* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download ECMA04H – Week 10
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
ECMA04H – Week 9 Efficiency in competitive and monopolistic markets. Regulating natural monopoly. Objectives this week: - Review Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus - Define Gain to Society (GTS) as summary measure of net economic benefits - Discuss allocative efficiency in competitive and monopolistic markets - Discuss ways to regulate natural monopolies, including marginal cost pricing and average cost pricing 1 From Week 3, what is consumer surplus?…. Price $20 Demand $10 P = 20 – 2Q $6 0 5 7 Fred’s Demand2 for Hamburgers 10 Quantity Per month We can interpret areas under the Demand curve as Total Utility (measured in dollars) Expenditure (P x Q) Consumer Surplus U(Q) – [P x Q] Fred maximizes CS by choosing Q, such that P = 20 – 2Q (price equals marginal utility) We can interpret the height of the curve as: Marginal Utility (dU/dQ) Willingness to pay for this unit (= marginal value or marginal benefit) 3 1. Individuals consume because they gain utility 2. Consumers seek to maximize consumer surplus by choosing amount to consume 3. Consumer surplus is dollar value of utility received by consumers above cost of purchase 4. Consumers max CS by following OPR and choosing amount of good such that MU = P or dU/dQ = P. This is the individual demand curve. 4 Consumer Surplus, Producer Surplus How much does society gain from the activities of producing and consuming? Different answers depending on the situation. Simple situation (normal) when there are no (a) taxes or tariffs (b) external benefits (c) external costs (d) public goods In the simple situation, the benefits to society are the benefits to the individuals that are participating in consuming and producing. i.e., consumer surplus and producer surplus (or profit). 5 Remember definition of economics: Economics is the science that studies the allocation of scarce resources to alternative uses to satisfy unlimited human wants “Efficiency” is achieved when those resources are allocated in a way that delivers the most gain to society Allocative Efficiency 6 Consumer surplus (CS) is dollar value of utility received by consumers above cost of purchase CS represents extra “willingness to pay” above the current price. It is a measure of the “satisfaction” that consumers get above what they have to pay for a good. Increasing CS represents a social gain – a gain to society 7 What is producer surplus? Producer surplus (PS) is the dollar value of revenue received by producers above the minimum amount they require to be willing to supply the good. It is a form of “surplus” received by producers, and therefore can also be considered a gain to society 8 In the short run, the minimum amount producers require is to cover their TVC – the total variable costs of production. Therefore, PS = TR – TVC But, Π = TR – TC = TR – (TFC + TVC) So, TR – TVC = Π + TFC Or, PS = Π + TFC If TFC = 0, PS = Π 9 So PS is a concept very similar to profit (a surplus received by producers above what they require to supply the good). In the SR, PS is bigger than profit by the amount of fixed costs. (As you will see, we often use profit [instead of producer surplus] when calculating Gain To Society). Look at CS and PS on graph 10 Price $60 Supply $30 $25 $15 $11 0 Demand 100,000 300,000 350,000 11 Market for 4’ x 8’ sheets of ¾” plywood 475,000 450,000 Quantity Per month Price $60 Supply $30 $25 $15 $11 0 Demand 100,000 300,000 350,000 Market for 4’ x 8’ sheets of ¾” plywood 12 475,000 450,000 Quantity Per month Price $60 Supply $30 $25 $15 $11 0 Demand 100,000 300,000 350,000 Market for 4’ x 8’ sheets of ¾” plywood 13 475,000 450,000 Quantity Per month Define Gain to Society (GTS) as the sum of Consumer Surplus plus Profit GTS = CS + Π Use this to compare competitive and monopoly results (allocative efficiency in competitive and monopoly markets) 14 Imagine there are 100 firms in a perfectly competitive market. In the long run, in this constant cost industry, supply is given by P = 100 (horizontal long run supply at a price of $100). Consumer demand in the industry is given by P = 1000 – Q What is the equilibrium in this industry in the LR, and what is the GTS? 15 Draw the diagram 16 GTS = CS + Π 17 Imagine that a monopoly firm is able to buy up all 100 firms and establish some barrier to new firms entering the industry (e.g., a government licence as exclusive supplier). The monopolist keeps all the 100 plants separate and operates as many as he needs to supply the good. In effect the SLR becomes the MC curve (and the AC curve) of the monopolist. 18 The Gain To Society in the monopoly situation is given by GTS = CS + Π 19 How do perfect competition and monopoly compare? Under PC, GTS = $405,000 (and all of it goes to the consumers). Producers receive just enough to keep them in the industry and producing, but not more. Under monopoly, GTS = $303,750 (lower by $101,250), and there has been a transfer of surplus so that the producer receives the biggest part ($202,500) and consumers receive $101,250. 20 Perfect competition maximizes the sum of the surpluses to consumers and to producers. Therefore, PC has the largest Gain to Society and is efficient. There is a loss of Gain To Society under monopoly. In other words, there is a loss of efficiency under monopoly. We call this a “deadweight” loss or efficiency loss. “Deadweight” because it is completely lost to society (rather than transferred to someone else). Note: not all losses are deadweight losses. 21 There is also a transfer of surplus under monopoly, which we might well object to (but it is not part of our calculation of GTS). Two concepts: Efficiency and Equity We notice equity, but focus on efficiency. 22 Look at this problem graphically: 23 What should government policy be towards monopoly? It depends: (a) is allocative efficiency the only measure? What about dynamic efficiency? (Schumpeter – waves of creative destruction) (b) Why does the monopoly exist? What is the nature of the “barrier to entry”? Is it a government patent? Is it a economies of scale (i.e., natural monopoly)? (c) What can government do? Can government restore competition? Can it regulate the monopolist? Will the results be better? 24 In case of natural monopoly (electricity, telephone, roads, bridges, etc.), governments may regulate the monopolist. (Another alternative is to take firm into public sector). Rate of return regulation Control monopolist by forcing it to charge a certain price that will affect the profits and production of the monopolist. 2 choices: (a) Regulate monopolist to charge P = MC (b) Regulate monopolist to charge P = AC 25 Diagramatically, what are these alternatives? 26 What are the effects of P = MC? 27 What are the effects of P = AC? 28 What will happen if the government does nothing? 29 What are the strengths and weaknesses of these different solutions? 30 An algebraic example: Highway 407. Privately owned and operated highway. Demand: P = 300 - .5Q, where Q is measured in trips per day FC = $1,950 per day VC = $100 per trip TC = $1,950 + 100Q 31 What will unregulated monopolist do and what is the GTS? 32 What if government regulates the monopolist to charge P = MC? What happens and what is the GTS? 33 What if government regulates the monopolist to charge P = AC? What happens and what is the GTS? 34 Conclusions? 35