental factor when deciding public policy and intervention. Econômica, nº 3, pp. 75-101, junho 2000 Luis Currais The world-wide situation today with respect to health is characterized by the huge differences in the mortality profiles of those who live in developed, developing or underdeveloped countries. In the most developed countries, there is an enhanced expectation of life at birth, an important component of which is improved survival in early life, particularly from birth to the first birth year. According to the World Bank Health Report (1993) and WHO (1993) there are four groups of factors which contribute decisively to high levels of life expectancy: rising incomes, health expenditure, improvements in medical technology, and shifts in social behavior and cultural factors such as education and in particular female education. Each of these groups of factors has influenced the decline in mortality rates and increased life expectancy in different countries to varying degrees. The role of preventive and curative policy depends on the level of development of medical technology and the level of per capita health expenditure within the society. The contribution of any one specific factor to contemporary declines in mortality would be difficult to quantify, but these declines are certainly influenced by recent advances in medical technology and increases in health expenditure, whereas historically, declines in mortality were more as a result of economic factors such as education, nutrition and behavioral changes. According to the World Bank, differences in health spending are an important starting point in the search for an explanation of the differences in health and mortality rates among countries. In 1990, total annual health spending ranged from less than $10 per person in several African and Asian countries to more than $2.700 in the United States. There was also considerable variation within regions. In Africa, Tanzania spent only $4 per capita on health in 1990, while Zimbabwe spent $42 per person. In Asia, Bangladesh spent $7 per person each year, as against $377 in Korea. Since the share of GNP devoted to health tends to rise with income, the difference between what rich and poor countries spend on health is even greater than their difference in income. As a consequence of this, life expectancy ranges from forty years or less in some countries in Sub-Saharan Africa to seventy-five or more in developed economies. In Sub-Saharan Africa half of all Econômica, nº 3,pp. 75-101, junho 2000 85 From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition 86 deaths occur below the age of 5. In the developed economies half occur after the age of 74. Child mortality rates exceed 200 per 1.000 in several African countries but are below 20 in the richest countries. The level of disease, in per capita terms, is five times higher in developing regions than in the healthiest regions. Falls in mortality and morbidity rates, which are linked to per capita health expenditure and their consequences for a healthier population and work force, are important in promoting economic productivity and fomenting economic development. In the long run the benefits of improved health are also likely to influence the way work is organized and carried out. Endogenous population growth literature also points out the important link between human capital and health economics theories and their consequences for fertility and longevity (Grossman, 1972; Ehrlich & Chuma, 1990, pp. 761-782). Different authors focus on the relationship between population, growth and human capital, stressing the role of health by using different theoretical and empirical approaches. In studying the implications of health economics on economic growth Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995, p. 432) find that life expectancy should be considered as an important growth factor. They calculate that a 13 year increase in life expectancy would yield an increase in the annual growth rate by 1.4 percentage points. Jablonski, Rosemblum and Kunze (1988, pp. 34-38) obtain similar empirical conclusions for life expectancy. They study the relationship between life expectancy, productivity and health. Their results support the theoretical and empirical findings of Currais and Rivera (1999a, pp. 258-267;1999b, pp. 761-764) where health expenditure, used as a proxy of health status, increases productivity through its effect on human capital accumulation. Estimates are made for the OCDE countries for the period 1960-90. They find that investment in health contributes in a significant way to explaining variations in output through human capital, even in those countries, which presumably have high levels of health. This result is justified fundamentally by the decrease in the depreciation rate of human capital and the reduction in morbidity which affects the mortality rate. Econômica, nº 3, pp. 75-101, junho 2000 Luis Currais There are several empirical studies that study the positive correlation between higher per capita health expenditure and lower mortality rates (WHO, 1993; Kawachi et al., 1997, 1491-1498). Beyond this relationship we find those works that analyze the positive impact of higher health spending on lower mortality rates and higher economic growth, which would be probably bounded in the most developed countries (World Bank, 1993; Fogel, 1997). Evidence obtained by these authors was very important in promoting new research based on dynamic models, which incorporate trends in mortality, fertility, intergenerational transfers and economic growth. Blackburn and Cipriani (1998, pp. 517-534) develop an overlapping generation model where parents choose savings and births and may also reduce infant deaths by incurring expenditure on health care, which is also provided by the government. A generalized production technology accounts for long-run endogenous growth. Their results confirm the importance of health care on reducing mortality rates. Economic and demographic outcomes are determined jointly in a choice-theoretical model of fertility, mortality and capital accumulation, and the results support the empirical evidence on the relationship between demography and development. A different benchmark is presented in Currais and Gomez (1999) and Currais (2000). They use an infinite horizon framework that represents an altruistic link between parents and children, to the childrens children and so on. Individuals choose their consumption levels and the number of children they have in order to maximize the household optimization problem. The intertemporal dynastic utility function can be formally described by U = ∫ ∞ 0 e − ρt [ N ψ ( c + ϕ g )( n − d ( gˆ )) φ ]1 − θ − 1 dt 1−θ where p is the rate of time preference and represents parental altruism. N is the size of the family, n is the fertility rate, and d ( gˆ ) is the mortality rate. The familys budget constraint in per capita terms is represented as k& = w + [( 1 − τ k ) r − n + d ( gˆ ) ]k − bnk − ( 1 + τ c ) c − ( 1 − s g ) g − R Econômica, nº 3,pp. 75-101, junho 2000 87 From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition 88 where w is the wage rate, r is the interest rate, tc is the consumption tax rate, tk is the capital tax rate, sg is the subsidy rate and R is a lump sum tax and bk denotes the opportunity costs that increase as parental capital increases. The number of children depends on the child rearing costs and health spending, which in turn also affects the mortality rate. Higher health spending produces a lower mortality rate and a higher per capita capital in the steady state. The analysis reveals that the mortality and the fertility rates are correlated both significantly and negatively with per capita income. As the economy develops both the mortality and the fertility rates fall, and these falls are accompanied by an increase in per capita income, which characterizes the demographic transition. Recent works attempt to explain how developing economies have typically moved from a state of low per capita income, high mortality and high fertility to a regime of persistent growth in which first mortality, and then fertility are continuously declining while per capita income presents persistent growth. The following section discusses this phenomenon, known as the transition from the Malthusian regime to the modern demographic transition. 5. From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition Over approximately the last sixty years the demographic transition has been a leading topic for growth economists interested in population growth and modern demography. Notesteins article (1945, pp. 36-57) is generally regarded as the first acceptable formulation of the demographic transition theory. The first outline of the theory however was undertaken somewhat earlier by the Office of Population Research in Princeton which based its work on previous research carried out by Notestein et al. (1944). Indeed, Notestein did not refer to his generalization as a transition. The first to use this expression was Adolphe Landry (1934) and some years later Davis (1943) referred to the transition in a publication that he edited and which was published almost at the same time as Notesteins work. The demographic transition theory is based on the idea that the societies which undergo a process of modernization, progress from Econômica, nº 3, pp. 75-101, junho 2000 Luis Currais a pre-modern regime of high fertility and high mortality to a postmodern regime, in which both decrease. The key term modernization includes the crucial questions about causation that form the subject of much of the modern demographic literature. The basis of the demographic transition model is a classification of populations which are differentiated in terms of their distinct combinations of fertility and mortality. Thompson (1929, pp. 959975) carried out the first formulation of this type, which is to be found in English demographic literature. He specified three groups of countries with different rates of population growth. In the first group are to be found the countries from Western Europe along with countries, which were originally settled by European immigrants. Although mortality in these countries was low, their rapidly declining fertility rates indicate first a stationary and then declining population growth. The second group included the countries of Eastern and Southern Europe. For these countries both birth and death rates had fallen, but death rates had declined sooner and more rapidly than birth rates. As a result their populations grew very rapidly, until they reached a stationary state which was then followed by declining population. This trend is comparable to that of the first group some 35 to 40 years earlier. In the third group Thompson suggested that we would find nearly 75 per cent of the worlds population. The lack of data confined his analysis to those countries were data was available, that is, to Japan, India and Russia. Those countries in which neither birth nor death rates were under control were classified as Malthusian. Following the work of Thompson, Landry (1934), also postulated three stages of population development: primitive, intermediate and contemporary. It was roughly equivalent to Thompsons classification, although Landrys analysis of the decline in mortality and fertility rates was much more in depth than that of Thompson. Later, Notestein (1945) presented a typology of populations which has many parallels with the works of Thompson (1929) and Landry (1934). His study analyses three types of populations as a way of introducing a review of the potential effects of world population growth. For him the changes in norms and values associated with the Econômica, nº 3,pp. 75-101, junho 2000 89 From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition 90 process of modernization were the major reason for the decline in fertility. Coale and Hoover (1958) and later Coale (1963, p. 69) stressed the importance of the socio-economic aspects of the modernization process, although they paid more attention to cultural factors. Their works are indispensable reference points in population growth literature. Their main conclusion was that national economic growth is impaired if fertility levels greatly exceed mortality levels. The implications for demographic transition theory were that transition was made possible only by profound changes in the social structures of societies.2 In 1974 Julian Simon assessed and summarized much of the research evidence available on fertility and economic development concluding that everywhere fertility is subject to much rational control. This rational control is directly linked to higher educational levels and advances in birth control. According to Kremer and Chen (1999, pp. 155-160) the presumption that as education levels rise, fertility rates fall is a strong evidence in developing countries. They suppose a production technology represented by Y = LαS L1U−α where L S and L U are the number of skilled and unskilled workers. Income distribution dynamics depends on the simplified utility function that is given by U = ln( n ) + X where n is the number of children and X is consumption. They used data from 62 countries from 1974 to 1995, regressing total fertility on womens years of education. Fertility differentials between educated and uneducated women are typically greater in countries with high Gini coefficients of inequality. For example, in Brazil, women with no education have three times as many children as women with ten or more years of education. Since children of the uneducated are less likely Evidence on demographic transition theory can be found in Rostow (1990) and Kirk (1996, pp. 361-387). 2 Econômica, nº 3, pp. 75-101, junho 2000 Luis Currais to become educated, this threefold difference in fertility creates a major demographic force, which increases the proportion of unskilled work force. We can take the main arguments used for national populations and apply them to individual families in order to focus the analysis of population growth on the ideal family size. This was the main postulate in subsequent research, which culminated in various studies on rational fertility control. The analysis which followed therefore were to focus not only on behavioral rationality with respect to fertility but also on behavioral economic rationality. The central idea was that family size would tend to correspond to a number, which maximizes the net utility to be derived from having children in the society. Within this framework of rational decision, fertility decline may be viewed as a rational response to economic and social changes within society. The majority of the recent literature on the relationship between population growth and output has been directed towards analyzing the various aspects and evidence of the modern demographic regime and the demographic transition. This process of demographic transition have taken shape in the developed countries over the last century, and which are now taking shape in much of the rest of the world. The studies cited in the previous sections, focus on the negative association between income and population growth through numerous works based on cross-sectional analysis of countries or time series data. The dynamics of population growth reflected both changes in constraints and qualitative changes in household behavior induced by the economic environment. High levels of both fertility and mortality had characterized the Malthusian demographic regime. As living standards rose, mortality fell. Reductions in mortality rates initially led to an increase in population growth, both because more children reach breeding age and because individuals live longer. The initial effect of higher income was an increase in fertility, mainly by causing an increase in the propensity to marry. According to Dyson and Murphy (1985, pp. 399-440) fertility rates increased in most of Western Europe until the second half of the nineteenth century, peaking in England and Wales in 1871 and in Germany in 1875. But as income continued Econômica, nº 3,pp. 75-101, junho 2000 91 From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition 92 to rise, population growth fell further below the maximum rate that could be sustained given the mortality regime. The reduction in fertility was extremely rapid in Europe around the turn of the century. In England, live births per 1000 women aged 15-44 fell from 153.6 in 1871-80 to 109.0 in 1901-10. The reversal in the Malthusian relationship between income and population growth was directly linked to an increase in the level of resources invested in each child. Matthews et al. (1982) point to an increase in the average number of schooling years in England and Wales from 2.3 for the cohort born 1801-05 to 5.2 in 1852-56 and 9.1 for the cohort born 1897-1906. Maddison (1982, 1995) analyze the relationship between the population growth rate and the growth rate of per capita income for Western Europe over the period 500/1990. His analysis indicates that from the year 500 to 1820 the population growth rate was exceeded the income per capita growth rate until 1820, when this tendency changed. From 1820 to 1990 per capita income growth increases progressively in comparison to the population growth rate which decreases continuously. Recently Kremer (1993) and Lucas (1996) reexamined the Malthusian regime in two different papers. The former develops a model in which the rate of technological progress is proportional to the size of the population. His model yields an acceleration in the growth rate of total output whilst the level of per capita output remains constant and the demographic transition does not follow that stage. The latter develops a Malthusian model in which households make optimizing choices with respect to fertility and consumption, but the transition from this regime is not considered. Gary Becker et al. (1999, pp. 145-149) explores the implications of human capital accumulation and urban-economics on population and economic growth as determinants of the demographic transition. For them, in modern urban economies, the increased density that comes with bigger populations and greater urbanization promotes higher investment in human capital, specialization, and the rapid accumulation of new knowledge. They consider two different effects which take place and these depend on the relative density of the population of the city. On the one hand, population may reduce productivity because of Econômica, nº 3, pp. 75-101, junho 2000 Luis Currais traditional diminishing returns from the more intensive use of land and other natural resources. On the other hand, bigger cities with high population densities tend to encourage greater specialization and greater productivity, and these factors lead to increases in per capita income and increases in the shadow cost of having large families compared to investing more in each child. Rather than explicitly modeling a utility function and a value function for a dynastic family, they assume a parental utility function such as U = u ( c) + an1−eV ( q ) where e is the elasticity of parental utility with respect to number of children, c is consumption, n is the number of children and q is the human capital level of each child which is produced primarily in the urban sector. Here the utility function is separable between current consumption and childrens human capital depends not only on parental time and parental human capital but also on population density which is greater in big cities. The demographic transition towards smaller families in economies with initially high fertility and low per capita incomes may be stimulated by an initial growth in population. The consideration of urban-economics introduces a new and important element into the analysis of the demographic transition through its implications on income and population growth. Galor and Weil (1999, pp. 150-154) adopt a different approach and develop a single unified model, which describes the whole economic transition process from the Malthusian regime to the modern growth regime. In the Malthusian regime, there is a link association between population growth and the level per capita income. Technological progress is slow and offset by proportional increases in population, thus per capita output remains stable at a constant level. In the postMalthusian regime, the growth rates for technology and total output increase. Population growth absorbs much of the growth of output, but per capita income rises slowly. The positive relationship between per capita income and population growth is reversed and the economy undergoes a demographic transition. In the modern growth regime, population growth is moderate or even negative, and technology and Econômica, nº 3,pp. 75-101, junho 2000 93 From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition per capita income increase rapidly. The evolution of technological change leads to a rise in the rate of human capital return. Parents switch from quantity to quality of children in response to technological progress, rather than in response to changes in the level of income. The building of unified population and development models that address not only the demographic transition and contemporary growth regimes but also the Malthusian regime, which has characterized much of human history, are essential for a fuller understanding of the development process. The entire transition analysis allows us a more complete understanding of the situation with respect to population, growth and their evolution in the future. 6. Conclusions 94 In the literature analyzed in this paper we attempted to include the most relevant references on the formal treatment of the problem of population and growth in a very comprehensive way. In societies of every type and stage of development, fertility and mortality are fundamentally associated with the socio-economic aspects of the modernization process. This process is a result of several determinants which are analyzed in different theoretical and empirical studies. They include parents altruism, intergenerational transfers, the role of the security system, raising education and health levels, aiding birth control and distinct incentives which govern intra-family choices, technological innovation and human capital accumulation. The Malthusian model was almost abandoned by most of the recent research on population and growth, but its main legacy, that higher population tends to reduce per capita income, lives on in the neoclassical literature through the assumption of diminishing marginal product for a greater labor supply. From a contemporary point of view per capita income growth is caused principally by the accumulation of human and physical capital and technological innovation. From the interaction of these factors and their effects on population growth there emerges the Malthusian trap and the post-Malthusian regime, which replace the tendency toward a population explosion with a simiEconômica, nº 3, pp. 75-101, junho 2000 Luis Currais lar concern for the tendency of a population to implode due to falling birth rates and an aging population. Several studies on economic and population growth recognize the role of longevity in economic growth and have reached a generally optimistic assessment of the relationship between human capital and health economics on fertility and longevity through a healthier population. This innovate approach considers mortality as an endogenous variable and analyses its consequences on morbidity and mortality rates, thus giving us more complete insights into the relationship between economic growth, development and longevity. The ongoing demographic transition in several developing countries with persistent economic growth creates new challenges. Perhaps the relationship between population and per capita income is far more complicated than that which is to be found in Malthusian, neoclassical or endogenous-growth models. In certain economies with small agricultural sector the increase in density that comes with higher population and greater urbanization promotes specialization, greater investment in human capital, and the rapid accumulation of knew knowledge. Under these conditions higher rates of return due to knowledge accumulation are likely to be more important than diminishing returns in constrained sectors. These facts would increase the cost of having children as compared with investing more in each child. Thus, the demographic transition toward smaller families may be stimulated by an initial growth in population. Over the last few years the literature on population has been evolving into a comprehensive dynamic framework where population, development and growth are determined endogenously and simultaneously. The development process and the demographic transition have been treated as a single unified model, capable of explaining both growth and stagnation in output and population. The direction of the changes in population and economic growth are the consequence of shifts in the initial conditions or basic parameters of the model, rather than as a result of changes in demographic variables. The explanation of the complete transition should allow us to better understand the phenomEconômica, nº 3,pp. 75-101, junho 2000 95 From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition 96 ena related to population and growth, its consequences, the prediction of future trends and the effects of policy intervention. This, then, constitutes the thrust of current literature at the cutting edge of population and development research. Possible extensions to this literature might provide further insights into demographic change, both theoretically and empirically. For instance the consideration of a model with endogenous population and growth based on heterogeneous rather than homogeneous agents would overcome one of the limitations of the present models. It would be a more plausible framework, which would allow us to study different patterns of fertility, longevity and income growth across economies and families. Another extension to the model might be the study of the implications of birth control in developing countries. How government intervention through contraception, abortion and legality would affect the societys wealth and welfare. The re-examination of the impact of legalizing abortion, which is being carried out progressively in some developed countries, and the effects of public medical care programs, such as the Medicaid funding available in the United States for those of low income groups, would be another important line of research. References BARRO, R. J. & SALA-I-MARTIN, X. Economic growth. New York, McGraw-Hill, 1995. BECKER, G. S. An economic analysis of fertility. In: Demographic and economic change in developed countries. A conference of universities. NBER Committee for Economic Research. Princeton, Princeton University Press, 1960. ____ . A treatise on the family. Cambridge, Harvard University Press, 1994. BECKER, G. S. & BARRO, R. A reformulation of the economic theory of fertility. Quarterly Journal of Economics, n. 103, 1988. Econômica, nº 3, pp. 75-101, junho 2000 Luis Currais BECKER, G. S. & LEWIS, H. G. On the interaction between the quantity and quality of children. Journal of Political Economy, n. 81, 1973. BECKER, G. S., GLAESER, E. & MURPHY, K. Population and economic growth. American Economic Review, v. 2, n. 89, 1999. BECKER, G. S., MURPHY, K. & TAMURA, R. Human capital fertility and economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, n. 98, 1990. BLACKBURN, K. & CIPRIANI, G. P. Endogenous fertility, mortality and growth. Journal of Population Economics, v. 11, n. 4, 1998. BOTERO, G. Della region di stato. Torino, Editice Torinese, 1948. First edition, 1589. CALDWELL, J. Toward a restatement of demographic transition theory. Population and Development Review, n. 2, 1976. ____ . Theory of fertility decline. New York, Academic Press, 1982. CASS, D. Optimum growth in an aggregate model of capital accumulation. Review of Economic Studies, n. 32, 1965. CIGNO, A. & ROSATI, F. The effects of financial markets and social security on saving and fertility behavior in Italy. Journal of Population Economics, n. 5, 1992. COALE, A. J. The demographic transition. Proceedings of the International Population Conference, Liége, 1963. COALE, A. J. & HOOVER, E. M. Population growth and economic development in low-income populations. Princeton, Princeton University Press, 1958. CURRAIS, L. Population, Growth and Health Expenditure. Forthcoming in Revista Brasileira de Economia, 2000. CURRAIS, L. & GOMEZ, M. Endogenous population growth and health spending: A theoretical investigation. Mimeo, La Coruña University, 1999. Econômica, nº 3,pp. 75-101, junho 2000 97 From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition 98 CURRAIS, L. & RIVERA, B. Income variation and health expenditure: Evidence for OECD countries. Review of Development Economics, n. 3, 1999a. ____ . Economic growth and health: Direct impact or reverse causation. Applied Economic Letters, n. 6, 1999b. DAVIS, K. World population in transition. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Science, n. 237, 1943. DYSON, T. & MURPHY, M. The onset of fertility transition. Population and Development Review, v. 3, n. 11, 1985. EASTERLIN, R. A. Population, labor force and long swings in economic growth. New York, Columbia University Press, 1968. ECKSTEIN, Z. & WOLPIN, K. Endogenous fertility and optimal population size. Journal of Public Economics, n. 27, 1985. EHRLICH, I. & CHUMA, H. A model of the demand for longevity and the value of life extension. Journal of Political Economy, n. 98, 1990. EHRLICH, I. & LUI, F. T. Intergenerational trade, longevity and economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, n. 99, 1991. ____ . Social security, the family, and economic growth. Economic Inquiry, July, 1998. ENTWISTLE, B. & WINEGARDEN, C.R. Fertility and pension programs in LDCs: A model of mutual reinforcement. Economic Development and Cultural Change, n. 32, 1984. FOGEL, R. New findings on secular trends in nutrition and mortality: Some implications for population theory. In: Mark Rosenzweig and Oded Stark (eds.), The handbook of population and family economics, v. 1A. Amsterdam, North Holland, 1997. GALOR, O. & WEIL, D. From Malthusian stagnation to modern growth. American Economic Review, v. 2, n. 89, 1999. GROSSMAN, M. The demand for health: A theoretical and empirical investigation. New York, Columbia University Press, 1972. Econômica, nº 3, pp. 75-101, junho 2000 Luis Currais JABLONSKI, M., ROSEMBLUM, L. & KUNZE, K. Productivity, age, and labor composition changes in the U.S.. Monthly Labor Review, v. 9, n. 111, 1988. KAWACHI, I., KENNEDY, B. P., LOCHNER, K. & PROTHOWSTITH, D. Social capital, Income Inequality and Mortality. American Journal of Public Health, v. 9, n. 87, 1997. KIRK, D. Demographic transition theory. Population Studies, n. 50, 1996. KOOPMANS, T. C. On the concept of optimal economic growth. In: The economic approach to development planning. Amsterdam, North Holland, 1965. KREMER, M. Population growth and technological change: One million B.C. to 1990. Quarterly Journal of Economics, v. 3, n. 108, 1993. KREMER, M. & CHEN, D. Income distribution dynamics with endogenous fertility. American Economic Review, v. 2, n. 89, 1999. LANDRY, A. La revolution démographique. Paris, 1934. LEIBENSTEIN, H. Economic backwardness and economic growth. New York, Wiley, 1963. LONG, C. D. The labor force under changing income and employment. Princeton, Princeton University Press, 1958. LUCAS, R Ricardian equilibrium: A neoclassical exposition. Economics Workshop Series, Israel Institute of Technology, 1996. MADDISON, A. Phases of capitalist development. Oxford, Oxford University Press, 1982. ____ . Monitoring the world economy: 1820-1992. Paris, OECD, 1995. MALTHUS, T. R. An essay on the principle of population. London, W. Pickering, 1986. English first edition, 1798. MATTHEWS, R. C., FEINSTEIN, C. H. & ODLING-SMEE, J. C. British economic growth: 1856-1973. Stanford, Stanford University Press, 1982. Econômica, nº 3,pp. 75-101, junho 2000 99 From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition 100 MINCER, J. Labor force participation of married women. In: Aspects of Labor Economics. Princeton, Princeton University Press, 1962. NOTESTEIN, F. The future population of Europe and the Soviet Union: Population projections 1940-1970. Geneva, 1944. ____ . Population the long view. In: T. Schultz (ed.), Food for the world. Chicago, 1945. NUGENT, J. B. & GILLAPSY, R. T. Old age pensions and fertility in rural areas of less developed countries: Some evidence from Mexico. Economic Development and Cultural Change, n. 31, 1983. ROSTOW, W. W. Theorists of economic growth from David Hume to the present. New York, Oxford University Press, 1990. SCHULTZ, T. The economic value of education. New York, Columbia University Press, 1963. ____ . Changing world prices, womens wages and the fertility transition: Sweden 1860-1910. Journal of Political Economy, n. 93, 1985. SCHUMPETER, J. History of economic analysis. New York, Oxford University Press, 1954. SIMON, J. The effects of income on fertility. Chapel Hill, Carolina Population Center, 1974. SMITH, A. An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. New York, Random House, 1937. English first edition, 1776. SOLOW, R. A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, n. 70, 1956. THOMPSON, W. S. Population. American Journal of Sociology, n. 34, 1929. WILDASIN, D. Non-neutrality of debt with endogenous fertility. Oxford Economic Papers, n. 42, 1990. WILLIS, R. J. Public and private intergenerational transfers, economic growth and demographic transition. Taipei, Taiwan, Academy Sinica, 1989. Econômica, nº 3, pp. 75-101, junho 2000 Luis Currais WORLD BANK. World development report. New York, Oxford University Press, 1993. WORLD HEALTH ORGANIZATION (WHO). Health and mortality. Geneva, 1993. 101 Econômica, nº 3,pp. 75-101, junho 2000