* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Dynamics between Military Expenditures and
Survey
Document related concepts
Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup
Steady-state economy wikipedia , lookup
Economics of fascism wikipedia , lookup
Business cycle wikipedia , lookup
Chinese economic reform wikipedia , lookup
Transformation in economics wikipedia , lookup
Transcript
Dynamics between Military Expenditures and Economic Growth: What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Bachelor Thesis: International Economics & Finance at Tilburg University R.P. Roborgh 369326 06-06-2010 Supervisor: A.C. Meijdam Number of Words: 8496 Faculty of Economics and Business Administration Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Table of Content: Chapter 1: Introduction 2 Chapter 2: Literature 4 2.1 History of Theories 2.2 Major Channels 2.3 Hypotheses Chapter 3: Research 4 16 18 20 3.1 Database 3.2 Research 20 21 Chapter 4: Conclusion 27 Literature List 29 Appendix A: Variables 31 Appendix B: Countries 32 Appendix C: Regressions 33 Page 1 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? CHAPTER81:8INTRODUCTION The financial crisis of 2007 was followed by a public debt crisis all over the Western-world. Especially in European countries, markets have put a lot of pressure to improve state finances. While the north of Europe is doing relatively well on economic growth and public finances, the south of Europe is having more trouble to deal with the aftermath of the financial crisis. To decrease budget deficits and to slow the pace at which debt-to-GDP ratios increase around Europe, governments have made and will continue to make tough choices on where to cut their spending. Military spending is one of the expenditures most targeted by budget cutters and is also one of the expenditures where cuts are most visible to the public. For example, in April 2011, the Dutch government announced to cut all tanks, four (out of ten) minesweepers and all Cougar-helicopters, giving budget cuts a physical character (Volkskrant,22011). Not only do governments have to find billions of budget cuts, they are also in the danger zone of choking the weak economic growth which should soften the impact of worsening debt ratios and which is the source of their tax base. It is therefore important to analyze what the impact is of specific government expenditures on economic growth. If there is a strong positive relationship, it would be unwise to cut spending, while in the case of a insignificant or negative relationship, cutting could even accelerate economic growth. In this thesis I will research this relationship for military spending. Although the world is changing fast and European countries face different threats every year, I will not look at strategic determinants of military spending or the ideal amount of military spending from a security perspective. The reason is that recent revisions in military spending have shown that military spending cuts and preparing the army for the future, might go hand in hand. Last year, the United Kingdom and France have announced to cooperate on aircraft carriers, while former defense minister of Germany Zu Guttenberg planned to cancel obligatory conscription to reduce spending. Military cooperation is a good way to economize on the military budget while increasing security for the participants. Because of the ambiguous effects of military budget cuts on security this research is solely aimed at showing the relationship between military expenditures (to which I will refer in this paper with “milex”) and economic growth and will only look at strategic factors when they have a direct influence on this relationship. Page 2 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? The8aim8of8the8research8and8a8first8definition8of8the8subject8matter The aim of this research is to show the correlation between military spending and economic growth for (Western) European countries. A lot of research, starting with Benoit in 1973 has been done so far on this milex-growth relationship. However, this research was mostly based on undeveloped countries and only exceptionally on Europe. The research was often straight to the point and ignored special characteristics as neutrality or a strong domestic defence industry (Military Industrial Complex). Therefore, in this research I will also compare European countries based on their neutrality and domestic defence sector. An interesting part of defence economics literature concerns hegemonic leadership decline. France and England are the only two military superpowers left in Europe. I will research if leaders receive a premium on their economic growth or a discount. This leaves me with the following research questions: - What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? - What does having a strong domestic defence industry mean to real economic growth compared to having a small domestic defence industry? - What is the effect of a foreign policy based on neutrality on real economic growth? - Do European leaders grow stronger than non-leaders? The8methods8and8approaches8to8be8used This research consists out of four chapters. The second chapter will describe the history of research done so far on defence economics. It is based on the most commonly used groups of theories, namely: Marxist/Underconsumptionist, the Keynesian/Institutionalist and the Neoclassical plus the most influential independent theories. Besides that, this chapter will also name all channels that were not included in these theories but have been named or proven by economists. The aim of this is to show how defence economics has developed through the last forty years and how complex defence economics is. I will also include the assumptions and theories behind the research questions in this chapter. In chapter 3 I will do regressions to obtain the correlation between milex and economic growth and to obtain specifics results for the sub-groups. I use the SIPRI (Stockholm International Peace Research Institute) for data on milex and a combination of sources for data on economic variables. In chapter 4 I will give my conclusions on this research and answer the research questions. Page 3 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? CHAPTER 2 2.1 History of Theories The research on defense economics started with Benoit in 1973 who researched the milexgrowth relationship for developing nations. He found a positive relationship implying that an increase in military expenditure leads to an increase in the growth rate. Not only did many researchers question his research method, also his results have been criticized (Pieroni, 2007: 2). Since 1973, many have researched the milex-growth relationship. Where researchers like Benoit started with ad-hoc models, later they could make use of more sophisticated growth models (Ram, 1995: 8). Some looked at developing nations, others at developed nations, some at countries in state of war, others at countries in peace. Throughout the history of defense spending different groups of dominant theories existed, supplemented with individual theories on channels through which milex might affect economic growth The research aims, methods and results have been various and a .single conclusion cannot be made. While some researchers have found a small significant positive relationship, others found an insignificant relationship. However, after almost forty years of research, most of the researchers agree on the fact that military spending has a small depressing8effect8on8economic8growth8(Aizenman8&8Glick,82003:82). Underconsumptionist-Theory and the Keynesian Approach Already before Benoit in 1973, theories about defense economics existed. A defense economics groups of theories is the Marxist´ Underconsumptionist-theory, which was popular as early as the 1960s. The theory is based on the assumption that capacity will outstrip demand, thereby creating a surplus which is increasingly difficult for the economy to absorb. This will have major consequences for capitalist industries, bringing them on the brink of stagnation and crisis. However, due to the capitalist nature of these systems, with their particular distribution of power, there will be pressure on governments not to make any anti-capitalist moves. Military expenditures enters the picture because it has a more ideological ground, namely fostering national security, while it effectively would increase demand, absorbing the available capacity surplus. It could therefore function as an effective anti-cyclical tool, with little political resistance (Rasler & Thompson, 1988: 5). Page 4 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Related to the Underconsumptionist-theory is the Keynesian-approach, which also calls for government intervention in order to use excess capacity output. Other than the Marxists, the Keynesian-approach emphasizes multiplier effects through which an increase in the exogenous milex will lead to an increase in capacity utilization. This is expected to improve the profitability of firms, giving them a bigger investment power, leading to growth. Closely connected to the Keynesian-approach is the Institutionalist-approach, which agrees with the Marxists that defense spending is a gateway to corporate profits. While the Marxists see them as a result of the capitalist system, the Institutionalists see it is a failing of the political system. The Military Industrial Complex, a combination of interest groups benefiting from military spending, puts pressure on governments to spend on defense even in the absence of threats, thereby creating immoral profits (Dunne, 2008: 4-5). However, where the Institutionalist-approach puts more emphasis on the demand for military spending, the Underconsumptionists and Keynesians aimed to explain a positive relationship between milex and economic growth. Smith’s Burden-on-Growth-Theory One of the major researchers of defense economics, Smith, strongly opposes the Underconsumptionist-theory. He accepts the fact that military spending could increase aggregate demand in the short run, but is opposing the idea that it could sustain higher levels of demand. ‘He disagreed with other Marxists in not interpreting war or rearmament as a deliberate instrument of economic policy´ (Cappelen et al., 1988: 12). The nature of defense spending is that it is subject to time lags due to its capital intensity and is therefore not useful in maintaining aggregate demand in the short run. Smith’s criticism started as early as the 1970s, followed by Dunne in 1990. They both see a drop in unemployment during periods of higher defense spending, however, they do not see a systematic response of the state on its defense spending in times of increasing unemployment-levels. Except for rejecting the ´Underconsumptionist´-theory, Smith and Dunne also reject the Keynesian approach which states that growth will take place through private investments. These are funded, according to the Keynesians, by improved revenues for defense companies. However, the net effect of short run stimulation on investment-levels in the long run is unlikely to be positive due to Smith’s negative crowding out-effect of military spending on investment levels. Smith and Dunne introduce the burden-on-growth thesis, which Page 5 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? emphasizes the resource trade-off between military expenditure and investment. `Aggregate production is strictly resource-constrained, so that military spending cannot but divert resources from other activities´ while taking the `potential output, rate of growth and rate of utilization´ as given. ´Military expenditure is determined exogenously in the light of strategic considerations and constraints, and investment then adjusts´, giving the government the key to this ´crowding out´-effect. This depressing effect on capital investment formation is likely to decrease the economic growth rate. Later, Dunne extends this trade-off to not only diverting resources from investment, but also consumption, the balance of payments and other government expenditures (Pivetti, 1992: 3,6-7). The crowding out-effect, originating from the Burden-on-Growth-theory, is throughout defense economics the most popular channel and is expected to show a negative relationship between milex and economic growth. Smith’s Leadership-Theory The investment-trade-off is the core argument of the guns-for-butter (or burden-on-growth) theorists. In 1977 Smith includes this theory into his more strategic theory of hegemonic leadership decline. This theory says that the goal of the hegemonic leader is to `organize the system at a world level much as individual nation-states do at the national level´. The costs for this are `proportionate to the magnitude of the relative military power needed to assume and maintain the leadership role´. Since this military power functions as a defense for other states as well, these are less inclined to spend on defense, allowing them to avoid the crowding out-effect. This defense-umbrella further increases defense costs for the hegemonic leader while allowing other capitalist nations to improve their relative economic position. ´The economic costs of the defense burden tend to undermine the very hegemonic military-political structure that it is intended to defend’. Especially neutral countries and countries whose defense is guaranteed by others, like in Iceland’s case, take maximum profit from this defense-umbrella. In 1981 Gilpin adds to Smith’s theory that not only the milex of a hegemonic leader crowd out investments, also consumption shares of the economy increase at the expense of investments. Rostow counters Smith´s theory by pointing at the tendency of investments levels for hegemonic leaders to level off while the other countries see higher investments levels to make up for their lagging position. (Rasler & Thompson, 1988: 7-9). Hegemonic decline is therefore a normal, unavoidable process. Also the PhoenixPage 6 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? effect, observed by Organski and Kugler, might play a role. They find that defeated countries need about twenty years to match their victor’s welfare. This catching up-tendency might be the result of a strong work ethic to rebuild the country (Capellen et al., 1984: 11). Taken all effects8into8consideration,8leadership8decline9appears9to9be9inevitable. Feder-Ram-Model While Benoit, Smith and others had done innovative research in the field of defense economics, models through which the milex-growth relationship could be shown were still missing to this point. This changed with the creation of the Feder-model in 1983. Special to defense economics is that it distinguishes itself from mainstream growth literature by the models it uses. While mainstream growth economists nowadays prefer the Augmented Solow-Growth model and Barro-model, defense economists for a long time made use of the Feder-Ram model. This model eyed to show the effects of exports on economic growth. This model was based on two sectors: export and non-export. Three years later, Ram and Biswas adapted this model to research the effects of military spending on economic growth (Ram, 1995: 8-9) The model consists of two sectors: military and civilian output, denoted as: where (M) and (C) are the total outputs for the military and civilian sector. (Lm) and (Km), and (Lc) and (Kc) respectively, are the inputs of labor and capital for the military sector and respectively the civilian sector. The civilian production function allows for externality effects originating from the size of the military sector through the subscript (M), which also is the total military output. Furthermore, the model allows for differences in factor-productivity of the two sectors where the founders assumed that inputs are more productive in the defense sector: where the difference across the sectors in the marginal products of both capital and labor is Page 7 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? equal to (δ). Therefore, for a given amount of resources, assigning inputs towards the defense sector will increase total output. The Feder-Ram-model was thereby the first model that showed mechanisms through which defense spending could affect output and allowed for estimations. The first channel being the externality effect of military size on output, and a second channel through taking advantage of a positive difference in input productivity of the military sector compared to the civilian sector. Through these two channels, the Feder-Rammodel explains how defense spending positively affects economic growth. However, there were major shortcomings and the Feder-Ram-model is replaced by mainstream growth models as the Augmented Solow Growth-model and Barro-model. One major shortcoming comes from empirical research that has shown that the factorproductivity difference works in the advance of the civilian sector, rather than the defense sector. Meaning that the defense sector is less efficient in its resource-use of labor and capital than the civilian sector is. Reasons mentioned are that the defense sector is “less subject to the rigors of market discipline” and that “strong competitive pressure to induce … efficiency in management and use of resources” is absent. (Dunne et al., 2004: 9, 12) Another shortcoming of the Feder-Ram-Model was that it did not account for non-linearity. However, this limitation was later solved by Crespo, Cueresma and Reitschuler in 2004. Non-linearity During the process of unraveling the complexities of defense economics, researchers have found agreement in the fact that the milex-economic growth relationship is non-linear. Neglecting to look for non-linearity is one of the biggest criticisms of recent researches on older ones. The awareness of non-linearism in defense economics really took off with Landau’s work in 1993. Non-linearity in the defense economics implies that “at low levels of milex, there will be a positive impact on growth, at higher levels of milex, milex will lead to lower growth” (Landau, 1993: 6). Due to the wide variety of researches, all focusing at different channels and countries, there exist different views on through which channels this non-linearity exist. One of the primary explanations given by researchers is Landau’s theory that at lower levels positive security and efficiency channels dominate, while at higher levels of growth, the negative investment-channel dominates. Landau’s investment-channel is simply the crowding out effect on investments by milex. He adds to this that high milex Page 8 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? create a big government, putting a burden on economic growth, the so-called “ Pentagon”effect. His security channel is more controversial by assuming that higher milex, for any level of threat, will increase economic growth by creating an environment that stimulates private investment. The controversy lies in the assumption that an increase in milex is positive in the wake of a threat. His efficiency channel, or “Patriotic”-effect, considers the political reality that in the wake of a foreign threat, an increase in milex requires a broadening or better use of the tax base. This can be done by on one hand, modifying policies aimed at improving economic growth which increases the tax base, while on the other to take a close view on other government expenses, mainly rent creating policies. The level of awareness of the threat by the public plays a key-roll in this process in order to obtain social support. Both ways through the efficiency-channel lead to improved economic performance. Which of the channels dominate, determines the net-effect on growth, creating a mountain-shaped relationship (Landau, 1996: 11). Landau’s work was appreciated and formed the basis of future research. First in 2001 Stroup and Heckelman adapted Landau’s theory but put a focus on marginal productivity of the defense and civilian sector. Stroup and Heckelman accept the criticism on the Feder-Rammodel that marginal productivity in the civilian sector is higher than in the defense sector. They conclude that this acceptance implies that increasing the share of defense in the total economy results in an increase in the opportunity costs of defense spending at an increasing rate. A second process they identified was a consequence of diminishing marginal productivity in the military sector. Stroup and Heckelman noted that this implies that increasing defense spending as a share of the economy will create benefits at a decreasingly rate (Stroup & Heckelman, 2001: 6). These two processes lead to the following function: Page 9 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? (Stroup & Heckelman, 2001: 8) where the economy benefits most of defense spending at M1 and where it has no influence at M2. Cueresma and Reitschuler (Pieroni, 2007: 2) agree on this theory of marginal productivity as an explanation of non-linearity in defense economics, but they see it as a result of external threat levels. They add that this might even lead to the “existence of multiple8growth8regimes”. Threats Except for his focus on the non-linearity aspect of the milex-growth relationship in 1993, Landau also focused on the role of threats on defense economics. However, not until 2003 there was a clear theory on the role that threat plays in the milex-economic growth relationship. Aizenman and Glick (2003: 2-16) found non-linearity also in the role of external threats. They state that milex in the absence of threats reduces growth, a lack of milex in the wake of an external threat also reduces growth, but that milex in the presence of sufficient external threats improves economic growth. This means that below a certain threat level, an increase in milex has a negative effect on growth, while above this threat level, military spending stimulates economic growth. The model thus assumes that milex as a response to external threats increases growth, while milex due to rent-seeking corruption or inefficiency reduces growth. The optimum level of milex in the absence of threats is none at all, however in the reality of external threats, a positive milex is optimal. The presence of corruption works as a tax on defense spending, thereby raising the optimal amount of milex for any Page 10 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? threat level. Like Stroup and Heckelman, they find the source for non-linearity in the inconsistency of the marginal productivity of milex. One of the complexities of defense economics, which also puts Aizenman and Glick’s theory into uncertainty, is the effect of milex on external threat levels. An increase in milex could invoke an arms-war, leading to more insecurity, instead of its purpose. This ambiguity also puts in question the positive relationship between milex and the creation of an environment that attracts investments through spending on defense. Peace Dividend One of the practical aspects of defense economics is what would happen to economic growth when a country decides to reduce its defense spending. This discussion appeared after the Cold War in defense economics to give economic estimates for the ongoing process of disarmament. The drop in milex as a result of the easing of international tensions is called the Peace Dividend and gained popularity halfway the 1990s (Davoodi et al., 2001: 2). However, except for milex itself, a reduction in defense spending also implies other gains on the economy. Economic growth gains from the Peace Dividend through a reversal of the flows through most of the channels that are mentioned in this chapter. Also social programs are likely to benefit. Peace Dividend-economists mainly focused on the choice between spending the saved money to stimulate investments or to transfer it to deficit reduction. They concluded that stimulating investment is the best choice since it increases economic growth the most (Ward & David, 1992: 7). The difficulty of determining the size of the Peace Dividend is similar to the complexities of defense economics at large. The milex-growth relationship is subject to long lags in time and is also subject to different impacts in the long run than in the short run, making it difficult to predict the economic consequences of cutting defense spending for public policy makers. Exercising the Peace Dividend, thus reducing defense spending in the wake of peace, is believed to have a possible negative impact on economic growth in the short run, but positively affecting economic growth in the long run. While Smith and others dismissed the military budget as a suitable tool to alter aggregate demand, the Peace Dividend is appreciated for the role it could play in a structural long-run macroeconomic package to increase economic growth through an increase in capacity output. It should be emphasized Page 11 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? that the Peace Dividend-gains are only obtained to its full extent in the presence of peace, and spending reductions are therefore likely to be carried out in mutual agreement or understanding. Not only does the smaller defense expenditure distort the economy less, the affiliated presence of peace also is an improvement of security leading for example to more civilian R&D, a boost for free trade and more investments (Knight et al., 1996: 49-50). The emphasis of this approach lies at the political aspect. Is it a multilateral decision that does not decrease security nor does it create threats, or is the choice unilaterally made, stimulating economic growth through some channels, but losing some benefits due to increased insecurity or foregone gains as free trade? The benefits of a mutual reduction vastly outpace the gains of a unilateral decision due to the presence of multiplier effects for all parties involved. Related to this observation is the approach that does not see defense spending as a public good but as a “public bad”, referring to practice that increasing defense spending is likely to provoke a similar policy reaction from neighboring countries, not increasing security at all (Davoodi et al., 2001: 23). Augmented Solow-Growth Model One of the two Neoclassical mainstream growth models that are recommended by Dunne, Smith and Willenbockel (2001: 3) is the “ Augmented Solow Growth Model”. The Augmented Model originates from Mankiw et al. (1992), was first used for defense economics by Knight et al. (1996) and helps to explain and calculate the effects of milex on economic growth. The model is an appreciated alternative for the Feder-Ram-model and has the following production function: where (Yt) is aggregate real income, (Kt) is capital (physical and human), (Lt) is labor and (α) is the share of capital in output. (At) is technological change which is assumed to grow and is, next to population growth and investments/savings, the source of economic growth in this model. This model further assumes that the savings rate is exogenous, a constant labor force growth rate (n), and a given rate of depreciation (δ). Furthermore, output (Yt) is devoted to Page 12 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? (public and private) consumption (Ct), investment in physical and human capital (It) and military expenditure (Mt): or rewritten as shares of total output: This equation shows the negative relationship between investments and milex and implies that this relationship is one to one, as first stated in the work of Smith in 1980. The Augmented Solow-model does not allow this relationship (or trade-off) to influence the steady-state growth rate, in accordance with the original Solow-model. But similarly, it does allow for changes in the growth rate during the transition to steady-state. The one by one relationship between milex and investments means that an one percent-point decrease in milex consequently leads to an one percent-point increase in investments. Increasing investments, which are equal to savings, means an upward shift in the (SY)-line to (S1Y)-line. In this case, the original position is a steady-state growth rate (A). The movement of the (SY)line means a rise in the capital-labor-ratio from (K0) to (K1) and also an increase in the output-labor ratio from (Y0) to (Y1). During this transition from steady-state at point (A) to point (B) higher economic growth occurs. However, the effect of this boost is finished when arriving at the new steady-state, meaning a return to the former steady-state growth rate but at a higher K/L-ratio and Y/L-ratio. In reality, the original position where we start from is on the left of (A), at (C) for example. Through a positive net investment-level the economy was still moving to the steady-state growth rate at (A), but will now movie further to (B). The political choice for freeing money for investment at the expense of milex means that the future steady-state capital intensity and output-labor ratio of (A) are replaced by (B). In the Augmented Solow-model this gives a higher growth rate during the transition to the steadystate growth rate (Burda & Wyplosz, 2009: 55-77). Page 13 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? (Wikimedia, 2011) The criticizers of the Augmented Solow Growth Model state that the model is to tight and simple. Milex might influence savings, technological progress, the utilization labor and capital and human capital. Another point of criticism is the excluding of other variables. For this reason the Barro-model is gaining popularity. The Solow model and the Feder-Rammodel differ on a few points. While the Feder-Ram-model consists out of two sectors, the Solow-model has only one. But more importantly, the Feder-Ram-model is a supply-side model, while the Solow-model is in defense economics regarded as a demand-side because of its focus on investment displacement by milex. But despite being a demand-model, the Solow-model hardly looks like other (Keynesian) demand-models. The results in defense economics have, for a large extent, been depending on the choice between supply- and demand-models, with supply-models, like the Feder-Ram-model giving “either a small positive defense impact on growth or no impact at all”. On the other hand, demand-models, like the Solow-model, tend to find a negative relationship between milex and economic growth (Dunne, 2001: 5). Where supply-models look at the defense sector as a provider of public infrastructure, a contributor to human capital and a positive influence to private production through R&D experience and imitation of arms, (Keynesian) demand-models see in the defense sector a less-controversial political tool to absorb unemployment and raising aggregate demand, while creating a safe environment for investments (Shieh et al., 2002: 2). Page 14 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Welfare Maximizing However, just looking at the impact on economic growth to determine the optimum level of milex is too narrow, and ignores special characteristics of defense economics. As Futugama et al. (1993) and Greiner and Hanusch (1998) show: “maximizing economic growth is not equivalent to maximizing social welfare” when public services is a variable which determines welfare (Shieh et al., 2002: 2). Although the dynamics around the demand for defense spending will not be addressed in this paper, it is important to note this criticism on the Neoclassical approach. The explanation for this can be found in Deger and Sen’s (1995) work that “the demand for milex ultimately comes from perceived security – both external and internal” and therefore the “the causes of defense spending should be analyzed in terms of social welfare”. However, the first researchers introducing an extensive work on welfare in defense economics were Hamid Davoodi et al. (2002: 3).They stated that when security is regarded as a public good, defense should be included in the welfare function: where (W) is welfare, (C) is consumption, (M) is military spending, (O) is non-military government spending and (Z) is state variables.( )Z affects the leadership’s choice through attaching weights to (M) and (O). The welfare function shows the choice that leaders confront between maximizing public welfare through either military spending or nonmilitary government spending and implies that defense spending is a positive determinant of social welfare. Some empirical evidence for this statement could be found in the observation that since the end of the Cold War, disarmament or milex reductions barely have taken place. This suggests that economic reasons behind demand for milex, which should enforce a reduction in milex, are decimated in favor of social welfare. Accordingly, the optimal amount of defense spending, that maximizes economic growth, is smaller than the amount devoted to milex in order to maximize social welfare (Shieh et al., 2002: 10). The researchers around Hamid Davoodi acknowledge the negative impact of milex on economic growth, but suggest that countries take on this economic burden to improve public welfare. Except for this issue, it is hard to measure the economic effects of milex in the first place. Not only the benefits are hard to describe in dollars, the same counts for the expenses or the costs. An example given by Landau is the difference between the salaries of conscript and their actual Page 15 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? opportunity costs. Since salaries are lower than the opportunity costs of conscript, milex are similarly likely to be lower than the opportunity cost that the defense sector puts on the society and economy (Landau, 1996: 6) 2.2 Major Channels Although the most important channels have briefly been mentioned and have been connected to the theories they belong to, still two channels require special attention. Both the investment-savings-channel and R&D-channel have been playing key-rolls in defense economics and have received attention from nearly every researcher. What makes them interesting is the difficulties for researchers to decide on which flows dominate through these8two8channels. Investments8&8Savings Smith was the first researcher to focus on the negative relationship between military spending and investments through his so-called crowding-out effect. However, since Smith later researchers have found other ways through which the milex-investment relationship works. The main channel is the crowding out-effect it has on public and private investments. Government expenditures are basically financed through two ways: current taxes or borrowing (which could be seen as future taxes). Both reduce the after-tax return on investments, discouraging this economic activity (Knight et al., 1996: 16). At the same time the availability of savings for investments is absorbed by the government. Though milex does not only have a negative influence: if defense spending increases security it also shapes an investment-friendly business environment for domestic and foreign investors. A second positive effect is that defense spending has on investment is called the spin-off effect and finds its origin in the Keynesian theory. Defense expenditure is (partly) spent on weapons, which is positive for the private production of the defense sector, creating cash-flow available for further private investments by this sector (Shieh et al., 2002: 2). The level of milex also has a big influence on savings and thus on economic growth, especially in undeveloped countries, but also in some developed countries as the United States. If milex are funded by taxation, then there will be a direct negative effect on savings due to a reduced after-tax return. However, there is also a second crowding-out effect, next Page 16 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? to the crowding-out of investments, namely on competing government expenses as education and health. A reduced contribution by the government means a bigger financing risk lies at the public which induces them to save more and consume less (Dunne, 2008: 6). So defense has a two-way effect on savings, a positive and a negative. To see the influence of defense on savings, a good example was the increase in savings after the Cold War was ended, taking away the fear of a nuclear war and inducing people to plan for the future (Mintz & Stevenson, 1995: 18). R&D8&8Human8Capital The existence and size of a country’s defense sector, along with actual military spending, has both positive and negative effects on the knowledge and research of an economy. The effect that the military has on human capital and labor markets differs for countries according to their economic phase. In less developed countries, the military might lower the pain of unemployment, while providing training and education to a largely uneducated population. However, for rich countries, especially those with low unemployment, the military and especially conscription will impose more negative effects on economic growth (Shieh et al., 2002: 2). Well-educated citizens are displaced from the productive civilian sector, while conscription keeps students out of universities in their most productive years (Dunne, 2008: 5) In the field of research and development, two channels exist through which economic growth is affected. On one side, weapon production, especially in countries which possess capital-intensive industries, might benefit from technological spillovers from the military sector to the productive civilian sector. On the other side, fears exist that the military replaces civilian R&D, thereby changing productive R&D into unproductive R&D. The hope for technological spillovers, which is expected to improve the economy, is one reason, along with reducing the pressure on the balance of payments, to agree with weapon exporters on “arms trade offset-deals”, or producing under licenses. Especially small countries, not possessing a strong defense sector make use of these trades. However, Dunne & Brauer (2004) have shown that both deals neither have a positive impact on economic development, nor does it create any sustainable employment and the hoped technological spillovers8barely8take8place8(Dunne,82008:811). Page 17 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? 2.38Hypotheses In this paper I will research the relationship between milex and economic growth and the relationship between countries’ strategic characteristics and economic growth: - What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? - What does having a strong domestic defence industry mean to real economic growth compared to having a small domestic defence industry? - What is the effect of a foreign policy based on neutrality on real economic growth? - Do European leaders have stronger real economic growth than non-leaders? Based on the literature and earlier researches, I expect to see a negative relationship for milex and real economic growth based on the Augmented Solow-model and Smith’s theory of investment crowding-out. Landau and Aizenman and Glick’s theory of non-linearity is also expected to hold in reality. However, due to the strong convergence of milex-levels and economic growth in the EU, there might not be enough observations obtain a clear quadratic equation. The literature so far has not focused on the effects of the size of the defence industry on real economic growth. However, with the help of theories from defence economics predictions could be made. The Underconsumptionist-theory predicts a positive effect of a strong domestic defence industry on real growth. The defence sector is a high value-added industry and an a source for foreign capital inflow. It is therefore an ideal sector to absorb the capacity surplus in the economy. Using the Feder-Ram-model gives a similar conclusion. On the other side, Smith and the Augmented Solow-model both give no clear expectation. Having a strong defence industry is in itself not a source of investment crowding-out. However, countries that possess a strong industry might be lured into overspending on milex thereby8depressing8growth. Also about the influence of neutrality on real economic growth not much is known. The only theorists that might provide some guidance are Aizenman and Glick (2003). Countries running a neutral foreign policy could be seen as having a smaller external threat than nonPage 18 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? neutral countries, or no threats at all, since they do not endanger others’ security. This assumption divides the two sub-groups of countries on their optimal defence spending level. For neutral countries, the optimal level will be lower than for non-neutral countries, since at low external threat levels, negative channels dominate positive channels in the milex-growth relationship. This would imply that for any level of milex being neutrality means a discount on real economic growth. However, since these governments are aware of lower threatlevels, they have the opportunity to cut their military spending. According to Smith and the Augmented Solow-model, cutting milex will improve real economic growth. The answer of the question on leadership should be predicted with the help of Smith. His leadership-theory says that the fall in leadership is almost inevitable, especially due to security costs. It is therefore expected that being a leader puts a burden on real economic growth. Page 19 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Chapter83:_Research 3.1_Countries The relationship between military spending and economic growth has been researched many times in many different ways, also solely for the EU-15 and particularly for the Mediterranean countries. This paper differs from these researches on the sample that is taken and on the emphasis. To obtain the best results, only countries which face similar external threats will be used for this research. The sample therefore consists out of the EU15, minus Greece, but plus Malta, Norway and Switzerland. The reason that Greece is excluded from this sample is due to their Cyprus dispute with Turkey which has led to overspending on milex compared to “peaceful” Europe. Malta, Norway and Switzerland have been added due to their similarities with the EU-15 on milex and their threat-levels. New for defense economics is that this paper investigates what effect the presence of a strong domestic defense industry has on economic growth. Countries of the EU-15 have been classified in either the big arms industry or the small arms industry based on how they were categorized by Dunne and Nikolaidou (2011) as having a developed defense industry. Malta is due to its size classified as having a small arms industry. Switzerland and Norway however, are both grouped as having developed arms industries. Norway had the biggest arms exports per capita in 2006 (Afterposten, 2006), while ranking 11th in the world in real terms. Switzerland ranked 12th in arms exports in 2009 (SIPRI, 2011). The small states of Europe have been ignored because of their minimal size or for the reason that their territory is8protected8by8others,8as8the8United8States8does8for8Iceland. Another innovation is to research the effect of neutrality on economic growth. Out of the sample of 17 countries, only 6 are classified as neutral: Austria, Finland, Ireland, Malta, Sweden and Switzerland, where some have a longer tradition of neutrality than others. All of these 6 countries are member of the “Partnership for Peace”-program of the NATO, which was founded in 1994 to create trust between NATO-member states and other countries in Europe and former Soviet Union-states. Malta left the program in 1995 but reactivated its membership in 2008. While this program was not seen as an breach of neutrality, membership of the EU raised some questions on neutrality due to the Common Foreign and Security Policy. Despite the CFSP, these countries are still accepted as neutral (NATO, 2011). Page 20 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Although research was done in the field of Smith’s leadership theory, it was never focused on Europe and the existing research is outdated. Kasler and Thompson (1988) researched Germany (1873-1913 and 1951-1978), France (1821-1913 and 1951-1978) and Great Britain(1831-1913 and 1946-1978), next to the United States and Japan. Where Kasler and Thompson included Germany as a major power, I will not. France and the United Kingdom have a special military leadership role in Europe because of their nuclear deterrence, their aircraft carriers, their overseas bases and their high defense spending compared to GDP. 3.2_Research I will conduct the research by regressing various variables with real GDP-growth. As control variables, which are expected to explain economic growth, I will take “(Real) Initial GDP” in 1993, “(Real) Interest Rate”, “Average Years of Schooling”, “Population Growth”, “Investments as a share of GDP” and “Inflation rate”. The independent variable that is the key of my research is “Milex”, which stands for military spending. The problem of two-way causality arises when defense spending and education are included in the regression. The levels of milex and education influence economic growth, but the funding of them also depend on economic growth itself. To solve this I will take previous values for milex and education. While I normally take the averages of five years, with 1995, 2000 and 2005 as median-year, for these two variables I will scrap the years around 2005 but include the years around 1990. This will block the reverse causality sufficiently. It was impossible, especially due to a lack of military data, to obtain an instrumental variable that is unrelated to economic growth but which is a good estimator for milex. The other variables will make use of data running from 1993 to 2007 with every year taking in consideration and resulting in three averaged observations per country. By selecting three time-periods instead of one, the sample8increases8from8178possible8observations8to851. When regressing only milex with real economic growth, the following scatter plot is obtained. The plot shows a vague negative trend in economic growth while increasing the level of milex to GDP. The observations reflecting exceptionally high economic growth are Ireland, Luxembourg and Malta. The first two saw strong economic development through the financial sector while the latter came from a low point of economic development Page 21 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? On the right-flank of milex are France and the United Kingdom positioned, right after the collapse of the Soviet-Union, when they still had to start the process of monetizing the Peace Dividend. The precise results can be found in table 1, column 1. Milex is significant (1,5%) at the 5%level (α=0,5) and has a beta of -0,678. This gives the regression equation: Y = 4,149 – 0,678X, which complies with the main opinion of defense economists that milex has a depressing effect on economic growth with a 0,678 percentage point decrease in the real economic growth rate for every percentage point increase in milex. However due to the early work of Landau and later by Stroup and Heckelman, non-linearity gained popularity and should be checked for. To do that I add the square of milex to the regression. Table 1, column 2 shows the results for this regression. From this data the regression equation for the effect of milex on real economic growth can be obtained: Y = 6,625-3,497X+0,688X² for which milex (0,3%) is significant at the 1%-level (α=0,01) and milex² (1,3%) is significant at the 5%-level (α=0,5). Although the usefulness of the model increases from 11,5% to 22,2% by adding milex², the results do not comply with the expectations. Instead of a mountain-shaped regression line, a U-shaped regression line is formed. As Landau (1993: 6) puts it: ‘Initially increases in milex are associated with faster growth and beyond a certain level they are associated with slower Page 22 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? growth’. Instead we see the opposite: a decrease in growth rates at low levels of milex while an increase in growth rates at high levels of milex. The minimum of the regression equation lies at X = 2,54 where Y = 2,18 (see figure 1). This means that, according to the model, a milex-level of 2,54% of GDP is the most harmful to the economy and both increasing milex or decreasing it will improve economic performance. Based on the work of Landau (1993 and 1996) and Stroup and Heckelman (2001) it was expected to see a maximum somewhere close on the left of the model’s minimum of 2,54% milex. However, the extent to which their work is relevant to the European defense reality since the fall of the USSR is doubtable. Fig. 1: Milex - Real Economic Growth Real Economic Growth 10 8 6 4 Actual 2 Expected 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Milex Page 23 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? When I add the control variables, results are less fortunate for the hypothesis. Leaving aside the milex², but adding all control variables makes milex highly insignificant (94,8%). The variables “Real Initial GDP”, “Real Interest Rate”, “Average Years of Schooling” and “Population Growth” are significant. Real initial GDP (0,3%) is significant at the 1%-level (α=0,01) while showing a negative beta.. This complies with the “convergence-theory” which implies that countries with lower initial GDP will grow faster than countries which are further in their economic development. Real interest rate (8%) is significant at the 10%-level (α=0,1) and also has a negative beta. This was expected since real interest rates have a depressing effect on economic growth. Education is, together with real initial GDP, the most significant variable (0,7%) at the 1%-level (α=0,01) and has a positive beta. This is in line with Barro (1991) who proved that education is a contributor to economic growth. And last, population growth is significant (1,3%) at the 5%-level (α=0,05) and has a positive beta. This Page 24 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? is in accordance with the Solow-model which mentions population growth as one of the determinants of economic growth. Compared to only including milex in the regression, the usefulness of the model has risen sharply from 11,5% to 48,1%. With milex² taken into account, the usefulness increases from 22,2% to 48,1%. In that case the insignificancy of milex drops slightly from 94,8% to 87,4%, which is close to the insignificancy of milex2 88,3%. While the usefulness of the model has risen sharply after extending it, it makes the relationship between military expenditures and economic growth very insignificant. A way to obtain a significant level for milex is by removing population growth and education from the regression. In that case, milex will be significant (6,5%) again at the 10%-level (α=0,1). However, usefulness has dropped again to levels seen before (25,6%). Adding milex² gives both a very significant milex (1,4%) and milex² (3,9%). Also the real interest rate (8,4%) is significant at the 10%-level and usefulness has increased to 32,5%, but real initial GDP has turned insignificant. The results implicate that population growth and education take over military expenditures (and its square) as the determinants of economic growth in this model. Defense8Industry To research the effect of the size of the defense industry on economic growth I take the extended model excluding milex and milex2 since they are both insignificant. Table 3, column 1 shows the results when including a dummy for the size of the industry (with 1=big and 0=small). The dummy has a beta of -0,515, but is insignificant (15,3%). Therefore, no conclusions can be made about its relationship to real economic growth. Neutrality Changing the industry-dummy for the neutrality-dummy (with 1=neutral and 0=non-neutral), gives a similar result. The dummy for neutrality shows a positive beta of 0,607, but is insignificant (13,7%). Also about the effect of neutrality on real economic growth, no conclusions8can8be8made. Leadership The leadership-dummy (with 1=leader and 0=non-leader) is by far the most insignificant dummy (95,7%) and also its beta shows no clear direction (-0,029). Page 25 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Page 26 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Chapter84:8Conclusion The results of the regressions have not answered the research questions satisfactory. The main research question ‘What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth?’ was initially answered with the expected (significant) negative relationship. The non-linearity-theory however failed to hold. Although there was nonlinearity, it was a positive instead of a negative relationship. When extending the model with six other variables, both milex and milex2 turn insignificant. However, with all regressions taken into account, I think it is safe to say that milex has a depressing effect on real economic growth, albeit weak, in accordance with most recent findings of other researchers. To prove non-linearity, a more diverse set of observations is required, preferably outside Europe8to8include8observations8with8higher8levels8of8milex. On the second question ‘What does having a strong domestic defence industry mean to real economic growth compared to having a small domestic defence industry?’ , my research gives no clear answer since the dummy is insignificant. A way to solve this for future researchers might be to dig deeper into the defense industry. As I found out, defense economics is a playing field with many different players, interests, channels, opportunity costs and externalities. The emphasis should lie in analyzing the dynamics between governments and their domestic Military Industrial Complex. How does the MIC itself influence defense policies, how do defense policies change for economic reasons due to the existence of a big domestic defense industry, how much defense money flows abroad or comes in, and perhaps anno 2011 most importantly: how is your government’s milex financed and at what expense? Based on such a comprehensive analysis a conclusion can be made about the actual total benefits and costs of housing a big defense industry. The answer on ‘What is the effect of a foreign policy based on neutrality on real economic growth?’ is also disappointing since the neutrality-dummy was insignificant as well. Therefore no statistical conclusion can be made about the economic consequences of changing your foreign policy towards neutrality. However, since milex has a depressing effect on economic growth and since neutral countries have substantial lower defense spending without being attacked in recent history, you could conclude that neutrality is not a bad idea. At the same time, these countries managed to sustain a big domestic defense industry, like Austria, Sweden and Switzerland. Neutrality at the core of your foreign policy is in theory the only Page 27 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? way to maximize the ‘Peace Dividend’. It gives you an advantage over your economic competitors. This corresponds to Smith’s leadership-theory which sees the security-umbrella of the hegemonic-leader as the reason for the leader’s decline and the rise of its allies, which are at the same time its economic competitors. It is actually a reversion of the “Peace Dividend”-theory by implying that the position of hegemonic-leader is maximizing rejecting the “Peace Dividend”. Although my statistical research did not prove a relationship between neutrality and economic growth, it is undeniable that Europe’s neutral countries are the world’s most competitive. Today’s relevancy of Smith’s leadership-theory is questioned by the results for ‘Do European leaders grow stronger than non-leaders?’ My research gives insignificant results which cannot answer this question. The number of observations is limited plus the convergence of milex-levels after the USSR-fall might have made Smith’s leadership-theory irrelevant to the European situation anyway. Though, when looking at the past decade the United States seem to be the ultimate proof of the correctness of the leadership-theory. So we should be careful not to dismiss Smith’s theory because of the weak results of my research. A better set of observations (followed by better research results) might also allow for researching the effect of the dummies I took on the milexgrowth relationship itself through interaction-terms instead of directly on economic growth. This might allow for conclusions on which European countries can use milex-levels for balancing the overall budget through which part of the business cycles. Also, providing better estimates of non-economic effects of milex could result in a overall conclusion on the role of milex in the economy, but perhaps more importantly, its effect on social welfare. European governments should take notice from this and earlier research that cutting milex in the current budgetary turmoil might be a relieve to both the budget and the economy, leaving strategic reasons for milex aside. To obtain the entire “Peace Dividend”, European countries should consider building their foreign-policy around neutrality. The research was too limited to conclude on the consequences of a big domestic defence industry. Perhaps the best conclusion is that having one is a blessing, but it starts acting as a curse when policy decisions are made based on having and maintaining this industry instead of sound security interests, since it tends to drag scarce domestic resources from the national budget to an unproductive8sector. Page 28 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Literature8List Aizenman, J. and Glick, R. (2003), ‘Military Expenditure, Threats and Growth’, NBER Working Paper Series, April 2003 ANP, 2011. Defensie: 6.000 Mensen en Alle Tanks Weg. Volkskrant, [online], 8 April 2011. Available at: <http://www.volkskrant.nl/vk/nl/2824/Politiek/article/detail/1872359/2011/04/08/Defensi e-6-000-mensen-en-alle-tanks-wegbezuinigd.dhtml> [Accessed 25 April 2011]. Barro, R.J. (1991),’ Economic Growth in a cross section of countries’, Quaterly Journal Of Economics, vol. 106 (2), pp. 407-443 Burda, M. Wyplosz, C., 2009. Macroeconomics: A European Text. 5th ed. Oxford University Press. Cappelen, A. Gleditsch, N.P. Bjerkholt, O. (1984), ‘Military Spending and Eonomic Growth in the OECD Countries’, Journal of Peace Research, vol. 21 (4), pp. 361-373 CIA The World Factbook (2011). Available at: <https://www.cia.gov/index.html> [Accessed 25 April 2011] Davoodi, H. et al. (2001), ‘Military Spending, the Peace Dividend and Fiscal Adjustment’, IMF Staff Papers, vol. 48 (2), pp. 2-23 Dunne, J.P. and Smith, R.P. (2001), ‘Military Expenditure Growth and Investment’. Available through: Carecon [Accessed 14 March 2011]. Dunne, P.D. Smith, R. Willenbockel, D. (2004), ‘Models of Military Expenditure and Growth: A Critical Review’. Available through: Carecon [Accessed 14 March 2011] Dunne, J.P. (2008), ‘Does High Spending On Arms Reduce Economic Growth? A Review of Research’, Oxfam, July 2008 Dunne, J.P. and Nikolaidou, E. (2011), ‘Defense Spending and Economic Growth in the EU15’. Available through: Carecon [Accessed 13 March 2011]. Knight, M. Loayza, N. and Villanueva, D. (1996), ‘The Peace Dividend: Military Spending Cuts and Economic Growth’, Policy Research Department of the World Bank No. 1577. Available through: Ideas [Accessed 13 March 2011]. Landau, D. (1993), ‘The Economic Impact of Military Expenditures’, Policy Research Department of the World Bank No. 1138. Available through: Ideas [Accessed 12 March 2011]. Landau, D. (1996), ‘Is One of the ‘Peace Dividends’ Negative? Military Expenditure and Page 29 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Economic Growth in the Wealthy OECD Countries’, The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, vol. 36 (2), pp. 183-195 Mintz, A. and Stevenson, R.T. (1995), ‘Defense Expenditures, Economic Growth, and the “Peace Dividend”: A Longitudinal Analysis of 103 Countries’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, vol. 39 (2), pp. 283-305 NATO (2011). Available at: <http://www.nato.int/pfp/sig-cntr.htm> [Accessed 25 April 2011] Pieroni, L. (2007), ‘Military Expenditure and Economic Growth’, Defense and Peace Economics, 2007, vol. 20, no. 4, pp. 327. Available through: Ideas [Accessed 12 March 2011]. Pivetti, M. (1992), ‘Military Spending as a Burden on Growth: an Underconsumptionist Critique’, Journal of Economics, vol. 16, pp. 373-384 Ram, R. (1995) ‘Defense Expenditure and Economic Growth’, Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 1, pp. 251-274. Available through: ScienceDirect [Accessed 12 March 2011]. Rasler, K. and Thompson W.R. (1988), ‘Defense Burdens Capital Formation and Economic Growth: the Systematic Leader Case’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, vol. 32 (61), pp. 2-9 Shieh, J.Y. Lai, C.C. and Chang W.Y. (2002), ‘The Impact of Military Burden on Long-Run Growth and Welfare’, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 68 (2), pp. 443-454 Sipri (2010), ‘Arms Export Database’. Available at: <http://armstrade.sipri.org/armstrade/page/toplist.php> [Accessed 25 April 2011] Stroup, M.D. and Heckelman, J.C. (2001), ‘Size of the Military Sector and Economic Growth: A Panel Data Analysis of Africa and Latin America’, Journal of Applied Economics, vol. 4 (2), pp. 329-360 Tisdall, J., 2006. Norway big in arms export. Aftenposten, [online], 18 January 2006. Available at: <http://www.aftenposten.no/english/local/article1200921.ece> [Accessed 25 April 2011]. Ward, M.D. and David, R.D. (1992), ‘Sizing Up the Peace Dividend: Economic Growth and Military Spending in the United States, 1948-1996’, American Political Science Review, vol. 86 (3), pp. 748-755 Wikimedia (2011). Available at: <http://upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/en/1/11/Solow_growth_model1.png> [Accessed 30 April 2011]. Page 30 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Appendix A: Variables Av_Yrs_Schooling: Average years of schooling calculated with the data of 1990, 1995 and 2000. Data source: World Bank. http://siteresources.worldbank.org/EXTEDSTATS/Resources/3232763-1171296308277/34459081171320551553/3449375-1171320604454/total_age15.xls D_Industry: Dummy for having a big (1) or a small (0) defense industry, based on “Defense Spending and Economic Growth in the EU15” by J.P. Dunne and E. Nikolaidou and with data on arms exports on SIPRI. D_Leadership: Dummy for military leadership position (1) or non-leader position (0). D_Neutrality: Dummy for being non-neutral (1) or neutral (0), based on CIA World Factbook. Eco_Growth: Real annual economic growth calculated by taking an average of 5 years-periods with 1995, 1995 and 2005 as median-year and data running from 1993 to 2007. Data source: Eurostat. http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/tgm/table.do?tab=table&init=1&language=en&pcode=tsieb02 0&plugin=1 Inflation_Rate: Inflation rate, as the annual percentage change in consumer prices, calculated by taking 5 year-periods with 1995, 2000 and 2005 as median-year and data running from 1993 to 2007. Data source: World Bank. http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/FP.CPI.TOTL.ZG Initial_GDP: Real Initial GDP per capita in 1993, 1998 and 2003 (current US$). Data source: World Bank. http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.PCAP.CD?page=3 Interest_Rate: Real interest rate calculated by taking the average of 5 years-periods with 1995, 2000 and 2005 as median-year and data running from 1993 to 2007. Data source: Nationmaster. http://www.nationmaster.com/graph/eco_rea_int_rat-economy-real-interest-rate Invest_GDP: Investments as a share of GDP calculated by taking the average of 5 years-periods with 1995, 2000 and 2005 as median-year and data running from 1993 to 2007. Data source: World Bank. http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NE.GDI.TOTL.ZS Milex: Military expenditures as a share of GDP calculated by taking the average of 5 yearsperiods with 1990, 1995 and 2000 as median-year and data running from 1988 to 2002. Data source: SIPRI (Stockholm Institute for Peace Research Institute). http://milexdata.sipri.org/ Popul_Growth: Population growth as a percentage increase of the population calculated by taking the average of 5 years-periods with 1995, 2000 and 2005 as median-year and data running from 1993 to 2007. Data source: World Bank. http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SP.POP.GROW Page 31 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Appendix B: Countries Total: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany (FRG+GDR), Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Malta, Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland and United Kingdom. Neutral: Austria, Finland, Ireland, Malta, Sweden, Switzerland. Non-Neutral: Belgium, Denmark, France, Germany, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain and United Kingdom. Big Defense: Austria, France, Germany, Italy, Netherlands, Norway, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland and United Kingdom. Small Defense: Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Ireland, Luxembourg, Malta and Portugal. Leaders: France and United Kingdom Page 32 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Appendix C: Regressions Regression table 1, column 1: Model Summary Model R Std. Error of the Square Estimate R Square a 1 Adjusted R ,338 ,115 ,096 1,41774 a. Predictors: (Constant), Milex b ANOVA Model 1 Sum of Squares df Mean Square Regression 12,736 1 12,736 Residual 98,489 49 2,010 111,225 50 Total F Sig. 6,336 a ,015 a. Predictors: (Constant), Milex b. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Coefficients a Standardized Unstandardized Coefficients Model 1 B Std. Error (Constant) 4,149 ,528 Milex -,678 ,269 Coefficients Beta t -,338 Sig. 7,852 ,000 -2,517 ,015 a. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Page 33 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Regression table 1, column 2: Model Summary Model R R Square a 1 ,471 Adjusted R Std. Error of the Square Estimate ,222 ,190 1,34248 a. Predictors: (Constant), Milex_Squared, Milex b ANOVA Model 1 Sum of Squares df Mean Square F Regression 24,716 2 12,358 Residual 86,509 48 1,802 111,225 50 Total Sig. a 6,857 ,002 a. Predictors: (Constant), Milex_Squared, Milex b. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Coefficients a Standardized Unstandardized Coefficients Model 1 B (Constant) Milex Milex_Squared Std. Error 6,625 1,083 -3,497 1,123 ,688 ,267 Coefficients Beta t Sig. 6,117 ,000 -1,745 -3,115 ,003 1,445 2,578 ,013 a. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Page 34 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Regression table 2, column 1: Model Summary Model R R Square a 1 ,693 Adjusted R Std. Error of the Square Estimate ,481 ,390 1,12991 a. Predictors: (Constant), Popul_Growth, Av_Yrs_School, Invest_GDP, Milex, Interest_Rate, Inflation_Rate, Initial_GDP b ANOVA Model 1 Sum of Squares df Mean Square Regression 47,246 7 6,749 Residual 51,068 40 1,277 Total 98,314 47 F Sig. a 5,287 ,000 a. Predictors: (Constant), Popul_Growth, Av_Yrs_School, Invest_GDP, Milex, Interest_Rate, Inflation_Rate, Initial_GDP b. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Coefficients a Standardized Unstandardized Coefficients Model 1 B (Constant) Std. Error ,757 2,049 -,018 ,273 -8,181E-5 Coefficients Beta t Sig. ,370 ,714 -,009 -,066 ,948 ,000 -,520 -3,201 ,003 -,159 ,089 -,260 -1,798 ,080 Invest_GDP ,002 ,034 ,007 ,051 ,960 Inflation_Rate ,161 ,279 ,093 ,577 ,567 Av_Yrs_School ,402 ,141 ,458 2,843 ,007 Popul_Growth 1,542 ,592 ,399 2,607 ,013 Milex Initial_GDP Interest_Rate a. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Page 35 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Regression table 2, column 2: Model Summary Model R R Square a 1 ,693 Adjusted R Std. Error of the Square Estimate ,481 ,374 1,14398 a. Predictors: (Constant), Milex_Squared, Inflation_Rate, Interest_Rate, Invest_GDP, Av_Yrs_School, Popul_Growth, Initial_GDP, Milex b ANOVA Model 1 Sum of Squares df Mean Square Regression 47,275 8 5,909 Residual 51,039 39 1,309 Total 98,314 47 F Sig. a 4,516 ,001 a. Predictors: (Constant), Milex_Squared, Inflation_Rate, Interest_Rate, Invest_GDP, Av_Yrs_School, Popul_Growth, Initial_GDP, Milex b. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Coefficients a Standardized Unstandardized Coefficients Model 1 B (Constant) Std. Error ,942 2,418 -,202 1,269 -8,030E-5 Coefficients Beta t Sig. ,390 ,699 -,101 -,159 ,874 ,000 -,511 -2,891 ,006 -,157 ,091 -,256 -1,717 ,094 Invest_GDP ,001 ,035 ,004 ,030 ,976 Inflation_Rate ,167 ,285 ,096 ,585 ,562 Av_Yrs_School ,397 ,146 ,453 2,721 ,010 Popul_Growth 1,517 ,623 ,392 2,436 ,020 Milex_Squared ,041 ,279 ,089 ,149 ,883 Milex Initial_GDP Interest_Rate a. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Page 36 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Regression table 2, column 3: Model Summary Model R R Square a 1 ,506 Adjusted R Std. Error of the Square Estimate ,256 ,173 1,35612 a. Predictors: (Constant), Inflation_Rate, Interest_Rate, Invest_GDP, Milex, Initial_GDP b ANOVA Model 1 Sum of Squares df Mean Square F Regression 28,466 5 5,693 Residual 82,758 45 1,839 111,225 50 Total Sig. 3,096 a ,017 a. Predictors: (Constant), Inflation_Rate, Interest_Rate, Invest_GDP, Milex, Initial_GDP b. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Coefficients a Standardized Unstandardized Coefficients Model 1 B Std. Error (Constant) 4,733 1,633 Milex -,560 ,295 -9,091E-6 Interest_Rate Invest_GDP Initial_GDP Inflation_Rate Coefficients Beta t Sig. 2,899 ,006 -,279 -1,895 ,065 ,000 -,067 -,422 ,675 -,201 ,094 -,316 -2,142 ,038 -,032 ,038 -,114 -,828 ,412 ,406 ,271 ,220 1,502 ,140 a. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Page 37 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Regression table 2, column 4: Model Summary Model R R Square a 1 ,570 Adjusted R Std. Error of the Square Estimate ,325 ,233 1,30581 a. Predictors: (Constant), Milex_Squared, Inflation_Rate, Interest_Rate, Invest_GDP, Initial_GDP, Milex b ANOVA Model 1 Sum of Squares df Mean Square F Regression 36,199 6 6,033 Residual 75,026 44 1,705 111,225 50 Total Sig. a 3,538 ,006 a. Predictors: (Constant), Milex_Squared, Inflation_Rate, Interest_Rate, Invest_GDP, Initial_GDP, Milex b. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Coefficients a Standardized Unstandardized Coefficients Model 1 B (Constant) Std. Error 6,911 1,876 -2,943 1,155 -1,059E-5 Interest_Rate Invest_GDP Coefficients Beta t Sig. 3,685 ,001 -1,469 -2,549 ,014 ,000 -,078 -,511 ,612 -,163 ,092 -,256 -1,770 ,084 -,034 ,037 -,121 -,912 ,367 Inflation_Rate ,363 ,261 ,197 1,391 ,171 Milex_Squared ,568 ,267 1,193 2,130 ,039 Milex Initial_GDP a. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Page 38 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Regression table 3, column 1: Model Summary Model R R Square a 1 ,712 Adjusted R Std. Error of the Square Estimate ,507 ,420 1,10114 a. Predictors: (Constant), D_Industry, Interest_Rate, Av_Yrs_School, Invest_GDP, Inflation_Rate, Popul_Growth, Initial_GDP b ANOVA Model 1 Sum of Squares df Mean Square Regression 49,814 7 7,116 Residual 48,500 40 1,213 Total 98,314 47 F Sig. a 5,869 ,000 a. Predictors: (Constant), D_Industry, Interest_Rate, Av_Yrs_School, Invest_GDP, Inflation_Rate, Popul_Growth, Initial_GDP b. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Coefficients a Standardized Unstandardized Coefficients Model 1 B (Constant) Std. Error 1,010 1,799 -7,101E-5 ,000 -,160 Invest_GDP Coefficients Beta t Sig. ,562 ,578 -,452 -2,759 ,009 ,085 -,262 -1,888 ,066 ,004 ,031 ,015 ,122 ,903 Inflation_Rate ,156 ,271 ,090 ,575 ,569 Av_Yrs_School ,378 ,135 ,432 2,808 ,008 Popul_Growth 1,421 ,571 ,367 2,487 ,017 D_Industry -,515 ,354 -,174 -1,457 ,153 Initial_GDP Interest_Rate a. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Page 39 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Regression table 3, column 2: Model Summary Model R R Square a 1 ,713 Adjusted R Std. Error of the Square Estimate ,509 ,423 1,09885 a. Predictors: (Constant), D_Neutrality, Initial_GDP, Invest_GDP, Popul_Growth, Interest_Rate, Inflation_Rate, Av_Yrs_School b ANOVA Model 1 Sum of Squares df Mean Square Regression 50,015 7 7,145 Residual 48,299 40 1,207 Total 98,314 47 F Sig. a 5,917 ,000 a. Predictors: (Constant), D_Neutrality, Initial_GDP, Invest_GDP, Popul_Growth, Interest_Rate, Inflation_Rate, Av_Yrs_School b. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Coefficients a Standardized Unstandardized Coefficients Model 1 B (Constant) Std. Error ,867 1,786 -6,738E-5 ,000 Interest_Rate -,149 Invest_GDP Coefficients Beta t Sig. ,485 ,630 -,429 -2,554 ,015 ,085 -,243 -1,749 ,088 -,010 ,032 -,037 -,304 ,763 Inflation_Rate ,289 ,284 ,166 1,018 ,315 Av_Yrs_School ,324 ,143 ,369 2,255 ,030 Popul_Growth 1,316 ,584 ,340 2,252 ,030 ,607 ,401 ,205 1,516 ,137 Initial_GDP D_Neutrality a. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Page 40 of 42 Bachelor Thesis Economics, Tilburg University: Dynamics of Military Expenditures and Economic Growth What is the relationship between military expenditures and real economic growth for European countries? Regression table 3, column 3: Model Summary Model R R Square a 1 ,693 Adjusted R Std. Error of the Square Estimate ,481 ,390 1,12993 a. Predictors: (Constant), D_Leadership, Initial_GDP, Popul_Growth, Invest_GDP, Interest_Rate, Inflation_Rate, Av_Yrs_School b ANOVA Model 1 Sum of Squares df Mean Square Regression 47,245 7 6,749 Residual 51,070 40 1,277 Total 98,314 47 F Sig. a 5,286 ,000 a. Predictors: (Constant), D_Leadership, Initial_GDP, Popul_Growth, Invest_GDP, Interest_Rate, Inflation_Rate, Av_Yrs_School b. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Coefficients a Standardized Unstandardized Coefficients Model 1 B (Constant) Std. Error ,736 1,968 -8,200E-5 ,000 -,161 Invest_GDP Coefficients Beta t Sig. ,374 ,710 -,522 -3,245 ,002 ,087 -,263 -1,842 ,073 ,002 ,034 ,007 ,057 ,955 Inflation_Rate ,158 ,280 ,091 ,564 ,576 Av_Yrs_School ,402 ,143 ,458 2,817 ,007 Popul_Growth 1,550 ,579 ,401 2,675 ,011 D_Leadership -,029 ,533 -,007 -,055 ,957 Initial_GDP Interest_Rate a. Dependent Variable: Real_Growth Page 41 of 42