* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Prices, Standards of Living and Material Incentives in Japan, 1937
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Prices, Standards of Living and Material Incentives in Japan, 1937-1941 Janet Hunter London School of Economics Preliminary Draft, Not for Citation 29th February 2008 Introduction It is widely recognised that by 1945 the extent of material deprivation and malnutrition in Japan was considerable, and that economic collapse was a key factor in Japan’s defeat. The position of the economy in the years of the China conflict prior to Pearl Harbor, 1937-1941, has received much less attention. Economic historians of 20th century Japan have long focused their attention on the interwar depression and Japan’s recovery under Takahashi after December 1931. Over recent years they have also increasingly analysed the nature of Japan’s war economy during the period 1937-1945, and its longer term implications for Japan’s postwar economy.1 It makes sense, of course, to treat the war years of 1937-1945 as a whole, but at the same time the treatment has often been imbalanced. The acute, and very obvious, problems of inadequate labour mobilization, skill and raw material shortages, and production decline, of 1943-45 have often led to the earlier years of conflict against China receiving only passing mention. Most of the papers in Pauer’s excellent volume, for example, focus primarily on the Pacific War years. Statistics often compare 1944/45 figures with those in the 1930 and 1940 censuses, by implication measuring 1940 against the 1930 baseline, rather than the post-depression start of the China War in 1937.2 Yet in many respects the period 1937-41, during which the state struggled to establish an efficient planning mechanism that would ensure the economy met the needs of the war effort, set the parameters for the operation of the war economy through to 1945. Moreover, as the transitional period between the recovery years that ended with Takahashi’s assassination in 1936 and the total war economy of 1942-45, these initial years of the China War merit attention in their own right. This paper will analyse the functioning of the Japanese economy during these years. It will in particular look at the issue of material incentives, arguing that the decision to expand the conflict in the autumn-winter of 1941 was taken in a context in which Japan’s economic vulnerability in this area was already apparent to observers both inside and outside the country. It is not disputed that from very early on the country’s economic capacity for a sustained conflict was called into question by the appearance of inadequacies in labour, resource capacity and production. More seriously, 1 For example, T.Okazaki, ‘Senji Keikaku Keizai to Kakaku Tōsei’, in Kindai Nihon Kenkyūkai (ed.), Nenpō Kindai Nihon Kenkyū IX (Tokyo: Yamakawa Shuppansha, 1987); T. Okazaki & M.Okuno (eds.), Gendai Nihon Keizai Shisutemu no Genryū (Tokyo: Nihon Keizai Shinbunsha, 1993) (English version published as T.Okazai & M.OkunoFujiwara (eds.), The Japanese Economic System and its Historical Origins (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999)); Y.Noguchi, ‘The 1940 System: Japan under the Wartime Economy’, American Economic Review 88, 1998; A.Hara, ‘Japan: Guns Before Rice’, in M.Harrison (ed.), The Economics of World War II (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998); E.Pauer (ed.), Japan’s War Economy (London & New York: Routledge, 1999); T.Nakamura, ‘The Age of Turbulence: 1937-1954’, in T.Nakamura & K.Odaka (eds.), Economic History of Japan 1914-1955: a Dual Structure (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2003); A.Hara & S.Yamazaki (eds.), Senji Nihon no Keizai Saihensei (Tokyo: Nihon Keizai Hyōronsha, 2006). 2 This is true, for example, of many of the figures in J.B.Cohen’s Japan’s Economy in War and Reconstruction (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1949), which remains the best account of Japan’s wartime economy in English. 1 economic potential was crucially dependent on workers’ living standards and material incentives. The paper will argue that notwithstanding public pronouncements that recognised this relationship, the state failed effectively to address issues of declining real incomes for many citizens, shortages of goods and distorted incentive structures, all of which were well before December 1941 reducing the productivity of labour, affecting work effort, attendance and efficiency. It will be shown also that the progressive weakening of the material incentive structure was apparent to both Western and Japanese observers, who believed that it must eventually undermine Japan’s war effort, although there was no agreement on how long this might take. A key feature of wartime economies is a tendency towards inflation. In Japan after 1937 the inflationary threat was to be addressed by curbing the operation of non-essential industries and limiting private consumption. It was recognized, however, that private consumption could only be limited so far, particularly in a relatively poor economy such as Japan, in which average income levels were relatively low. Moreover a minimum standard of living had to be maintained if the populace was to continue to back government policy. Early on this dilemma led to increasing control over the economy through enunciation by the Konoe cabinet of its ‘Three Economic Principles’ of regulation and expansion of production, regulation of balance of payments and of material demand and supply.3 The first part of the paper outlines the development of regulation during this four year period, showing that it was largely ad hoc and lacking in systematic attention to material incentives. Two sets of incentives were important in maximising the contribution of labour to an efficient wartime economy, the material and the non-material (‘spiritual’). The spiritual mobilization campaign that was used to hone workers commitment to the national cause has been the subject of much analysis.4 Just as significant, however, were the material incentive structures in an economy in which market operation remained the norm even as state regulation increased. Wartime regulation by its very nature changed and distorted incentive structures, repeatedly generating new problems that demanded further intervention. Workers’ ability to contribute depended critically on the ways in which they could be remunerated and incentivised. This in turn impacted on work effort, attendance and efficiency. In trying to balance material demand and supply through physical controls over the economy, successive Japanese governments were faced with major dilemmas in this respect. Labour productivity depends crucially on providing 3 T.Nakamura, ‘The Age of Turbulence: 1937-1954’, in T.Nakamura & K.Odaka (eds.), Economic History of Japan 1914-1955: a Dual Structure (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2003), p.55. 4 Eg. R.H.Mitchell, Thought Control in Prewar Japan (Ithaca NY; Cornell University Press, 1976); J.Dower, ‘Sensational Rumors, Seditious Graffiti and the Nightmares of the Thought Police’, in J.Dower, Essays in War and Peace (New York: The New Press, 1993); S.Garon, Molding Japanese Minds (Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press, 1997); B.Kushner, The Thought War: Japanese Imperial Propaganda (Honolulu HI: University of Hawaii Press, 2006). 2 appropriate material and other incentive structures that will allow workers to equate increasing efforts with increasing rewards. Neoclassical economists have focused on the importance of wage and income levels in this equation, and the second part of the paper will outline what was known about the trends in real wages and real income of Japanese workers during this period. However, labour productivity also depends crucially on workers’ capacity to make use of the income that they receive. As one textbook noted for the Soviet Union, one important measure of economic performance is the extent to which an economy meets the material need of its population with a given productive capacity, and in this respect the Soviet planning system often fell short in terms of the lack of consumer goods for purchase with the wages that were earned.5 Income ceases to be a motivating factor if you cannot buy anything with it. Moreover, if earning a decent income requires long extended hours of work and jeopardizes health, then workers will try and calculate how far such effort may, or may not, be worthwhile. We therefore need to consider in the Japanese case not just what was happening to workers’ real incomes, but their ability to consume material goods, enjoy leisure time and experience reasonable health. These broader indicators of living standards will be considered in the final parts of the paper, and it will be shown that notwithstanding trends in real incomes and official entitlements supplies of many commodities were deficient from a relatively early stage in the conflict. Qualitative and quantitative information on the Japanese economy was far more widely available during these years than was the case after Pearl Harbor. It was also more credible to contemporaries. Not only did the state publish a considerable amount of statistical data, there was also scope for semi-independent economists and journalists to produce additional information that would complement, or even call into question the accuracy of the government’s own figures. The Tōyō Keizai Shinpō under the editorial control of Ishibashi Tanzan, and its yearbook, the Tōyō Keizai Nenkan, was one such medium. An English-language version, The Oriental Economist, had been published from 1934, and was a source widely used by US commentators publishing in journals such as Far Eastern Survey and Amerasia.6 These journals are a key source for this paper, as they indicate what was known about the situation of the Japanese economy among an informed public, inside and outside Japan. 5 P.Gregory & R.C.Stuart, Soviet and Post-Soviet Economic Structure and Performance (5th edition, New York: Harper Collins, 1994), p.253ff. 6 Sharon Nolte’s book, Liberalism in Modern Japan: Ishibashi Tanzan and his Teachers, 1905-1960 (Berkeley CA: University of California Press, 1987) offers a detailed analysis of Ishibashi and his views. She observes that The Oriental Economist was more compliant with the official line after the start of the Pacific War, and had always been more ‘propagandistic’ than its Japanese parent publication. This may well have been due to greater constraints on a publication for overseas consumption, but The Oriental Economist is nevertheless conspicuous for its criticism of a number of aspects of government policy during these years, as well as its upholding of the benefits of free international trade and the detrimental effects of a regional yen bloc and military mobilization on Japan’s economic progress. 3 Emergence of Planning The broad thrust of economic policy after the assassination of Takahashi Korekiyo in 1936 was expansion and prioritization of war-related production, and a shift of resources away from peacetime industries. From late 1937 production in a range of peacetime industries was progressively cut. Some producers were able to switch their capacity to war-related production, and while some workers in less essential industries were deprived of employment, many could be absorbed by those areas of production that were growing. Between 1938 and 1942 the number of workers in manufacturing increased by nearly 25 %, to over 9 million.7 While concerns were expressed about there being insufficient skilled workers to sustain production increases in key industries, plans were articulated to provide for future human capital needs.8 We know that production grew substantially, with an estimated 30% increase in Gross Domestic Product between 1937 and 1941.9 Capital goods production grew disproportionately, while consumer goods production showed a relative decline. Beneath this apparent success story, however, lay a number of problematic issues. Starting with Finance Minister Baba in 1936-7 Japanese planners faced a fundamental macroeconomic policy dilemma. Growing expenditure on the military increased budget deficits and the threat of inflation. The additional expenditure had to be supported by either increased taxation or increased borrowing.10 Governments sought to address the inflationary threat by curbing the operation of non-essential industries and limiting private consumption. This strategy, however, brought a further dilemma. Military expansion was substantially dependent on imports of raw materials and finished goods. Securing essential foreign inputs meant instituting controls on foreign exchange, with the aim of directing scarce foreign currency to key industries. However, the supply of foreign exchange could only be secured by continuing to export the products of non-military (and therefore less essential) industries. A decline in exports meant that foreign payments would have to be made out of Japan’s finite supply of gold reserves. In the face of this dilemma in 1937 emergency foreign trade controls were rapidly introduced, which explicitly restricted imports of consumer items, including some foods and drinks, vehicles, musical instruments and photographic equipment.11 In April 1938 the National General Mobilization Bill went through the Lower House of the Diet, giving government extensive control over a range of economic activities, including the labour force. This legislation is appropriately regarded as the enabling act for wartime mobilisation of the 7 S.Nagaoka, Kindai Nihon no Keizai (Tokyo: Minerva Shobō, 1992), p.232, table II-15-2. M.S.F., ‘Japan to Coordinate Labor Supply and Demand’, Far Eastern Survey 7, 19, 28 Sept. 1938, pp.225-6. 9 Hara, ‘Japan: Guns before Rice’, p.226. 10 Ishibashi Tanzan argued strongly for the raising of money through taxation rather than increased borrowing in his publications (Nolte, Liberalism in Modern Japan, p.266). 11 Oriental Economist IV, 10, October 1937, pp.579-80. 8 4 economy, and has received much attention, including from contemporaries. As far as workers were concerned, it laid down that the government could ‘draft subjects of the Empire for employment in general mobilization enterprises or cause them to cooperate in the conducting of such concerns by the nation or local public bodies; give necessary orders concerning use, employment dismissal, wages and other labor terms of employees…and for the prevention, settlement, restriction, or prohibition of actions in labor disputes’. It could also ‘demand reports on and examine the vocational abilities of the subjects of the Empire; issue requisite orders regarding the training of technicians necessary for national general mobilization to their employers, and the institutions or places of work where they may be trained; cause owners of general mobilization enterprises to establish programs pertaining to mobilization or conduct drills based thereon.’12 The first moves to invoke the legislation came shortly afterwards. While controls over labour mobilisation became increasingly important in this period, it is regulation relating to the pricing and availability of goods that related most specifically to the issue of standards of living and material incentives. Price controls were some of the first to appear. Immediately after the outbreak of war in August 1937 the Japanese government invoked the 1917 Anti-Profiteering Law, and in October expanded its remit to include a diverse range of commodities. Powers were extended to weekly reporting of the prices of key items, and before the end of the year maximum prices had been fixed for some key commodities.13 Increasingly, though, the authorities found that it was impossible to control the price of one commodity without controlling those of others and intervening in supply-demand relationships. It was reported that the prices of many goods rose as people rushed to purchase and stockpile them. Voluntary restraints failed to address the problem, which, as, the Oriental Economist observed, ‘was inevitable in view of the fact that any effective price control policy must envisage the adjustment of supply and demand relations as well as the actual control of prices’.14 Recognising this problem, steps were taken early in 1938 to control distribution through national and local prices commissions and bodies such as the Interim Commodities Adjustment Bureau (Rinji Busshi Chōsei Kyoku). It was applied initially to cotton yarn, but ‘the fixed price was a product of voluntary cooperation and was ignored in actual practice.’15 This led in the spring of 1938 to the introduction of maximum fixed prices for cotton yarn and an overall policy on price controls with the formation of the Central Price Commission (Chūō Bukka Iinkai). A similar system to that for cotton was imposed on oil and gasoline from the 12 Kathleen Barnes, ‘Japanese Government Given Blank Cheque’, Far Eastern Survey 7, 7, April 6, 1938, p.80. Oriental Economist v, 6, June 1938, p.358; B.F.Johnston, Japanese Food Management in World War II (Stanford CA: Stanford University Press, 1953), p.170. 14 Oriental Economist V, 6, June 1938, p.359. 15 Oriental Economist V, 6, June 1938, p.360. The OE referred to this body as the Council on Adjustment of Supply and Demand. I have used the translation in Hara, ‘Wartime Controls’, p.255. A contemporary evaluation of this is E.Shiina, Senji Keizai to Busshi Chōsei (Tokyo: Tōa Seikeisha, 1941). 13 5 start of May, and then extended to other important commodities. By the end of 1938 77 kinds of merchandise were designated by the Commission.16 Prices continued to rise, generating proposals to fix the prices of some goods, but The Oriental Economist pointed out that in an economy in which fixed and non-fixed prices coexisted, the non-fixed prices would continue to move up, if anything at an even higher rate. While it was the government’s intention to cope with this problem by limiting profiteering through levies and surcharges, and by refusing raw materials for goods whose prices were not fixed, restricting inputs would be likely to raise prices further, while restricting profiteering would ‘merely prevent the dealers from retaining the fabulous profits involved’, not stop the prices themselves from rising.17 Price controls were strengthened after the outbreak of war in Europe, when the government, unable to stem ongoing price rises, passed a decree freezing official prices at their September 18th level. The few exceptions to these controls included perishable goods, such as fish, vegetables and fruit, and items for export. Legislation at the end of the year specifically prohibited selling at ‘excessive profit’, hoarding and refusing to sell.18 By 1940 popular confidence in the government’s ability to keep down prices was reported to be in decline. The government found itself obliged for political reasons to raise the maximum rice price payable to farmers, but this move seemed to refute the official commitment to lowering prices, as did a rise in retail prices by the tobacco monopoly. The government was forced to acknowledge that it was almost impossible to determine accurately what the ‘appropriate’ price for any commodity was, and ‘it has become growingly apparent, that without checking or depressing price levels in general, the value of any isolated commodity could not be restrained from a rise or, much less, depressed’. The low pricing policy in general was seen as threatening the desire for increased production and productivity.19 By the late summer of 1940 the Price Commission, now chaired by the Prime Minister, recommended that the prices of perishable foodstuffs, which had experienced conspicuous rises over previous months, also be controlled, resulting in the setting of price ceilings by local authorities. Again this was associated with distribution control, but in the case of fish, for example, the authorities found it hard to stop dealers from selling their limited stocks above the official price. By the autumn official prices well below the prevailing free market price had been established for 24 vegetables and 16 varieties of fruit, again accompanied by tighter distributional control.20 Price controls could not, however, address the fundamental supply deficiency that will be discussed below. Moreover, if combined with 16 Oriental Economist V, 6, June 1938, p.360; VI, 5, May 1938, p.305. Oriental Economist VI, 6, June 1939, p.375. 18 Hara, ‘Japan: Guns before Rice’, p.237; Hara, ‘Wartime Controls’, pp.258-9; Johnston, Japanese Food Management, pp.170-1. 19 Oriental Economist VII, 3, March 1940, p.137. 20 Johnston, Japanese Food Management, p.171. See also K.Baba, ‘Shokuryō Jukyū no Dōkō’, in Tōkei Kenkyūkai, Shokuryō Kanryō Shi vol.2 (Tokyo: Shokuryōchō, 1969). 17 6 inefficient or easily circumvented distributional policies, or inappropriate incentives, then they were unlikely even to meet the short term needs of the economy. Further tools which had a role in constraining consumption and limiting the budget deficit were taxation and savings programmes. Individual savings rose from around 10% of GNP in 1937 to over 20% in 1941. In the early 1940s around 70% of these savings were in the form of deposits in financial institutions.21 Large scale tax reform to support increases in military expenditure had been proposed as early as 1936-7,22 and while much of the increased expenditure was supported by government borrowing rather than tax increases, taxation remained an important tool both of government revenue and for regulating distribution and consumption. Immediately after the outbreak of war with China the government imposed emergency tax increases on income and profits.23 Early in 1940 a significant reform of the tax system was attempted, which sought to expand dependence on income tax, introduce a corporation tax, revise and simplify the temporary profits tax, and introduce a new structure for local taxes. There were significant increases in inheritance tax and all indirect taxes. The ability of the Japanese population, whose average income remained relatively low by international standards, to bear higher taxation was a topic of debate. Estimates in 1939 suggested that the incidence of tax was equivalent to 17% national income, which indicated that there was some scope for increase.24 The 1940-41 fiscal year budget anticipated tax receipts over 25% above those of 1939-40. Particularly significant components of total revenue were the brewery tax (¥263m.), the sugar excise (¥156m.) and tax on textile consumption (¥71m.). The amusement and restaurant meal tax was expected to bring in over ¥112m., an increase of more than 200% over the previous year.25 By 1941 additional taxes were payable on furniture, pets, bonsai and antiques. Taxation also hit staples. The duty on tea, which stood at 10% at the start of the conflict, was raised to 20% in May 1941, and the tax on cheap tobacco was also increased.26 While the spread of income tax mostly affected only the better off (income over ¥50 per annum), other tax changes impacted directly on prices and hence on consumers. Prices, Wages and Incomes This was the policy context within which, following the outbreak of the war in China, both prices and wages began to rise. Average wages rose in conjunction with an increase in labour 21 T.Okazaki, ‘Wartime Financial Reforms and the Transformation of the Japanese Financial System’, in Pauer (ed.), Japan’s War Economy, p.145. 22 A.Hara, ‘Wartime Controls’, p.249 23 Oriental Economist IV, 8, August 1937, p.443. 24 Oriental Economist VI, 6, June 1939, pp.362-3. 25 ‘The Tax Reform’, Oriental Economist VII, 3, March 1940, pp.155-8. 26 Marc T.Greene, ‘How Much Longer, Japan?’, Amerasia IV, 12, February 1941, pp.570-1(?). 7 mobility, indicating significant variation in wages and working conditions across different sectors of production. The fact that workers with the highest wages were the least mobile27 seems to underline the importance of material incentives in influencing worker behaviour at this time. Both planners and firm managers recognized that some firms needed to offer higher wages to attract workers, but also ecognized that this would fuel inflation further. From 1938 the government set in train a strategy whereby limits on wage rises and worker mobility operated together. At the same time, constraints upon workers’ freedom and wages meant that alternative incentive structures needed to be devised to sustain workers’ commitment and productivity. The introduction of price controls made it very difficult for Japanese economists to construct meaningful price indices, particularly given that policy indicated standard prices, but failed to impose them as official prices. There were significant disparities between different indices produced during and immediately after the war.28 It is clear, however, that wholesale prices rose at a lower rate than the prices paid by consumers, and this has been confirmed by subsequent calculations. Moreover, the indices compiled by the Tōyō Keizai Shinpōsha are close to the figures produced by more recent estimates. The Tōyō Keizai Nenkan calculated that the Tokyo wholesale price index had risen by around 30% between 1937 and the start of 1942 (See Table 1). Other big cities experienced similar rises. Retail prices accelerated much faster. One estimate suggested that by March 1939 average retail prices were already a third higher than they had been in June 1937.29 Analysis of the prices of commodities exempt from official pricing showed that prices were continuing to rise, and The Oriental Economist in mid-1940 estimated that the retail price index had risen by nearly 60% since July 1937, and living costs had risen by over 10% over the five months from September 1939 alone. Referring to its earlier predictions, it noted ‘the main cause of the recent upward curves of the living cost and retail price indices may be found in the sudden rise of these articles excepted from the price-pegging system’. More detailed breakdowns showed that the price for many commodities more than doubled between 1937 and 1941 (See Table 2) The official Tokyo wholesale price of fish, for example, rose 130% between 1936 and 1942.30 Initial price rises after the incident started were most marked in textiles and clothing, but the momentum behind the rises then shifted to cereals, other foodstuffs and drinks, which were experiencing the most price inflation from late 1939.31 (See also Tables 3 and 4)). Perishable commodities had experienced a particularly conspicuous rise over the previous year, with fish prices rising 61% between July 1939 and July 1940, and green vegetables by 48%. Miscellaneous 27 H.Hazama, Chōki Antei Koyō (Tokyo: Bunshindō, 1998), pp.76-79. Cohen gives a comparison of 7 contemporary official and unofficial indices (Japan’s Economy in War and Reconstruction, p.356). 29 Oriental Economist VI, 5, May 1939, p.305. 30 Tōyō Keizai Nenkan vol.28, 1944, p.135. 31 Oriental Economist VII, 6, June 1940, pp.351-2. 28 8 household products such as paper, soap, buckets, matches and alcohol had likewise experienced a rise of nearly 30%.32 The shift in the pattern of price rises was important, as Japanese at this time, like their counterparts in other lower income countries, on average spent a higher proportion of their incomes on basic necessities, particularly food. Examinations of expenditure suggested that food and drink accounted for around 45% of spending, housing for around 17.5%, clothing 14% and lighting and heating 5%.33 Price inflation in the items on which workers spent most, therefore, was likely to be particularly damaging. As noted above, wage rates, particularly in key industries, also rose in the months after 1937. Official cabinet statistics suggested that the average daily cash wages of male factory workers rose by 20-25% between 1937 and 1941.34 This figure conceals considerable disparities between workers, since many of the additional male workers joining the key industries were young and unskilled. Male wage rates were also much higher than those of females. These figures suggest that wage rates were not rising in line with price increases. However, overall earnings were rising rather faster, largely due to longer hours of work. Even as wage rate increases slowed from 1939, the earnings trend for male workers in factories continued to rise. While wage rates for all factory workers increased by about 20% between 1937 and 1940, actual earnings increased by around 50%. The Oriental Economist was cautious in commenting on any possible decline in real living standards. It was noted that early on rises in living costs were marginally ahead of growth in income, but by November 1938 the two series were moving in parallel.35 In spring 1941, after nearly three years of war, it voiced strong criticism of attempts to create the impression abroad that living conditions in Japan had become very difficult, arguing that living standards remained relatively unaffected, and with growing incomes workers and farmers were enjoying prosperity and contentment: ‘Despite a sharp upward movement in wholesale commodity prices, which are highly susceptible to variations in imported raw materials, national living conditions have thus far been immune to any harmful effect associated with rising commodity values. There has been an appreciation in living costs, but that is being offset by the full employment of labor and by rising wage rates.’ 36 The journal did, however, feel able to voice recurrent concerns about the inflation that was likely to result from shortages of consumer goods at a time of rising incomes.37 32 Oriental Economist VII, 10, October 1940, pp.600-1. Oriental Economist VII, 6, June 1940, p.353. 34 Cohen, Japan’s Economy in War and Reconstruction, p.336. 35 Oriental Economist VI, 4, April 1939, pp.236-8. 36 Oriental Economist V, 3, March 1938, p.140. 37 Oriental Economist V, 6, June 1938, p.344; Oriental Economist VI, 4, April 1939, p.226. 33 9 Again these figures do not, of course, tell us anything about income distribution. Women’s earnings remained well behind those of men. By December 1940 women factory workers’ actual earnings had recovered to the 1926 level, but those of male factory workers were 35% above it.38 In the summer of 1942, eight months after Pearl Harbor, the daily wages of women factory workers were at the most barely 50% of those of male workers, and in most sectors the figure was closer to 35-40%. (See Table 5) Even if male workers’ increased earnings could cope with the rising cost of living, those of female workers could hardly be expected to do so. It is clear also that some regions and groups did much better than others. Many contemporaries were concerned about urban-rural disparities. As early as late 1938 a decline in farmers’ real incomes was observed, and rising prices for inputs seemed likely to outweigh the advantages of rising prices for agricultural products. As such, the outlook for the agricultural sector was not particularly rosy: ‘Even if the equilibrium between general commodity prices and the prices of agricultural products is maintained, the purchasing power of the agricultural community will still be greatly weakened by the higher production cost resulting from the recent rise in the prices of general commodities. In either case, the restraint of the prices of agricultural products will increase the possibility of an accelerated downward trend of the purchasing power of the agricultural community, which has already entered a period of stagnation.’39 It must be emphasized, however, that it was not just the distribution of income that determined people’s ability to consume. Even where real incomes were maintained or increased, those incomes did not necessarily enable the acquisition of what was needed. The real problem for material incentive structures was an inability on the part of the state to ensure sufficient supplies to those who could afford them in the market, and to those who had legal entitlement to them under the system of allocation at official prices. This can be demonstrated by analyzing the constraints on consumption that emerged over the period 1937-41. Consumption Assessing actual consumption during this period is problematic. Data on consumption offered by the major statistical series are largely in current prices, and the value of consumption of most items went up, at least until 1940. However, per capita consumption expenditure in constant prices declined from 1938.40 Havens suggests that inflation resulted in an overall 17% decline in real per capita consumption over the period 1937-40.41 More recent scholarly work notes that a declining availability of consumer goods was apparent from 1939, although at an aggregate level the 38 From figures in Oriental Economist VIII, 4, April 1941, p.217. Oriental Economist V, 12, December 1938, pp.802-5 (quotation from p.5). 40 S.Miyohara (ed.), Kojin Shōhi Shishutsu, vol. 6 of Chōki Nihon Keizai Tōkei (Long Term Economic Statistics of Japan) (Tokyo: Tōyō Keizai Shinpōsha, 1967), p.141, Table 4. 41 T.R.H.Havens, Valley of Darkness: the Japanese People and World War II (New York: Norton, 1978), p.35. 39 10 availability of food staples and some basic energy sources such as firewood and charcoal appears to have been broadly sustained until 1941.42 There is now a consensus that consumer goods were already in rapidly declining supply within months of the outbreak of the China war. Contemporary indices of consumer goods supplies suggest that they declined from a peak in 1937, although the stockpiling that took place immediately after the start of the conflict helped to conceal some of this decline. Controls on imports of consumer goods, and on inputs for consumer goods production, threatened to limit availability of some commodities in the domestic market even before the outbreak of war, but well into the conflict Japanese commentators remained optimistic that previously accumulated stocks would support consumption levels: ‘The general public to date has hardly felt even a perceptible pinch in the supply of consumers’ goods….All department stores and other retail establishments display and offer for sale cotton goods and woolen products in full assortments and in abundant quantities. The same is also the case with hardware and other metallic products. Even gasoline, which is subject to a rationing system of the strictest sort, is available in a sufficient supply so that not only public buses and sightseeing cars, but motor vehicles of all imaginable sorts remain in operation.’43 A later article in mid-1940 loyally confirmed that such problems as had arisen in the supply of consumer goods were simply due to ‘faulty handling of matters by Government officials, by no means indicating any fundamental weakness in the nation’s economic structure’. Although the supply of some goods might be diminishing, as long as both consumers and merchants avoided stockpiling in anticipation of higher prices average individual consumption could be sustained at broadly the same level.44 Such optimism about stocks was not, however, always substantiated by information provided elsewhere in the same journal and in other contemporary evidence. For example, while the amount of goods held in public warehouses was reported as having increased in early 1941, there was a decline in stocks of many consumer goods, including grain, beans, peas, sugar, liquor, tobacco, marine products and toilet articles.45 Indeed, a succession of comments on shortages of one consumer good after another belied the optimism that was simultaneously attached to official pronouncements about their widespread availability. The view that Japan was ‘completely immune to a scarcity of food’46 was widely shared, and indices of agricultural production suggest that for most products production levels were sustained until at least 1941, and it was not until 1942-3 that supplies of some goods began to drop 42 Nakamura, ‘Age of Turbulence, 1937-1954’, p.71. Oriental Economist VI, 3, March 1939, p.154. 44 Oriental Economist VII, 6, June 1940, pp.344, 346. 45 Oriental Economist VIII, 3, March 1941, pp.137-8. 46 Oriental Economist VI, 3, March 1939, p154. 43 11 calamitously.47 There was a serious shortfall of rice production in 1940, largely due to drought, but output rose again the following year. However overall supplies were increasingly hit by problems in the operation of the domestic market, declining carryover from year to year, and diminishing imports. A drought that hit Northeast Asia in the summer of 1939 sharply reduced Japan’s rice imports from Korea. Staple imports from the colonies fell to less than 70% of the 1935-8 level in 1939-40, although they rose again the following year. The consequent dislocation of the normal distribution pattern led to supply problems in major cities of the Kantō region, and some shortages in producing areas.48 Measures to curtail rice consumption by 10%, to substitute for rice with other grains, and to control distribution were proposed. Recognising that Japan’s famed empire selfsufficiency in rice was jeopardised by import shortages, the government moved to try and maintain domestic rice supplies. A freeze was placed on the rents that tenant farmers paid for their land in an attempt to compensate for price ceilings on agricultural products.49 To boost the output of foodgrains restrictions were placed on what could be grown on newly cultivated land, and existing land was converted to staple food production.50 The output of many agricultural products actually increased in 1939, but supplies of non-foodgrain crops such as fruits, and even staples such as potatoes, buckwheat and millet, declined. By 1941 supplies of many non-foodgrain crops had become very restricted. Core foodgrain production soon experienced a similar trend, largely due to growing constraints on agricultural inputs. Declining availability of chemical fertilisers, which had been particularly important for output growth in prewar Japanese agriculture,51 was the main input constraint before Pearl Harbor. Imports of phosphate rock were impeded by lack of shipping capacity, and imports of potassium chloride, mostly obtained from Europe, declined substantially after the outbreak of the European war in 1939.52 By the summer of 1940 the problem was severe: ‘Though it is a fact that the revenue of farming households has increased, farmers are unable to obtain their farming materials even if they have money. Fertilisers are generally supplied only to an extent of 70% of the required quantity. Furthermore, it often happens that although the farmer is in possession of sulphate of ammonia, he does not have any potassium, superphosphate or bean and oil cakes. Then the distribution of such fertilisers is not always 47 M.Miyazaki & O.Itō, ‘Transformation of Industries in the War Years’, in Nakamura & Odaka (eds.), Economic History of Japan 1914-1955, p.328. 48 Hara, ‘Japan: Guns before Butter’, p.238; Johnston, Japanese Food Management, pp.151, 187-8. 49 Hara, ‘Wartime Controls’, p.259. 50 Among the crops banned on new land were tea, peppermint, tobacco, fruit and flowers. Some prefectures banned completely the production of some crops, including flowers and melons, on account of their low calorie yield (Johnston, Japanese Food Management, p.118). 51 Fertiliser was estimated at c.15-17% production cost of rice in 1937, and on average over one quarter of total farm costs and over one third farmers’ total cash expenditure (Johnston, Japanese Food Management, pp.14-15. 52 Oriental Economist VII, 5, May 1940, p.295; Miriam S.Farley, ‘Japan’s Fertilizer Problem Still Unsolved’, Far Eastern Survey 8, 6, 15 March, 1939, pp.73-4. 12 made in time for the proper season. Thus not only is it impossible to secure rational fertilisers, but also the fertilising seasons are often missed.’53 By 1941 consumption of potassium-based fertiliser had fallen to less than a quarter of its 1937 level, and was not compensated for by any increase in consumption of nitrogenous or phosphate fertilisers.54 Higher prices and increased production of some crops did not necessarily mean that producers of agricultural commodities were better off. The incentive structure facing farmers in the form of higher prices and higher farm incomes discouraged them from marketing their products. Johnston noted later that increasing rice consumption by the farm population reduced supplies to urban consumers, and ‘since the rural population comprised nearly half the total population of Japan, even a small increase in the level of rice consumption of farm families involved an important reduction in the supply available for the non-farm population whenever imports from foreign sources failed.’55 The Oriental Economist highlighted this problem in the summer of 1940: ‘Though the production of rice and wheat increased, their supply to the markets declined. The insufficient shipment of rice is not only due to speculative holding by merchants and rich farmers and storing by producers in fear of a food shortage, but also to the use of wheat and barley as well as broken rice as animal and fowl fodder, due to the advanced cost of miscellaneous cereals, and to the increased consumption of rice as food. It is also related to the decreased production of such miscellaneous cereals and to the reduced import of bran and other fowl feeds.56 The journal suggested that coercive measures to force producers to market their rice were, if anything, likely to exacerbate the problem.57 Moreover, because the system was such that farmers were obliged to estimate their expected rice crop, and to offer to the government a clearly stated total amount following deductions for necessary food and seed, the overwhelming inclination was to underestimate to avoid a situation in which they themselves would suffer a shortfall.58 Where farmers lacked the incentive to market, consumers were bound to be affected, and it was this situation that pushed the government towards tighter distributional controls. In January 1941 residents of the six largest cities were officially permitted an allocation of 330g. of rice per day.59 National rice rations for civilian adult Japanese were eventually fixed at 300-400g. per day 53 Oriental Economist VII, 7, July 1940, pp.415-6. Nagaoka, Kindai Nihon no Kaizai, p.139. 55 Johnston, Japanese Food Management, p.169. 56 Oriental Economist VII, 7, July 1940, pp.415-6. LTES vol.6 shows that the volume of farmers’ consumption went up 1938-40. In 1938 they took 34.23% of total agricultural output, but in 1940 they took 39.49% of a much smaller harvest (p.151 Table 10). 57 Oriental Economist VII, 8, August 1940, p.464. 58 Oriental Economist VIII, I, January 1941, pp.15-16. 59 Hara, ‘Wartime Controls’, p.262. 54 13 depending on sex, age and work.60 Military rations were higher. Even these allocations suffered from deteriorating quality before the start of the Pacific War, as the government had campaigned to reduce rice consumption through the mixing of rice with other grains, such as barley. The use of low quality and broken rice, and of other substitutes, spread. The adulteration was detrimental to the taste of cooked rice, a situation worsened by a shortage of charcoal for cooking it appropriately. 61 Rice shortages also hit other areas of consumption. As a greater share of rice was consumed, less was allocated to seeds and other manufacturing uses. The domestic supply of sake went down by over 40% 1937-40. 62 The attempts of the government to ensure at least a basic rice availability did not extend to many other foodstuffs. Imports of soy beans, a key source of protein, declined dramatically from 1940, in conjunction with falls in domestic supplies. Production of fats and oils also dropped dramatically 1939-40. A permit system that had been used for mochi rice at New Year began to be extended to other basic commodities from the spring of 1940, including miso, soy sauce and oil. The system was initially piecemeal and local, however.63 Net supplies of sugar were down by over 20% 1939-40.64 A distribution card system for sugar was initiated in June 1940 in the six major cities, and wider rationing for sugar was initiated in November 1940, but supplies were drastically reduced compared with pre-1937 consumption levels.65 Fish consumption was also hit, and there was a dramatic decline in shipments to large urban areas during 1941. Between 1937 and 1940 domestic supplies of fresh and frozen fish were down by nearly 20%.66 Fish and shellfish distribution control was strengthened, with allocation done by rotation between and within wards. Early on, there was a distribution of fish every few days, but the frequency diminished.67 It was reported that by early 1941 butter, eggs and coffee were unavailable outside the Imperial Hotel, 68 and while butter and coffee would rarely have figured in the diet of the average Japanese, an absence of eggs would have been more serious. Sake was rationed from May 1941.69 Neighbourhood associations were closely involved in attempts to try and cope with shortages of other goods. Some developed plans for raising chickens in urban areas, and distributed instructions for keeping rabbits and pigs for food. They were more successful in the gardening campaigns started in major cities in 1940, and also promoted cultivation by members of previously 60 A.Scherer, ‘Drawbacks to Controls on Food Distribution: Food Shortages, the Black Market and Economic Crime’, in Pauer (ed.), Japan’s War Economy (London: Routledge, 1999), p.109. 61 Pauer, ‘New Order for Japanese Society’, p.92; Oriental Economist VIII, I, Jan.1941, p.6. 62 Shinohara (ed.), Kojin Shōhi Shishutsu, p.160, Table19; p.193, Table 45; p.209, Table 58.. 63 Pauer, ‘New Order for Japanese Society’, p.91 64 Shinohara (ed.), Kojin Shōhi Shishutsu, p.195, Table 46. 65 Oriental Economist VII, 6, June 1940, p.335; Hara, ‘Wartime Controls’, p.261. 66 Shinohara (ed.), Kojin Shōhi Shishutsu, p.184, Table 35. 67 Johnston, Japanese Food Management, pp.209-10. 68 William S.Husk, ‘The Japanese Don’t Like It Either’, Amerasia V, 3, May 1941, p.116. 69 Hara, ‘Wartime Controls’, p.262. 14 uncultivated areas outside cities,70 a move that again suggests that consumer livelihoods were an ongoing concern for the authorities. While urban residents were more likely to suffer from declining supplies, however, they did have the advantage of higher incomes than their rural counterparts. The mass exodus of city dwellers to the countryside to purchase food is a phenomenon normally associated with the final years of the war, but an official report in the summer of 1941 complained that urban residents visiting the countryside for the Obon festival in August were buying up everything they could find, not just grain or vegetables, but canned and dried food as well.71 Shortages of clothing were particularly severe. Textile production for domestic use declined as capacity was increasingly restricted to the need to earn foreign exchange. By August 1941 only 50% of Japan’s cotton spinning enterprises were still in operation, and thread output had fallen to around half of the 1937 level. By 1940 imports of the American and Indian raw cotton on which the industry depended were barely a third of the 1936 level.72 Japan depended on imports for 80% of raw hide needs, and a shortage was reported as early as autumn 1937.73 By early 1940 leather for shoe repairs could be obtained only with a permit.74 The demand for the services of cobblers and shoe repairers grew as people sought to prolong the life of their existing footwear.75 As rubber supplies were curtailed or diverted to ‘essential’ use farmers had problems obtaining the rubber boots and rubber soled footwear on which they depended.76 Silk, a key foreign exchange earner, became a rarity even for those who could afford it. Imported raw cotton and wool were increasingly mixed with other fibres for domestic use. From December 1937 woollen and worsted yarns for domestic consumption had to contain 10-40% ‘staple fibre’ (made from bark or wood), while woollen and worsted fabrics had to contain at least 20% staple fibre. Two months later knitted woollen goods, serges and shawls also had to include 20-30% staple fibre.77 Wool was effectively unavailable by early 1941.78 By early 1938 cotton yarns for domestic use also had to contain at least 30% staple fibre, a requirement that in itself exceeded the productive capacity of the staple fibre industry. The pressure to increase staple fibre production brought its own problems, increasing demand for wood pulp, which was already in short supply, and pushing producers into thinking about wood pulp substitutes. Shortages of the carbon bisulphide and caustic soda used in its E.Pauer, ‘A New Order for Japanese Society’, p.96. Scherer, ‘Drawbacks to Controls on Food Distribution’, p.111. 72 M.Miyazaki & O.Ito, ‘Transformation of Industries in the War Years’, in T.Nakamura & K.Odaka (eds.), Economic History of Japan 1914-1955: a Dual Structure (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2003), p.294; Nagaoka, Kindai Nihon no Keizai, pp.24, 28. 73 Oriental Economist IV, 10, October 1937, p.580. 74 D.J.Orchard, ‘The Outlook in Japan’, Amerasia III, 8, Oct.1939, p.466. 75 Havens, Valley of Darkness, p.49. 76 Oriental Economist VII, 7, July 1940, p.416. 77 Oriental Economist IV, 12, December 1937, pp.701-2; V, 2, Feb.1938, p.105. 78 William S.Husk, ‘The Japanese Don’t Like It Either’, Amerasia V, 3, May 1941, p.116. 70 71 15 manufacture were a further problem.79 Staple fibre was stiff and harsh on the skin, could be worn only for a few months, and sometimes gave way altogether if exposed to heavy rain. 80 One commentator suggested that it was also particularly susceptible to being eaten by locusts.81 Residential and other construction was also before too long a victim of the pressure to focus on war needs, which brought with it restrictions on basic inputs such as iron, steel and lumber. By early 1938 commentators were noting particular declines in the construction of individual dwellings, department stores, office buildings, schools and combined shops/dwellings. Ferroconcrete and steel-based construction was particularly badly hit, though iron-frame, wood, brick and stone construction fared better.82 The price of lumber, essential for private dwelling construction, rose considerably, a situation to which the response was to institute what was effectively a government monopoly.83 Cement supply was inadequate to meet demand, and offered a typical example of how a shortage of one commodity had a knock on effect on others. Its manufacture was impeded by shortages of coal (although overall output of coal had increased), and its distribution by shortages of transport facilities, labour and paper bags.84 Energy shortages affected both manufacturers and individuals, who found it increasingly difficult to heat and light their homes, and to travel around within cities, let alone between them. Virtually all oil was imported, and designated for war needs. In April 1939 the government instituted a series of measures aimed at ensuring supplies of coal, which were being endangered by problems in transport and shortages of materials and labour. These included providing for increased housing for miners, and encouraging Korean immigration.85 Overall coal production peaked in 1940, but an increasing proportion was diverted to war industries. As early as the autumn and winter of 1939-40, power shortages erupted when a lack of coal constrained steam powered generation of electricity, compounded by a decline in hydroelectricity consequent on the drought. The search for substitutes was vigorously pursued, but was never very successful.86 Again, it brought its own problems. The search for oil substitutes, for example, increased the demand for coal. A 1938 programme to conserve petrol by mixing it with other forms of alcohol increased industrial demand for potatoes,87 whose production was not a priority for the agricultural sector. 79 Oriental Economist IV, 12, Dec.1937, p.702; V, 2, February 1938, pp.103-4; V, 4, April 1938, pp.226-8; VII, 9, Sept.1940, p.550. The wood pulp shortage was exacerbated by encouraging people to use rayon as a further substitute for natural fibres. The substitutes considered included sugar cane residue (bagasse) and rice husk pulp. 80 William S.Husk, ‘The Japanese Don’t Like It Either’, Amerasia V, 3, May 1941, p.116. 81 Marc T.Greene, ‘How Much Longer, Japan?’, Amerasia IV, 12, February 1941, p.573. 82 Oriental Economist V, 3, March 1938, pp.151-3. 83 Oriental Economist VII, 6, June 1940, p.362. 84 Oriental Economist VII, 8, August 1940, p.488; VIII, 2, Feb.1941, p.93. 85 Oriental Economist VII, 4, April 1940, pp.216-7. 86 M.S.F., ‘Japan Pushes Search for Substitutes’, Far Eastern Survey 7, 22, 9 Nov., 1938; Miriam S.Farley, ‘Coal Sales Licensed in Japan’, Far Eastern Survey 8, 2, 19 Jan., 1939. 87 Johnston, Japanese Food Management, p.83. 16 The direct impact on citizens of these growing constraints was initially limited, but by the end of 1939 air conditioning and elevators in public places were being halted, and people were being urged to limit home consumption.88 Oil-based energy was the main initial target of the government’s efforts. Petrol for vehicles was restricted from 1938, and buses received subsidies to install charcoal generators. By the autumn of 1940 such conversion was compulsory. 89 Many taxis followed suit. A petrol distribution policy proposed in the autumn of 1939 was a source of fierce internal conflict, and provoked an angry response from agricultural interests which took the view that it would prioritise the needs of commerce and manufacturing over those of farming and fishing. The government was forced to compromise,90 but farming remained the loser in the distribution of oil-based fuels. Between 1939 and 1942 the availability of kerosene for use in farm machinery declined by around 60%.91 The chance of obtaining the petrol to operate the few civilian motor vehicles declined rapidly. At the same time, demand for charcoal increased, and charcoal for domestic use was rationed from May 1941.92 Shortages increased, and the government again found itself pushed in the direction of imposing a state monopoly. Charcoal and wood shortages affected heating in private homes, and by early 1941 the public bath houses used by most ordinary Japanese were closed on some days due to lack of fuel.93 Fuel shortages and other equipment shortages also meant overcrowded buses and public transport systems.94 In areas such as Tokyo the implications of this for both living standards and efficiency were considerable. Another commodity regarded as an essential material incentive was tobacco. From the start of the China war maintaining supplies of tobacco to the army became a priority concern, putting civilian consumption under pressure. Tobacco had been a government monopoly since the Meiji period, but its sale and distribution had been substantially according to market principles. Tobacco prices were allowed to rise, and tobacco consumption by value went up considerably in the early years of the conflict. However, the government was accused of acting in contravention of its own price controls by allowing the tobacco monopoly to raise prices in September 1939, just when the prices for most other goods had been frozen.95 It was suggested that by the end of 1940 the two ‘solaces’ of tea and tobacco were beyond the reach of many Japanese. 96 Personal care also became 88 D. J.Orchard, ‘The Outlook in Japan’, Amerasia III, 8, October 1939, p.469. Oriental Economist VIII, 3, March 1941, p.139. 90 Lawrence K.Rosinger, ‘Petroleum Control in Japan Reflects Internal Conflict’, Amerasia IV, 1, March 1940, pp.4346. 91 Johnston, Japanese Food Management, p.114. 92 Hara, ‘Wartime Controls’, p.262. 93 Marc T.Greene, ‘How Much Longer, Japan?’, Amerasia IV, 12, February 1941, p.571 94 Dorothy J.Orchard, ‘The Outlook in Japan’, Amerasia III, 8, October 1939, p.466. 95 Havens, Valley of Darkness, p.49. 96 Marc T.Greene, ‘How Much Longer, Japan?’, Amerasia IV, 12, February 1941, pp.570-1. 89 17 more restricted. Cosmetics and perms were banned in 1939 on the grounds of being unnecessary luxuries,97 and in that context became objects of material shortage as well as social opprobrium. A range of other domestic items were affected by declining supplies resulting from the pressure to use substitutes for expensive imports and switch needed materials to war use. Matches, critical for most households, became subject to a distribution card system in June 1940.98 People were also increasingly pressured to give up their possessions for recycling for war purposes. Metal goods began to be surrendered relatively early on. Scrap metal was collected and the use of substitutes for domestic machinery, pots and pans were encouraged.99 In May 1940 it was decreed that department stores could no longer sell ‘non-essential’ goods, and all such goods had to be disposed of by the first week of October. The consequence was a bonanza of price cuts and purchases.100 It was possible to put a positive slant on this situation. One estimate suggested that ‘compared with pre-Incident days, current department store sales are fully 30% greater with high grade, expensive articles commanding especially ready market’.101 However, many retail workers were laid off or transferred to more ‘essential’ occupations. Although the big department store chains enjoyed expanded sales in 1939-40, they were increasingly hit by the rising cost and general shortage of items for sale, and by anti-luxury campaigns that led to more and more items being prohibited. From spring 1940 they were unable to engage in promotional activities and the prospects for the future were uncertain. ‘In some places, sales counters have become thinly covered with articles though the popular purchasing capacity remains as immense as ever. The department store executives are racking their brains over how to cope with the situation.’102 The more extensive official controls became, and the greater the shortages of particular commodities, the greater the incentives for individuals and organisations to try and circumvent the controls and the greater the divergence between official and ‘real’ prices. (Table 6) Moreover,as Nakamura has noted, well before Pearl Harbor purchase or rationing vouchers did not necessarily produce the promised commodities and unplanned shortages and surpluses of specific goods appeared. Under the circumstances a new phalanx of ‘brokers’ emerged to manipulate market transactions, while black market and illegal channelling of commodities mushroomed.103 The inevitable failure of the regulated market to supply consumers with what they expected and needed was the emergence of a black market which extended to imported commodities and could be exploited by those who had the funds and talent to do so. It was reported in autumn 1939 that 97 Havens, Valley of Darkness, p.18. Oriental Economist VII, 6, June 1940, p.335. 99 Hara, ‘Wartime Controls’, p.256 100 Havens, Valley of Darkness, p.50. 101 Oriental Economist VII, 6, June 1940, p.344. 102 Oriental Economist VII, 12, December 1940, pp.706-7. 103 Nakamura, ‘The Age of Turbulence, 1937-1954’, p.66. 98 18 ‘ordinary Japanese have become small importers exercising their right to 100 yen of foreign exchange a month. With this exchange they buy such things as drills and bits and sell them to a middleman at 200 to 300 per cent profit. The middleman in turn sells to manufacturing establishments at double the price he has paid.’104 Even the most worthy organisations became involved in improper transactions. Pauer reports the illegal exchange of purchase permits within block and neighbourhood associations.105 The black market and official prices for rice had diverged considerably by 1941, and the economic policing mechanisms put in place in August 1938 expanded rapidly. By 1941 there were nearly three quarters of a million police dealing with economic crimes. The number of persons arrested for economic crimes grew from 28,367 in 1939 to 129,110 in 1941,106 but the number of violations were far greater. In Tokyo the Economic Control Section of the police claimed to have exposed over 239,000 violations between August 1938 and December 1939, 148,000 of them in the last five months of 1939 alone.107 In March 1940 the Diet was so concerned about ‘the rampancy of outlaw transactions in many commodities.… attributable to a faulty price policy and distribution of supplies’ that an official note calling on the Government to stamp out such practices was incorporated in the resolution approving the 1940-41 budget.108 Illegal trafficking in fuels and other commodities was widespread. In February 1940 the police rounded up over 2,000 Tokyo sake merchants in connection with market collusion and profiteering. It was recognised however, that the number of cases that resulted in a court appearance, let alone a successful conviction, were lamentably small,109 and as long as prices continued to increase and supplies to diminish, the so-called ‘outlaw transactions’ were unlikely to be brought under control. Evidence suggests that they increased as the war progressed. It is therefore difficult to know how far citizens’ circumvention of the spreading rationing system and price controls meant that their consumption levels were higher than would otherwise have been the case. Time, Leisure and Health In general average working hours were rising over this period, as attempts to increase production in the face of a shortage of labour, especially skilled labour, led to factories pushing for more overtime. There was a cost to such strategies. Exhaustion, illness and accidents among workers increased, especially among the younger workers who were unfamiliar with machinery and 104 D. J.Orchard, ‘The Outlook in Japan’, Amerasia III, 8, October 1939, p.467. Pauer, ‘New Order for Japanese Society’, p.92. 106 Scherer, ‘Drawbacks to Controls on Food Distribution’, pp.114-116. Scherer’s article focuses mainly on the period after 1941, and there is no breakdown by kind of economic crime for these early years 107 L.H.Odell, ‘Japan Fights Widespread Violation of Control Regulations’, Far Eastern Survey 9, 10, 8 May, 1940, pp.121-2. 108 Quoted in Oriental Economist VII, 3, March 1940, p.136. 109 L.H.Odell, ‘Japan Fights Widespread Violation of Control Regulations’, Far Eastern Survey 9, 10, 8 May, 1940, p.122. 105 19 lacked skills. More significantly, if we are thinking of the impact of material incentives, is the fact that absenteeism rates increased markedly over the period 1937-40, becoming very high in some key war-related industries.110 With longer working hours, of course, there was less free time for leisure activities. This was diminished further by less efficient public transport and increasing time spent queuing for rationed or non-rationed goods, something that consumer cooperatives sought to address through collective action.111 The range of leisure activities available to those who could afford them also diminished, notwithstanding buoyant demand. One article in June 1940 remarked that ‘movies, play houses and other theatrical offerings have been doing a booming trade, in a great many cases with tickets sold out for days or even weeks in advance’.112 Dance halls were given a two year warning and forced to close in autumn 1940. One manager reported: ‘They were packed. We were given permission to remain open until 2 a.m. Even on Christmas nights we’d only been allowed to stay open to midnight. The last melody was “Auld Lang Syne”. All the girls were weeping. Understandably. From the morrow they no longer had jobs.’113 Sports activities lost out to more ‘essential’ pursuits. Joseph C.Grew, the US ambassador in Japan, reported in July 1941 that ‘Osaka reported that the annual tennis tournament and other athletic contest scheduled for this week have all been cancelled as they would require space for many students travelling in the trains which are needed for other reasons’.114 While many students were initially protected from conscription into the armed forces, the motivation that they had for their studies appears to have been limited. One commentator who had spoken to faculty and students at Kyoto University described how little work got done, as most of the students lacked much commitment, coming to class or not as they chose, laughed at the authorities and frequently got drunk. The students themselves argued that they might as well enjoy themselves before going off to be killed in China or sent to a dead end job.115 In many respects the health levels of Japanese citizens remained relatively unchanged during the 1937-41 period, at least by comparison with the dramatic declines that occurred later on. Japanese governments had shown a commitment to public health measures since the Meiji period, and had been relatively successful in curbing diseases such as cholera and smallpox, although low income levels had limited sustained increases in life expectancy during the early decades of the 20th century.116 However, levels of health and life expectancy had been improving during the interwar 110 H.Hazama, Chōki Antei Koyō (Tokyo: Bunshindō, 1998), p.81. Pauer, ‘New Order for Japanese Society’, p.96. 112 Oriental Economist VII, 6, June 1940, p.344. 113 Hara Kiyoshi, in Haruko Taya Cook & Theodore F.Cook, Japan at War: an Oral History (New York: The New Press, 1992), p.63. 114 Ten Years in Japan (London: Hammond, Hammond & Co.Ltd., 1944), p.349. 115 William S.Husk, ‘The Japanese Don’t Like It Either’, Amerasia V, 3, May 1941, p.117. 116 S.R.Johansson & C.Mosk, ‘Exposure, Resistance and Life Expectancy: Disease and Death during the Economic Development of Japan, 1900-1960’, Population Studies 41, 2, July 1987. 111 20 years, and in some respects health provision actually improved after the start of the China war. The Welfare Ministry was established in 1938, some workers benefited from national health insurance, and there was a growth in the number of public health centres and health professionals. 117 The birth rate declined significantly in 1938-9, but then recovered in 1940-41.118 Nevertheless, there were signs that these gains were unlikely to be sustained, and as nutrition began to decline so did health. Calorie intake, particularly from animal protein, fell markedly from the late 1930s. Survey data on 17 year olds of both sexes show a marked decline in average height and weight between 1935 and 1945, particularly for mails, but it is hard to determine at what point this decline began. 119 However, one 1938-41 survey of elementary school pupils showed a sharp drop in average weight gain in 1941.120 Mortality data also suggests that 1941 was a turning point in terms of health. From then on rates of mortality from the leading causes of civilian death, which had declined substantially during the 1930s, again started to rise.121 These included tuberculosis, pneumonia and strokes. A clear contributory cause was the declining availability of drugs. Conclusion It has been long established that output per worker in Japan fell steadily throughout the years of conflict. Much of this has been attributed to deficiencies in labour mobilization, and to shortages of skilled workers, inputs and functioning machines.122 It has been suggested here, however, that labour productivity may also have been undermined even before Pearl Harbor by failures in the material incentive structure. The failures in material living standards at this time should not be exaggerated. Experts in the US emphasized early on in the war that there had been a broad improvement in living standards since the First World War, and assumptions by some writers that social unrest in Japan was nearing the point of explosion were grossly exaggerated.123 It was also to be expected that Japanese journals would put a positive gloss on the situation. In mid-1940 The Oriental Economist wrote positively of consumers who could be expected to ‘realize the folly of buying unnecessarily large quantities’ and merchants who would ‘cease selling in anticipation of higher prices’, and rejected predictions of disaster based on claims of shortages and rampant black markets with the resounding statement: ‘Do these surface indicators fully and correctly reflect 117 Havens, Valley of Darkness, p.46; M.S.F., ‘Health Ministry Established in Japan’, Far Eastern Survey 7, 5, Mar.2, 1938. 118 I.B.Taeuber, The Population of Japan (Princeton NJ; Princeton University Press, 1958), p.232; Oriental Economist IV, 8, August 1937, p.456. 119 H.Kitō, ‘Seikatsu Suijun’, in S.Nishikawa, K.Odaka and O.Saitō (eds.), Nihon Keizai no Nihyakunen (Tokyo: Nihon Hyōronsha, 1996), pp..437, 439. 120 Scherer, ‘Drawbacks to Controls on Food Distribution’, p.109 121 Tauber, Population of Japan, p.290. 122 Cohen, Japan’s Economy in War and Reconstruction, p.275. 123 Article by Staff of the American Council, Far Eastern Survey 6, 21, Oct.20, 1937, p.246; Elizabeth Boody Schumpeter, ‘Japanese Economic Policy and the Standard of Living’, Far Eastern Survey 7, 2, Jan.19, 1938, p.13ff. 21 Japan’s economic position? In other words, is Japan so hopelessly impoverished as one would be inclined to believe on the basis of these reports of apparent distress? Our answer is, positively, No’.124 At the same time, however, this and other journals continued to document and disseminate extensive empirical data on prices, goods availability and consumption that led to a very different conclusion. That this was recognized by the state is apparent from the emphasis in the 1940 labour mobilization plan that ‘In view of the drop in the will to produce and the physical deterioration of the labourers, special emphasis will be placed upon efforts to preserve labour efficiency…’.125 124 125 Oriental Economist VII, 6, June 1940, p.335 Quoted in Cohen, Japan’s Economy in War and Reconstruction, p.310. 22 Table 1. Tokyo Wholesale Price Index, 1936-1942 (January 1913 = 100) 168.3 206.0 227.5 243.3 266.6 280.8 298.0 1936 1937 1938 1939 1940 1941 1942 Source: Tōyō Keizai Nenkan 1944, p.125 Table 2. Tokyo Retail Price Index 1942 (1937=100) Food/Drink 183.9 Housing 213.1 Light/Heat 164.3 Clothing 273.6 Source: Tokyo Metropolitan Authorities reported in Tōyō Keizai Nenkan 1944, p.136 Table 3. Workers’ Living Expenses 1939-1942 (July 1937=100) 1939 1940 1941 1942 Food/Drink 123.2 152.3 152.5 156.3 Housing 107.3 115.3 119.4 124.4 Light/Heat 122.6 139.9 142.3 147.5 Clothing 150.6 185.5 202.5 216.5 Overall 121.2 143.4 147.3 153.7 Source: Index compiled by Tōyō Keizai Shinpōsha, published in Tōyō Keizai Nenkan 1944, p.137 Table 4. Tokyo Wholesale Price Index for Specified Commodities (1931=100) 1937 1938 1939 1940 1941 Cereals 181.7 188.9 238.7 267.5 270.0 Other Foods 119.5 128.1 144.8 167.9 175.6 Source: Tōyō Keizai Nenkan vol.28, 1944, pp.126-33 23 Metals 279.6 307.9 261.7 273.5 281.8 Table 5. Factory Workers’ Average Daily Wages August 1942 (¥) Men 3.84 3.23 3.12 3.30 2.42 2.97 2.84 3.30 3.24 Metals Machine Tools Chemicals Utilities Spinning/weaving Lumber/woodworking Foodstuffs Printing/publishing All industries Women 1.49 1.59 1.42 1.25 1.11 1.30 1.29 1.57 1.32 Source: Cabinet Statistics Office Table 6. Index of Real and Official Prices, Japan, 1936-1941 (1936=100) Wholesale Prices Retail Prices Real Official Real Official 1936 100 100 100 100 1937 119 121 109 110 1938 126 127 120 125 1939 145 141 135 141 1940 171 158 175 163 1941 184 167 204 165 Source: J.B.Cohen, Japan’s Economy in War and Reconstruction, p.97. 24