Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
1 Finding the Balance: Market-Based Approaches to Invasive Species Management Nick Ballou April 6, 2016 EVST 4650 Senior Colloquium Invasive Red Lionfish (Pterois volitans) in Florida 2 Table of Contents Abstract ...................................................................................................................................... 3 Summary of Recommendations ................................................................................................. 4 Introduction ................................................................................................................................ 4 History of the Field .................................................................................................................... 6 Present-day Invasive Species Management ............................................................................... 7 Future of the Field ...................................................................................................................... 9 Implementation of Recommendations ..................................................................................... 10 Works Cited.............................................................................................................................. 12 3 Abstract More than 50,000 non-native plant and animal species currently live in the United States (Margolis, 2005, p. 308). An enormous number of these have confirmed detrimental effects, whether that be in the context of biodiversity and competition against endemic species, as a hindrance to human economic activities, as a health risk, or an assortment of other potential consequences. On the current 958 species protected by the Endangered Species Act, 400 of them face competition from non-native invasive species (Dobson, 2013, p. 65). The problem is clear: species brought over from one region or part of the world to another may have adaptations that allow them near-unrestricted growth in the new ecosystem. Lack of predators, more abundant food supply, and other eased environmental restrictions favor the new species at the expense of the “natural” ecological state. The examples are endless; the Burmese pythons are some of Florida’s biggest predators, the light brown apple moth has eaten quickly away at various crops in California (particularly organic ones), and Zebra mussels clog the intake valves for various urban water supplies throughout the Great Lakes. The aggregated impact is estimated to have cost the U.S. $127 billion in 2010, a number which has been steadily growing each year and which also does not include potential human disease costs (Corn, 2013, p. 2). Despite the enormity of the issue, the policies around the issue have long lagged behind the science. Current invasive species management is both less effective and less financially efficient than it could be. In the following discussion, market-based strategies and their benefits are compared to historical and present-day non-native organism regulation. Pigouvian taxes, tradeable risk permits, and performance bonds are also underutilized options with the potential to capture the invasive species-related economic externalities. A number of useful suggestions are made and contextualized, with the goal of advising policy-makers and citizens as to all their possible options in combatting this extraordinarily important problem. 4 Summary of Recommendations Increase prevalence of and funding for city, state, and regional invasive species boards Revise invasive species blacklist strategies Implement market-based approaches one species at a time Use raised funds to promote research on non-native species interaction Introduction The Asian Longhorned Beetle (Anoplophora glabripennis) threatens more than 30% of urban trees throughout the entire United States (Porter, 2010, p. 3). Burmese Python (Python bivittatus) number more than 30,000 in the Everglades alone and remain at the very top of the food web with little to no competition for resources (Corn, 2013, p. 1). The Black Rat (Rattus rattus) has inhabited and spread disease to all corners of the earth for the better part of two millennia. These examples all have one thing in common: they are species that, through human activity1, were brought from their native habitat to a new one in which environmental pressures are significantly lower than those to which they are adapted. They are invasive species—those non-native organisms which cause harm to the environment, economy, or public health in their new region. Lack of predators, more abundant food supply, and other eased environmental restrictions favor the new species at the expense of ecological balance. There are invasive species on every continent in the world, in every state in the U.S., and in every form from viruses to land mammals and every plant and animal in between. Though very difficult to quantify, a highly involved study by researchers at Cornell University estimates aggregate economic costs from selected invasive species2 at $127 billion annually in the United States, excluding costs for human health impacts (Pimental, 2005, p. 273). These included economic costs include direct damage, loss to property values, control costs, agricultural or natural resource productivity or output loss, and dozens of other sources of monetary damages. Studies by Cook (2007) and Leung et al. (2002) corroborate the large 1 Invasive species need not necessarily be introduced by humans, but there are currently no confirmed examples of an invasive species invading through natural pathways. Potential nonhuman introduction could occur with large-scale geological shift, a natural disaster, or extraterrestrial life, but has not occurred thus far 2 The non-native species ignored by the study were those either a) under human domestication, b) non-native but with no demonstrable negative effects, nor c) non-native species introduced with positive benefits to the environment (cereal rye [Secale cereale], for example, is wild and non-native, but desirable in the Midwest United States) 5 and growing number of over $100 billion in total yearly impact—in short, the data has been consistently dire since the 1990s, which was the beginning of when the science of the field began to rapidly progress. The science demonstrates that the consequence is more than just economic damages, but ecological damages as well. The problem of invasive species becomes even more grave with the knowledge that they pose the second-largest threat to U.S. biodiversity nationwide, behind only the habitat loss and degradation caused by development and pollution (Beck, 2008, p. 416). The magnitude of the issue is clear and well-documented, and as a result, it is in the best interest of all parties to legislate effective means of control. Everyone from bright greens to the most diehard capitalist has an incentive to manage non-native species control correctly. By doing so, small costs to society today can prevent enormous ones in the future, and the critical biodiversity of our nation and of our planet can be adequately protected. The present legislation leaves a lot to be desired. Fortunately, there is another option: market-based solutions have been shown to be effective if properly legislated (Richards, 2010). 6 History of the Field In order to understand how the future of invasive species management could look, it is necessary to look at the history of the politics surrounding the issue. Invasive species management began at the very end of the 19th century, in the United States before anywhere else and long before significant international environmental management existed. The first bill addressing non-native species impact is the Lacey Act of 1900. In the Lacey Act, “injurious species provision” is criminally codified, and the Secretaries of the Interior and of the Treasury are given control over which species are allowed to be imported and exported as well as transported between states. The Lacey Act was initially implemented as a whitelist policy, a type of single species control. Single species control is the first and oldest of two basic regulatory approaches to invasive species control; the other is known as the pathways approach. Under the single species approach, the Lacey Act would turn out to be an exception— most commonly, species are placed on a blacklist, at which point their means of transport are identified and regulated. The Lacey Act, on the other hand, utilized a whitelist policy. Under either strategy, shipments are required to declare any plant or animal life being transported. In a blacklist policy, any species on the list is denied or even quarantined if necessary. However, getting on one of the blacklists can be difficult, because demonstrating harm by a non-native species is arduous and often only possible long after the organism has been reproducing rapidly and inflicting damage in the non-native region. The whitelist policy forbids the transport of any species not found on the list. In this way, whitelist policy is much more cautious and therefore safer; as a result, it is also harder to implement and can put unnecessary pressure on firms. Under ideal circumstances, a whitelist would be perhaps the most effective form of control, but the reality—in which many species are unidentified and their means of transport either unknown or unregulated—makes a foolproof whitelist impossible. It is important to note here that the Lacey Act was originally fairly limited in scope; it endeavored to prevent interstate wild bird transport to sell game, and opened a few other known injurious species categories like mollusks and fish. But many varieties of animals and almost all plants continued to be completely unmonitored, leading to situations like the current water hyacinth (Eichhornia crassipes) explosions across southern Louisiana and the surrounding areas, which have been choking out rivers, killing fish, and hindering shipping for the better part of a century after its horticultural introduction from Southeast Asia. 7 In 1949, the first major amendments to the Lacey Act caused it to be more broadly based on blacklist policy instead of the whitelist strategy of the past. This would continue to be the legislative standard until the Clinton Administration of the 1990s. Executive Order 13112 of 1999 fundamentally changed America’s strategy on non-native species management, establishing the National Invasive Species Council (NISC) with members from more than thirty-five federal agencies. The critical difference in the establishment of the NISC was the switch toward emphasis of the pathways approach—the alternative to single-species management that seeks to identify all major sources of species transport and sterilize them or otherwise prevent plants, animals, and microorganisms from being undesirably transported. To this end, the NISC works hand in hand with the Invasive Species Advisory Committee (ISAC) to take information from scientists, state and local representatives, and stakeholders and apply it effectively. The partnership between the federal and state governments is a positive one; no strategy can be effective without utilizing resources from both areas. The downside, however, is that the regulatory framework has ended up being something of a loose patchwork between those two approaches, whereby some species are regulated twice and others not at all. Present-day Invasive Species Management The patchwork prevention continues to this day. The National Invasive Species Management Plan, as implemented in Executive Order 13112, offers a framework for invasive species management, but this plan has only been updated once since its 1999 inception. The management plan is ambitious and promising, but has not yet lived up to its anticipated efficacy. Currently, international pathways prevention falls generally under the NISC’s watch, and in this realm there has been some level of success. A number of successful strategies have been nationally implemented 8 under their management: universal ballast water chlorination, wood product sterilization, and various other industrial treatments are all in effect and were designed to limit unplanned plant, animal, or microbial invasion. These industry-wide NISC requirements take a significant pressure off each state by tightening the scope of what state-led ISACs need to accomplish. While the NISC has made significant progress and effectively managed some of the most important non-native pathways to introduction (ballast water is the single largest contributor to aquatic invasive species worldwide), some other areas are unfortunately lacking. Beyond the largely easily-identifiable and nationally-implementable pathways regulation, the NISC is too small to offer much more than guidance about how to manage particularly dangerous single species in each state. Single-species invasive species management in the states remains largely underfunded and under-prioritized. One major way in which invasive species costs are shifted onto the taxpayer without their knowledge is in human health effects. Invasive species have a multitude of direct and indirect effects on human health which are estimated to cost the U.S. at least $20 billion annually. This occurs in four major categories (Corn 2013): By being itself a pathogen o Ex. West Nile Virus, brought to North America from Africa by an infected bird or mosquito By being a vector for either a native or non-native pathogen o Ex. Human Monocytotropic Ehrlichiosis (HME) is carried and spread by the lone star tick (Amblyomma americanum) in 10-fold increased numbers after the introduction of the invasive weed Amur honeysuckle (Lonicera maackii) (Hulme 2009, p. 12). By changing the ecosystem in ways that favor the outbreak of a pathogen o Ex. The zebra mussel (Dreissena polymorpha) promotes annual toxic bluegreen algal blooms in the Great Lakes By increasing human exposure to hazards o Ex. The non-native termite Coptotermes formosanus, known as the “Super Termite” weakens wooden structures all across the U.S. and the world such as boats and high-rise buildings, leading in extreme cases to collapse The U.S. has given states a hefty portion of the responsibility to manage non-native species. A core issue with this policy, however, is that every continental state is either aided by the strength or hindered by weakness of its neighbors’ laws. The state-level approach allows much more attention to specific organisms in regional ecosystems, but loses its efficacy without a broadly-developed federal system in the background. The biggest pitfalls of the current invasive species management landscape include its highly reactive, not proactive, nature, its lack of sufficient federal funding, and its lack of fund generation. The system generates effectively no money, requiring taxpayer dollars to continue the regulation. Not only does this make invasive species regulation inefficient and 9 expensive, it also turns citizens against the issue: those who are not familiar with the science of invasive species see only the governmental roadblock and economic losses associated with regulation. Future of the Field Clearly, the United States’ strategy needs to change, and there is one major step forward waiting to be taken: Market-based approaches are a highly untapped resource in invasive species management. A number of variations are possible, all of which with confirmed success on small scales and very high potential efficiency. Knowler and Barbier (2005) propose a system of Pigouvian taxes, which can capture the externalities of invasive species and may achieve the optimal balance between controlling damage and encouraging the diversity benefits that follow from importing non-native species. Constanza and Perrins (1990) suggest a system of performance bonds and associated financial penalties for firms who failed to meet environmental standards. Horan and Lupi’s 2005 essay on tradeable invasive species risk permits provides the most unadulterated market-based strategy, recommending that a market be created for permits associated with any non-native species introduction. These strategies all have much in common. By one way or another, they create a system of environmental responsibility for any firms who put the nearby ecosystem at risk with their business activities, and raise funds from those risk-taking businesses. In the end, the best strategy will always be dependent on the region, the particular non-native species or species pathway, and the local governmental stance, but it is in everyone’s best interest to have the greatest possible range of effective options at hand. The other aspect in common lies in the ability to generate revenue, something the current system lacks entirely. The money raised from Pigouvian taxes, tradeable permits, or even the performance bonds all represent a better long-term future in invasive species management, because the money can be used within the field to better study, identify, and track non-native species interaction. Research funding is often difficult to support, but this system would take it much closer to the self-sustaining ideal. Determining the dollar value on each of these programs is difficult, but the science of the field is now making previously-impossible tasks manageable. Biostatisticians are able to calculate with increasing accuracy the likelihood of a stochastic non-native species emission, and the subsequent likelihood of a species taking up residence and harming the local environment (Richards 2010, p. 353). These estimates can be used to put a value on the risk of 10 non-native species import, and efficiently capture that risk in the existing market (Cook 2007, p. 1833). For example, horticultural imports to Hawaii by boat may have a .1% chance per 1000 pounds of cargo to introduce a new species—this a stochastic event; either it happens or it does not. One risk permit allows for that 1000 pounds to be shipped into the state. Now, algae biofuel import and cultivation is an industry with a known high danger of non-native species emission. The biostatistician may calculate a .1% chance per 100 gallons of fuel produced, a higher rate than the horticultural imports, and this would also be worth a permit. Another new tool available to scientists are biodiversity modules, which can be set up remotely and monitored over time for changes to the flora, fauna, and microbial life in the area. Monitoring species and pathways closely remains especially important, as that gives the best chance of early detection, and subsequently the best chance of corrective action. When the invasive species is identified and caught early, a variety of techniques are available. From artificial pheromones released to decrease sexual attraction in fish, introduction of sterilized males into insect community, to simple mammalian catch and kill strategies, each situation must be handled with the appropriate technique. When no market-based approach is possible and the biostatistical data is not strong enough, Barbier et al. suggest a licensure policy, which would require members of the horticultural industry to provide proof of training and oversight before being allowed to import plant species. A licensure strategy has the benefit of being simple and easy to implement, but has the trade-off that any fund generation would be sunk largely into the regulatory costs thereof, and the disadvantage that only certain industries (those with intentional and knowledgeable non-native species import) can be included. Nonetheless, licensure policy offers yet another option to round out the possibilities. Implementation of Recommendations Moving toward these new strategies will be a slow process. The first step will be to increase the availability of resources to the city, state, and regional invasive species boards. These boards are short on scientists, and even shorter on funding. With time and personnel, the invasive species boards can begin to work their way through the current blacklists. From these lists, some species will not be manageable with a market-based approach, and others will stand out as viable options due to their particular pathways. 11 A market-based approach will be best introduced slowly, one species at a time. This system works most effectively with risk permits, as a well-implemented permit system will be fully functional for any number of industries; when a new expansion is proposed, the statistics need only be compared to the current permits and weighted accordingly. Over time, the dollar values and weights of these permits will change to better reflect the information on the likelihood of a given species emission, residency, and ecological harm. From here, the system is cyclical. Generated funds will be allocated for invasive species research. The more scientific data available, the more accurate the tax/permit value. Market-based approaches will not be perfectly efficient in their initial iterations; instead, they will set up a foundation for a long-term future of invasive species prevention and control that will save the U.S. billions and provide a structural framework for worldwide invasive species policy. As Leung et al. so eloquently wrote in 2002, invasive species can be treated with “an ounce of prevention or a pound of cure.” We find ourselves currently at a turning point, and foresight now can save tons of economic headaches in the future. The more individuals get involved, the more likely that this issue will rise up the political priority list—to that end, research and community education remain critical to the strategy. Readers are encouraged to continue to stay informed and share ideas with others, and stay optimistic about the future of invasive species management: we have the tools to minimize, and perhaps someday even fully solve, this crucial problem. 12 Works Cited Barbier, E. B. (2001). A Note on the Economics of Biological Invasions. Ecological Economics, 39(2), 197-202. Beck, K. G., Zimmerman, K., Schardt, J. D., Stone, J., Lukens, R. R., Reichard, S., and Thompson, J. P. (2008). Invasive Species Defined in a Policy Context: Recommendations from the Federal Invasive Species Advisory Committee. Invasive Plant Science and Management, 1(4), 414-421. Cook, D. C., Thomas, M. B., Cunningham, S. A., Anderson, D. L., & De Barro, P. J. (2007). Predicting the Economic Impact of an Invasive Species on an Ecosystem Eervice. Ecological Applications, 17(6), 1832-1840. Corn, M. Lynne. (2013, October). Invasive Species: Major Laws and the Role of Selected Federal Agencies (CRS Report No. R43258). Retrieved from Congressional Research Service website: http://nationalaglawcenter.org/wpcontent/uploads/assets/crs/R43258.pdf Dobson, A., Barker, K., & Taylor, S. L. (2013). Biosecurity: The Socio-Politics of Invasive Species and Infectious Diseases. New York, NY: Routledge. Horan, R. D., & Lupi, F. (2005). Tradeable Risk Permits to Prevent Future Introductions of Invasive Alien Species into the Great Lakes. Ecological Economics, 52(3), 289-304. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2004.06.018 Hulme, P. E. (2009). Trade, Transport and Trouble: Managing Invasive Species Pathways in an Era of Globalization. Journal of Applied Ecology, 46(1), 10-18. doi:10.1111/j.1365-2664.2008.01600. Knowler, D., & Barbier, E. (2005). Importing Exotic Plants and the Risk of Invasion: Are Market-Based Instruments Adequate? Ecological Economics, 52(3), 341-354. Leung, B., Lodge, D. M., Finnoff, D., Shogren, J. F., Lewis, M. A., & Lamberti, G. (2002). An Ounce of Prevention or a Pound of Cure: Bioeconomic Risk Analysis of Invasive Species. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B: Biological Sciences, 269(1508), 2407-2413. Margolis, M., Shogren, J. F., & Fischer, C. (2005). How Trade Politics Affect Invasive Species Control. Ecological Economics, 52(3), 305-313. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2004.07.017 McNeely, J. A. (2001). The Great Reshuffling: Human Dimensions of Invasive Alien Species. Gland, Switzerland: IUCN. Pimentel, D., Zuniga, R., & Morrison, D. (2005). Update on the Environmental and Economic Costs Associated with Alien-Invasive Species in the United States. Ecological Economics, 52(3), 273-288. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2004.10.002 13 Porter, R. D., Graham, S., & Fishman, A. (2010). Status and Trends in State Invasive Species Policy: 2002-2009 (Publication). Washington D.C.: Environmental Law Institute. Richards, T. J., Ellsworth, P., Tronstad, R., & Naranjo, S. (2010). Market-Based Instruments for the Optimal Control of Invasive Insect Species: B. Tabaci in Arizona. Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 35(3), 349-367. Westphal, M. I., Browne, M., Mackinnon, K., & Noble, I. (2007). The Link Between International Trade and the Global Distribution of Invasive Alien Species. Biological Invasions, 10(4), 391-398. doi:10.1007/s10530-007-9138-5