Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Demutualization of cooperatives: Reasons and effects. Keywords: cooperative, demutualization, growth, conversion, transformation Authors: Elena Meliá Martí and Mª Pía Carnicer Andrés Affiliation: CEGEA (Centre for Research in Business Administration). Universitat Politècnica de València. Abstract Demutualization is an increasingly common reality in the world of European cooperatives. It can be held in its purest form, with the disappearance of the mutual base entity and its conversion to other forms, or understood in a broader concept as the implementation of models that deviate from the cooperative principles and from the traditional cooperative model. This paper analyzes, first of all, the causes or reasons that drive cooperatives into a demutualization process. Secondly, from a sample consisting on the 80 largest agri-food cooperatives in the European Union (of the dairy, meat, horticulture and supplies sectors), we will select those that have chosen in their expansive model the creation of a business corporation and the entrance of external investors (reducing therefore the percentage of the cooperative control over the entity) in order to analyze the profile of cooperatives that have demutualized; and finally, using panel data, it will be studied the degree of fulfillment of those objectives that led to the migration to other formulas (as business corporations). 1. - Introduction The production of agricultural cooperatives represents the 60% of total agricultural production in the EU-15. In some countries the cooperative market share exceeds 90%, such as the milk production in Denmark, Austria, Finland and the Netherlands, pork in Denmark and cut flowers in the Netherlands, facts that show the farmers’ confidence in this form of association (Juliá and Meliá, 2008). The agri-food industry in which they operate is characterized by high price volatility (Committee on Agriculture and Rural Development, European Parliament, 2009), the growth of agricultural production costs, as a result of the increase in input prices, the consequent reduction in agricultural incomes and the increasing concentration of demand. Therefore, cooperatives have adopted various business growth strategies, through formulas such as mergers and acquisitions, joint ventures, the creation of federated structures, etc.., consolidating large cooperative groups in the European Union. There are several studies that prove this fact, as is the case of Hudson and Herndon (2000) whose results from a survey of a sample of 500 U.S. cooperatives in 2000 showed that 78.5% of the surveyed cooperatives had participated in a merger or acquisition over the past five years, distributed as follows: 25.4% had been involved in a merger, 30.5% in an acquisition, 33.2% in a joint venture and 11.8% have had an strategic alliance (Hudson and Herndon, 2000). Demutualization has been analyzed and studied by several researchers all over the world. However, there is not a clear definition of the term. In general, the term demutualization is associated with processes such as conversion or transformation. There is a tendency for large cooperatives towards creating business corporations, with greater flexibility to respond to the requirements of the global and competitive economic context in which they operate. Most authors describe demutualization as a process in which the cooperative ceases to exist and / or becomes an economic entity, far from the mutual nature (Chaddad and Cook, 2004). However, there exists disagreement in the degree of detachment that should be given in order to call it ‘demutualization’. According to Chaddad and Cook (2004), conversion, increasingly known as demutualization (Birchall, 2001), refers to changes in the ownership structure of user owned and controlled organizations from a mutual to a for-profit, proprietary organization. As a result of demutualization, residual claim and control rights are reassigned among stakeholders with implications to firm behavior and performance. In particular, cooperative membership rights are converted to unrestricted common stock ownership rights in a corporate organization. In order to get extra financing, most of the demutualizations are followed by public listing, and members are invited to exchange their shares and become members of the corporation. There are some studies that have analyzed the reasons given by the entities that have opted in this process of expansion by formulas that involve a greater or lesser level of demutualization; among them the following are included (Cronan, 2007; Fulton and Hueth, 2009): - the need to access capital beyond the membership base - the desire by members to be able to access their equity or realize the market value of the co-op - the desire to unlock the value in co-operatives/mutuals for members and other investors and to enable this to be freely tradable - the requirement for a more commercial, flexible, competitive and less restrictive corporate structure - the lack of a sufficiently strong understanding of and support for co-operative and mutual principles, values and member service within the organization - a public policy environment which often doesn’t fully understand the needs and operational character of co-operative and mutual organizations - Poor management of the cooperative. 2. - Objectives This paper presents a triple objective: First, it attempts to explore the concept of demutualization (through existing references in this area), the reasons that cause it and the different formulas used by cooperatives to address it. Secondly, from a sample consisting on the 80 largest agri-food cooperatives in the European Union (of the dairy, meat, horticulture and supplies sectors), we will selected those that have chosen in their expansive model the creation of a business corporation and the entrance of external investors (reducing therefore the percentage of the cooperative control over the entity) in order to analyze the profile of cooperatives that have demutualized (compared to those that have not demutualized). Finally, using panel data, it will be studied the degree of fulfillment of those objectives that led to the migration to other formulas (as business corporations). 3.- References BIRCHALL, J. (2002). “Mutual, non-profit or public interest company? An evaluation of options for the ownership and control of water utilities”. Annals of Public and Cooperative. Economics, Volume 73 Issue 2, pp.181. CHADDAD, F. and COOK, M. (2004). “The Economics of Organization Structure Changes: a US perspective on demutualization”. In: Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics 75:4, pp. 575–594. COMMITTEE ON AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT, EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT (2009). “Report on the prices of food products in Europe, 24th February 2009”. Presented to the European Parliament. (http://www.europarl.europa.eu) CRONAN, G. (2007). “Something for Nothing - It's Fabulous”: An Australian Perspective of Demutualisation. New South Wales Department of Fair Trading, Australia. pp. 1-13 http://www.ica.coop/coop/mutuality/garrycronansomethingfornothing.pdf FULTON, M. and HUETH B. (2009) “Cooperative Conversions, Failures and Restructurings: An Overview”. Journal of cooperatives. Vol 23. pp. 1-11. HUDSON, D. and HERNDON, C. (2000). “Mergers, acquisitions, Joint Ventures and Strategic Alliances in Agricultural Cooperatives”. Research Report 2000009. Mississipi State University. JULIÁ, J. and MELIÁ, E. (2008). “Social Economy and the Cooperative Movement in Europe: Contributions to a New Vision of Agriculture and Rural Development in the Europe of 27”. CIRIEC-España, Revista de Economía Pública, Social y Cooperativa, n. 62, Special Issue, pp. 147-173.