Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
ARTICLE IN PRESS Energy Policy ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]] Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Energy Policy journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/enpol Viewpoint Review of OECD study into ‘‘Projected costs of generating electricity—2010 Edition’’ Hisham Khatib Global Energy Award Laureate (2007), P.O. Box 410, Amman 11831, Jordan a r t i c l e in fo abstract Article history: Received 6 May 2010 Accepted 9 May 2010 This joint report by the International Energy Agency (IEA) and the OECD Nuclear Energy Agency (NEA) is the seventh in the long established series of studies into electricity generating costs. It presents the main results of the work carried out in 2009 for calculating the costs of generating baseload electricity. The study is quite comprehensive in covering almost all financial aspects facing investors in the electricity generating system. Therefore this study although useful, its usefulness lies in explaining methodologies, mentioning factors that affect investment and cost, educating planners and improving investment evaluation and planning methodologies, its resulting figures and cost comparisons are however controversial. Generation planning and investments are case and country specific, and should be studied correspondingly and as close as possible to the timing of decision making to take account of trends. Most likely such case specific results will differ from figures calculated in the study. Therefore we need to emphasize a key conclusion of the study which is ‘‘that country-specific circumstances determine the LCOE’’; it is this that needs to be considered and not the results represented in the study. & 2010 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. Keywords: Electricity Generating plant Economics This joint report by the International Energy Agency (IEA) and the OECD Nuclear Energy Agency (NEA) is the seventh in the long established series of studies into electricity generating costs. It is referred to later as the ‘‘study’’. Projected Costs of Generating Electricity—2010 Edition (OECD, 2010) presents the main results of the work carried out in 2009 for calculating the costs of generating baseload electricity from nuclear and fossil fuel thermal power stations as well as the costs of generating electricity from a wide range of renewable technologies. All of the included technologies are expected to be commissioned by 2015. The work was conducted under the supervision of the Ad hoc Expert Group on Electricity Generating Costs which was composed of representatives of the participating OECD member countries, experts from the industry and academia as well as from the European Commission and the International Atomic Energy Agency (IAEA). This review is in two parts. Part I directly quotes the main assumptions and conclusions of the study as outlined in its Executive Summary. Part II is a critical evaluation of some of the assumptions and methodologies adopted in this study as well as its conclusions. E-mail address: [email protected] 1. Part I—Study assumptions, methodologies and main conclusions 1.1. Methodology and generic assumptions The study focuses on the expected plant-level costs of base load electricity generation by power plants that could be commissioned by 2015. It also includes the generating costs of a wide range of renewable energy sources, some of which have variable output. In addition, the report covers projected costs related to advanced power plants of innovative designs, namely commercial plants equipped with carbon capture, which might reach the level of commercial availability and be commissioned by 2020. Cost data provided by the experts were compiled and used to calculate the levelised costs of electricity (LCOE) for base load power generation. The calculations are based on the simple levelised average (unit) lifetime cost approach, using the discounted cash flow (DCF) method. The most important assumptions concern the utilization of two real discount rates, 5% and 10% (common to all technologies), also keeping with tradition, fuel prices and, for the first time, a carbon price of $ 30 per ton of CO2. The study reaches two important conclusions (see Figs. 1 and 2 below). First, in the low discount rate case, more capital-intensive, low-carbon technologies such as nuclear energy are the most competitive solutions compared with coal-fired plants without carbon capture and natural gas-fired combined cycle plants for 0301-4215/$ - see front matter & 2010 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2010.05.023 Please cite this article as: Khatib, H., Review of OECD study into ‘‘Projected costs of generating electricity—2010 Edition’’. Energy Policy (2010), doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2010.05.023 ARTICLE IN PRESS 2 H. Khatib / Energy Policy ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]] Fig. 1. Regional ranges of LCOE for nuclear, coal, gas and onshore wind power plants (at 5% discount rate). Fig. 2. Regional ranges of LCOE for nuclear, coal, gas and onshore wind power plants (at 10% discount rate). base load generation. It should be emphasized that these results incorporate a carbon price of $ 30 per ton of CO2. Second, in the high discount rate case, coal without carbon capture equipment, followed by coal with carbon capture equipment, and gas-fired combined cycle turbines (CCGTs), are the cheapest sources of electricity. In the high discount rate case, coal without CC(S) is always cheaper than coal with CC(S), even in low-cost coal regions, at a carbon price of $ 30 per ton. The results highlight the paramount importance of discount rates and, to a lesser extent, carbon and fuel prices when comparing different technologies. The study also includes extensive sensitivity analyses to test the relative impact of variations in key cost parameters (such as discount rates, construction costs, fuel and carbon prices, load factors, lifetimes and lead times for construction) on the economics of different generating technologies individually considered. The electricity generation costs calculated are plant-level (busbar) costs, at the station, and do not include transmission and distribution costs. Finally, the cost estimates do not include any external costs associated either with residual emissions (other than CO2 emissions) or impacts on the security of supply. A key conclusion is that countryspecific circumstances determine the LCOE. 1.2. Main results The most important results is the fact that nuclear, coal, gas and, where local conditions are favorable, hydro and wind, are Please cite this article as: Khatib, H., Review of OECD study into ‘‘Projected costs of generating electricity—2010 Edition’’. Energy Policy (2010), doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2010.05.023 ARTICLE IN PRESS H. Khatib / Energy Policy ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]] now fairly competitive generation technologies for base load power generation. Their precise cost competitiveness depends more than anything on the local characteristics of each particular market and their associated cost of financing, as well as CO2 and fossil fuel prices. As mentioned earlier, the lower the cost of financing, the better the performance of capital-intensive, low-carbon technologies such as nuclear, wind or CC(S); at higher rates, coal without CC(S) and gas will be more competitive. In the view of the study there is no technology that has a clear overall advantage globally or even regionally. Each one of these technologies has potentially decisive strengths and weaknesses that are not always reflected in the LCOE figures provided in the study. 3 2. Part II—critical evaluation It must be emphasized that this 2010 edition is a comprehensive study. It deals not only with the methodology, conclusions and technology review; but it also covers country-by-country data, sensitivity analyses, financing issues, working of actual power markets and carbon capture and storage. The study covers in an extensive way renewable power generation and its system integration. These sources, in spite of their modest contribution, are gaining increasing attention in OECD countries and apparently the study recognizes this in a rather extensive analysis. In the following section, I will present a critical review of some of the study’s assumptions; these include: common discount rates, decommissioning costs, fuel and carbon prices, reference year, as well as the way in dealing with system and other costs. 1.3. Conclusions of the study The levelised costs and the relative competitiveness of different power generation technologies in each country are highly sensitive to the discount rate and slightly less, but still significantly sensitive, to the projected prices for CO2, natural gas and coal. For renewable energy technologies, country- and sitespecific load factors also play an important role. With the liberalization of electricity markets, certain risks have become more transparent, so that project proponents must now bear and closely manage these risks (to the extent that they can no longer be transferred to consumers or taxpayers). This has implications for determining the required rate of return on generation investments. Access to financing and national support policies for individual technologies designed to reduce financing risks (such as feed-in tariffs, loan or price guarantees) are thus likely to play an important role in determining final power generation choices. Environmental policy will also play an increasingly important role that is likely to significantly influence fossil fuel costs in the future and the relative competitiveness of various generation technologies. In addition, the markets for natural gas are undergoing substantial changes on many levels which make current projections for prices even more uncertain than usual. Also, coal markets are being influenced by new factors. Security of energy supply remains a concern for most OECD countries and may be reflected in government policies affecting generating investment in the future. The study provides insights into the relative costs of generating technologies in the participating countries and reflects the limitations of the methodology and the generic assumptions employed. The limitations inherent in the approach are stressed in the report. In particular, the cost estimates presented do not represent the precise costs which would be calculated by potential investors for any specific project. Together with national energy policies favouring or discouraging specific technologies, the investors’ concern about risk is one of the reasons explaining the difference between the study’s findings and the market preference for gas-fired technologies. Different fuel price expectations may also affect investors’ decisions in some markets. Within this framework and various limitations, the study suggests that no single electricity generating technology can be expected to be the cheapest in all situations. The preferred generating technology will depend on a number of key parameters and the specific circumstances of each project. This edition of Projected Costs of Generating Electricity indicates that the investors’ choice of a specific portfolio of power generation technologies will most likely depend on financing costs, fuel and carbon prices, as well as the specific energy policy context (security of supply, CO2 emissions reductions, market framework). 2.1. Discount rates Discounting is the most important aspect in project evaluation and choices of the least cost project (Khatib, 2003). The methodology adopted in the study is based on a fixed discount rate (5% or 10%) common to all forms of considered generation technologies. This is a controversial approach. As is well known the discount rate, is the opportunity cost of capital (as a percentage of the value of the capital). In turn the opportunity cost of capital is the return on investments forgone elsewhere by committing capital to the project under consideration. It is also referred to as the marginal productivity of capital, i.e. the rate of return which would have been obtained by the last acceptable project. In investment decisions, the opportunity cost of capital is the cut-off rate, below which it is not worthwhile to invest in the project. To serve this purpose, the nominal discount rate should be equal to at least a value which, after tax, would provide the investor with the following: (i) compensation for a reduction in the purchasing power of money which is brought about by inflation, (ii) a real return, (iii) compensation for the extent of risk undertaken by committing capital to this investment. The value of the nominal discount rate is correspondingly a function of the above three factors, namely inflation, risk-free real return and the extent of risk in the project (or technology). The methodology of the study opted to chose a real discount rate, which ignores inflation. When reference is made to the discount rate, then it is the real discount rate that is meant. But by choosing a common discount rate that applies to different generating technologies, and investment decisions, the methodology ignored the most important aspect of choosing a discount rate which is the ‘‘compensation for the extent of risk of this type of generation technology’’. Is the risk of investing in nuclear facilities the same as investing in CCGT, or does investing in a traditional coal plant carry the same risk as investing in the yet un-established new technologies of renewable plants; are the long term risks of investing in traditional carbon emitting technologies similar to new technologies with carbon capture and storage (CCS)? In my view, definitely not. Nuclear facilities (because of its capital intensive nature, long execution time and public controversies) carry more investment risk than that of conventional facilities, and investing in a carbon emitting coal plant can pose a higher long term risks to an investor (carbon taxation) than in building a cleaner gas firing plant. Different generating technologies have different risks; correspondingly discount rate(s) utilized should be different for each form of generation technology to connote the perceived risk in investing in this technology. Please cite this article as: Khatib, H., Review of OECD study into ‘‘Projected costs of generating electricity—2010 Edition’’. Energy Policy (2010), doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2010.05.023 ARTICLE IN PRESS 4 H. Khatib / Energy Policy ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]] Increasingly investing in generation facilities is being undertaken by the private sector through independent power producers (IPPs) or private–public partnership (PPP) where the perceived risk of the investment carries a primary role in decision making, like what takes place in financial markets. In the financial market a stock’s sensitivity to change in the value of the market portfolio is known as ‘‘beta’’. Beta, therefore, measures the marginal contribution of a stock to the risk of a market portfolio. In a competitive market, the expected risk premium varies in direct proportion to beta. This is the capital asset pricing model (Bealey and Myers, 2000), usually referred to as (CAPM). Expected risk premium on a stock¼beta expected risk premium on market. Therefore, treasury bills have a beta of zero because they do not carry any risk. The average equity in the market portfolio has a beta of 1. Generally speaking: Expected risk premium on investment ¼ beta average market risk premium. Real discount rate ¼ real risk-free rate + (market risk premium beta). Fig. 3. Sensitivity of nuclear and coal power station costs to discount rate (Following assumptions of Dimson 1989). Investment cost (pounds million) Operating costs/kWh Fuel cost/kWh (ignoring carbon cost) Nuclear Coal 1527 0.37 p 0.45 p 895 0.46 p 1.43 p p (pence) ¼0.01 pounds sterling ¼1.5 US cents. Apparently, no general global figure can be put into the beta of every generation technology or a new facility. Generation utilities have a higher risk and correspondingly higher beta value than distribution utilities. Nuclear has a higher risk than other forms of thermal generation and, correspondingly, utilities with nuclear generation have a higher beta than other generating utilities, depending on the extent of their nuclear component. New renewable facilities carry more investment risk than well established CCGT gas-firing facilities. Because of the uncertainty about future carbon pricing, investing in large long lead time pulverized coal-firing and heavy carbon emitting generating units is riskier than investing in smaller short lead time CCGT plant firing cleaner gas and which easily fits the load curve. Therefore the discount rate(s) to be utilized in comparing different generation technologies needs to be calculated in a CAPM methodology depending on a beta for each technology which can lead to a different discount rate for each new facility technology. It is these risks, as reflected in different ‘‘beta’’ and correspondingly a different discount rate, which can differ from one technology to another, are the main concerns of the investor. Obviously, the discount rate is crucial in such decision making between alternatives, as demonstrated in the following Fig. 3 (Dimson 1989). The figure demonstrates the important fact of the sensitivity of the cost of different types of technologies to the choice of the discount rate. It is clear that, because future net benefits are greatly reduced by the higher discount rate, the cost per kWh rises for capital intensive nuclear power stations more rapidly than it does for the less capital but higher operating cost coal power stations. For low operating cost alternatives, like nuclear, the high net benefits are severely eroded by the high discount rate, although the high up front capital investment is compounded by the high discount rate to the base year of commissioning. For the higher operating cost alternative, the net benefits as well as the up front investment are smaller and, correspondingly, the result is less affected by discounting. The choice of the proper interest rate is crucial in such highly different investment cost alternatives. The fact that the study assesses different technologies, by the same common discount rate disregarding the market and their technology risk, is one of the study’s weak points. 2.2. Decommissioning A major element of cost and risk consideration in investing in nuclear facilities is the decommissioning costs of the nuclear power plant. The study states that a generic assumption of 15% of the construction cost has been applied to calculate the costs incurred during all the management and technical actions associated with ceasing operation of a nuclear installation and its subsequent dismantling to obtain its removal from regulatory control. Disbursed during the ten years following shut-down, the decommissioning cost is discounted back to the date of commissioning and incorporated in the overall levelised costs. While an incontestably important element of nuclear power plant’s operation, due to the effect of discounting, decommissioning accounts for a smaller portion of the LCOE. In particular, the fact is that for nuclear power plants decommissioning costs are due after 60 years of operation, discounting them back to the commissioning date, makes the net present value of decommissioning close to zero, even when applying lower discount rates or assuming much higher decommissioning costs. Correspondingly the study actually considers the cost of decommissioning of nuclear power plants to be zero for today’s decisions. Is that a correct and fair treatment for investment decisions? Does it not represent shifting problems made by the present generation into the shoulders of the future generation, which is contrary to be basic assumptions of sustainable development. The investor of today does not care about costs incurred after sixty years however serious they were. It is others who have to wrestle with this problem and bear its substantial costs when it looms in the long term. Most likely it is going to be heavy social costs. Therefore the study’s practical assumption (brought out by discounting), that decommissioning costs are negligible for today’s decisions, is not fair, to say the least. Decommissioning costs, particularly of nuclear plants, have to be taken into account in today’s investment decisions. This can take many forms; one of them is to account for these costs with a ‘‘social discount rate’’ of zero. So that their estimated value will be fully incorporated in today’s investment costs, without discounting. An alternative arrangement is to account for them in the risk factor ‘‘beta’’. If today two plants have similar investment and operational Please cite this article as: Khatib, H., Review of OECD study into ‘‘Projected costs of generating electricity—2010 Edition’’. Energy Policy (2010), doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2010.05.023 ARTICLE IN PRESS H. Khatib / Energy Policy ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]] costs, the one with the high decommissioning cost needs to have a higher ‘beta’ than the other plant. The decommissioning cost will be reflected in having a different beta and correspondingly higher discount rate and lower benefits of the future income stream for plants with high long term decommissioning cost. 2.3. Carbon price and fuel prices The study allocates carbon price of $ 30 per ton of CO2 in OECD countries. Presently carbon is traded in the EU ETS (European Trading System) at less than $ 20 per ton. Carbon pricing and trading is a highly unpredictable subject with its long term prospects obscure. However pricing carbon, for comparing the economics of different generating facilities, has tremendous implications. CO2 prices or costs are explicit in the European Union (EU) with the introduction of the ETS in 2005. There are also indications of investors in other OECD countries, for example in the US, taking carbon pricing into account when making investment decisions, on the expectation that such a price will emerge in the future. CO2 prices in the EU ETS have fluctuated between $ 10 and $ 40/tCO2, reflecting great uncertainty, particularly regulatory uncertainty and initial problems related to the start of the system, but also reflecting competition between gas and coal, depending on their relative prices. The generic assumption for carbon prices was $ 30 per ton of carbon in the study for all OECD countries and zero for nonmember countries. The CO2 module of the study calculates the carbon cost per MWh. Whenever available, national data on carbon emission per MWh was used. Otherwise data were derived from the 2006 IPCC Guidelines (IPCC, 2006). Typically, carbon emissions are around 100 tCO2/TJ for hard coal and 50 tCO2/TJ for gas. With standard electric conversion factors of 40% and 55%, this amounts to emission of 0.9 tCO2/MWh for electricity from hard coal and of 0.33 tCO2/MWh for electricity from gas-fired power generation. The study concluded (Fig. 1) that average median LCOE for coal plant in the US was around $ 72/MWh, of this carbon prices were $ 27/MWh, i.e. around 38% of cost and more expensive than fuel costs. In Europe the median was around $ 82/MWh of which carbon prices were one third. These are very significant costs which reflect the importance of carbon pricing in generation costing, particularly for coal plant. A price of $ 30/ton of CO2, as utilized in the study, cannot be generalized and each decision must be considered on its own merits. Price of fuel in the study is also disputed. This study assumes a long-term OECD steam coal import cost of $ 90/ton, noting that several OECD regions have costs well below this level and are not subject to the fluctuations of international markets. For these countries the study has used domestic coal prices for the country’s levelised cost calculations, in particular for Australia ($ 26.65/t of hard coal), Mexico ($ 87.50/t of hard coal) and the United States. ($ 47.60/t of hard coal), noting that in some regions of the US, coal prices are significantly below this price. However price of gas in this study, a generic natural gas import price of $ 10.3/MMBtu was assumed for European imports and $ 12.7 for Asian LNG. Domestic natural gas prices were applied in producing regions, namely in North America ($7.78/MMBtu) and Australia ($8/MMBtu). Such prices of natural gas are almost twice the prices prevailing now (April 2010), which casts serious shadow on the results of the study in case of costing output of CCGT plants and invalidates some of its conclusions. 5 2.4. Reference year The study is clear about the commissioning date (31.12.2015) and all the discounting of the costs and benefits of the project are allocated to that date. Costs and benefits are discounted according to ‘‘t’’ which denotes the year in which the sale of production or the cost of disbursement takes place compared to the commissioning date. But we have to realize that not all costs and benefits occur at the end of the year. The main benefits of electricity production, which is generation in kilowatt hour (kWh), occur continuously every hour of the year. To accumulate these as a single generation figure at the end of the year, as implied in the study, is an inaccurate approximation. Payments for salaries, fuel, etc. are costs which are incurred monthly and continue throughout the year. To lump them as a single payment at the end of the year and to discount them will result in an underestimation. To overcome this, such financial flows can be presented in a monthly form (or hourly) which makes the calculation cumbersome. As an alternative, they can be lumped as an annual flow at the middle of the year, which is a useful approximation. Therefore, if the commissioning year is the last day of year 2015, then the cash flow of the first year has to be grouped at the middle of year 2016 for present valuing purposes, and discounted for half a year. The second year’s cash flow is grouped at 1.5 years from the commissioning date, etc. Deviation from this, like the common practice of grouping all cash flows at the end of the year, causes some error. 2.5. Other costs The study recognizes that there are other significant costs that affect the comparison of LCOE of different plants. However these are not included in the study since each case and site has its particular costs. However cost of transmission greatly influences the choice of the least cost generation option. This particularly applies to renewables which are sited in remote places, like wind turbines, and many a time large solar plants are located in deserts. Many renewables are severely penalized by transmission costs and correspondingly abandoned. The study also recognizes difficulties in incorporating renewals in dispatching and building reserves in generation systems. No specific costs are allocated to these since they have to be considered individually. Correspondingly renewables, which according to the study are already higher in cost than conventional plants, will be severely penalized when individually considered with site locations and dispatching considerations. Their LCOE can be much higher than that quoted in the study. 3. Part III—to conclude The study is quite comprehensive in covering almost all financial aspects facing investors in the electricity generating system. It also deals with the effect of taxes, interest rates, currency exchange rates, weighted average cost of capital (WACC), inflation, impact of the recent economic recession, etc. However as mentioned above and as the study recognizes, it ignores external costs and cost of transmission and country specific investment considerations particularly specific country risk and technology risk. Most important are variations in fuel prices, particularly recent reduction in the price of natural gas, which has rendered some of its costing, particularly for CCGT Please cite this article as: Khatib, H., Review of OECD study into ‘‘Projected costs of generating electricity—2010 Edition’’. Energy Policy (2010), doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2010.05.023 ARTICLE IN PRESS 6 H. Khatib / Energy Policy ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]] generation, out-of-date. This besides the important five reservations mentioned in Part II of this review. Therefore this study although useful, its usefulness lies in explaining methodologies, mentioning factors that affect investment and cost, educating planners and improving investment evaluation and planning methodologies, its resulting figures and cost comparisons are however controversial. Generation planning and investments are case and country specific, and should be studied correspondingly and as close as possible to the timing of decision making to take account of trends. Most likely such case specific results will differ from figures calculated in the study. Therefore we need to emphasize a key conclusion of the study which is ‘‘that country-specific circumstances determine the LCOE’’; it is this that needs to be considered and not the results represented in the study. References OECD, 2010. Projected Cost of Generating Electricity, 2010 edition. Khatib, H., 2003. Financial and Economic Evaluation of Projects in the Electricity Supply Industry.. Institution of Electrical Engineers, London 2003. Bealey, R.A., Myers, S.C., 2000. Principles of Corporate Finance. McGraw Hill 2000. Dimson, E., 1989. The discount rate of a power station. Energy Economics 11, 13. IPCC, 2006. IPCC Guidelines for National Greenhouse Inventories, Chapter 2 ‘‘Stationary Combustion’’, p 2.16. Please cite this article as: Khatib, H., Review of OECD study into ‘‘Projected costs of generating electricity—2010 Edition’’. Energy Policy (2010), doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2010.05.023