Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Dividends The standard Black-Scholes analysis does not allow for div- Stochastic Calculus, Week 9 idend payments. We may introduce them in two alternative Applications of risk-neutral valuation ways: • Dividend is paid continuously, with a dividend yield δ; • Dividend is paid at discrete time points. Outline Continuous dividends 1. Dividends Suppose that the dividends are paid continuously at the rate 2. Foreign exchange δ, and that all dividends are reinvested in the stock. Then 3. Quantos the value S̃t of a portfolio that starts with one stock evolves 4. Market price of risk as dS̃t = at dSt + δat St dt, where at = S̃t /St , the number of shares at time t. Thus, dS̃t = S̃t (µdt + σdWt ) + δ S̃t dt = (µ + δ)S̃t dt + σ S̃t dWt . This implies that S̃t = eδt St , and hence at = eδt . 1 A strategy (φt , ψ t ) in terms of (St , Bt ) may be written as This yields, via risk-neutral valuation: a corresponding strategy (φ̃t , ψ t ) in terms of (S̃t , Bt ), with φ̃t = e−δt φt . The self-financing restriction now is (with Vt = • The forward price of St : setting e−r(T −t) EQ [(ST − φ̃t S̃t + ψ t Bt ) Ft )|Ft ] = 0 and solving for Ft gives Ft = e(r−δ)(T −t) St . dVt = φ̃t dS̃t + ψ t dBt = φt dSt + φt δSt dt + ψ t dBt . • The price of a call option struck at K. Following the The essential point is that, whereas the replicating portfolio same steps as in the standard Black-Scholes model, we is in terms of S̃t , the derivative is in terms of St . Note that find the measure Q which makes Z̃t = Bt−1 S̃t a martingale, does not make Bt−1 St Vt = e−r(T −t) EQ [(ST − K)+ |Ft ] a martingale. = e−δ(T −t) St Φ(d˜1 ) − e−r(T −t) KΦ(d˜2 ) n o −r(T −t) ˜ ˜ = e Ft Φ(d1 ) − KΦ(d2 ) We find dZ̃t = (µ + δ − r)Z̃t dt + σ Z̃t dWt with log(St /K) + [(r − δ) ± 12 σ 2 ](T − t) ˜ √ d1,2 = σ T −t log(Ft /K) ± 12 σ 2 (T − t) √ . = σ T −t = σ Z̃t dW̃t , µ+δ−r , which is a σ Brownian motion under the measure Q defined by dQ/dP = where W̃t = Wt + γt, with γ = exp(−γWT − 12 γ 2 T ). Hence dSt = (r − δ)St dt + σSt dW̃t , 1 2 St = S0 exp [r − δ − 2 σ ]t + σ W̃t 2 Discrete dividends Foreign exchange When dividends are paid at discrete time points T1 , . . . , Tn , Let Ct denote the exchange rate, in US dollar per pound then the stock goes ex-dividend, which means its price falls sterling. We’ll assume a geometric Brownian motion for instantaneously by the amount of the dividend. When these Ct : dividends are immediately reinvested, the value S̃t of that dCt = µCt dt + σCt dWt . strategy of course does not display these discontinuities; i.e., Next, consider a US cash bond Bt = ert and a UK cash bond we simply may assume Dt = eut ; i.e., the interest rates r and u may be different. dS̃t = µS̃t dt + σ S̃t dWt . From the perspective of the US investor, there are two as- (Note: µ here should be compared with µ + δ in the contin- sets: the domestic cash bond with price Bt , and the foreign uous dividend model). cash bond with price St = Ct Dt . Note that the latter is a risky asset; its SDE is When the dividend payments are δSt , we obtain dSt = Ct dDt + Dt dCt St = (1 − δ)n[t] S̃t , = (µ + u)St dt + σSt dWt where n[t] is the number of dividend payments made by = rSt dt + σSt dW̃t , time t. where W̃t = Wt + γt, γ = This implies Q, the risk-neutral measure. Ft = (1 − δ)n[T ]−n[t] er(T −t) St , and the value of a call option remains the same in terms of Ft . 3 µ+u−r . This again defines σ Notice that under this measure, Again, the value of a call option on the exchange rate struck at K is the same as before, when expressed in terms of Ft . EQ [CT |Ft ] = e−uT EQ [ST |Ft ] = e−uT er(T −t) St Change of numeraire = e(r−u)(T −t) Ct , The entire analysis could be repeated from the perspective of the UK investor, who has the choice between a sterling which yields the uncovered interest rate parity: cash bond Dt and the sterling value of a dollar cash bond, EQ [CT |Ft ] (r − u)(T − t) = log , Ct S̃t = Ct−1 Bt . The discounted price then is Dt−1 Ct−1 Bt = where the right-hand side is the conditionally expected con- Zt−1 , where Zt = Bt−1 St . The martingale measure is not tinuous depreciation. the same as before: a measure which makes Zt a martingale The forward exchange rate (for delivery at time T ) Ft should hedge ratios are the same, regardless of the choice of the solve measure. e−r(T −t) EQ [(CT − Ft )|Ft ] = 0, 1 2 and since CT = Ct exp [r − u − 2 σ ](T − t) + σ[W̃T − W̃t ] , Similarly, in the standard Black-Scholes model we may also does not make Zt−1 a martingale. However, the prices and work with a measure Q∗ which makes St−1 Bt a martingale. this will yield (r−u)(T −t) Ft = e The important thing is to make relative prices martingales – Ct , the choice of the numeraire is not important. which gives the covered interest rate parity: (r − u)(T − t) = log Ft . Ct 4 Quantos The equivalent martingale measure now should turn both dollar assets Bt−1 Ct St and Bt−1 Ct Dt into martingale, which Quantos are derivatives which have a payoff in another cur- now involves a vector γ = (γ 1 , γ 2 )0 , with rency than the underlying asset, using a fixed, prespecified exchange rate C̄ (e.g., one dollar per pound sterling). For dQ = exp −γ 0 WT − 12 γ 0 γT , dP example, when St is a sterling stock price and K is a cor- where WT = (W1 (T ), W2 (T ))0 . The actual definition of rresponding strike price, then a quanto call has the dollar γ follows from deriving the SDE for the discounted dollar payoff assets and setting the drifts to zero. + C̄(ST − K) . Note that C̄St is not a tradable dollar asset; hence its dis- In order to price such a derivative, one has to set up a joint counted value need not be a martingale. In fact its drift is process for (St , Ct ), which is a vector diffusion with two (u − ρσ 1 σ 2 )C̄St dt, which in general does not equal rC̄St dt. independent Brownian motions (W1 (t), W2 (t)): It can be derived that the dollar forward price on C̄St will dSt = µdt + σ 1 dW1 (t), St dCt = νdt + σ 2 dW2∗ (t) Ct p = νdt + ρσ 2 dW1 (t) + 1 − ρ2 σ 2 dW2 (t), p ∗ where W2 (t) = ρW1 (t) + 1 − ρ2 W2 (t) is a standard be FQt = C̄ exp(−ρσ 1 σ 2 [T − t])Ft , where Ft is the sterling forward price. The quanto call value then is the usual, with Ft replaced by FQt , K replaced by C̄K, and σ replaced by σ 1 . Brownian motion, which has correlation ρ with W1 (t), i.e., EP [W1 (t)W2∗ (t)] = ρt. 5 where rt is the risk-free interest rate. In models with more Market price of risk than one driving Brownian motion, there is a vector of mar- The fundamental theorem of asset pricing states that the ab- ket prices of risk, one for each source of risk (i.e., each sence of arbitrage opportunities is equivalent to the exis- Brownian motion). tence of a measure Q under which all asset prices relative to some numeraire are martingales. The equivalent martin- Exercises gale measure is unique if markets are complete, i.e., if any 1. Consider a bivariate geometric Brownian motion of the claim is replicable. form Note that only tradable asset need to be martingales under dS1 (t) = S1 (t) {µ1 dt + σ 11 dW1 (t) + σ 12 dW2 (t)} , Q; the previous examples all had a payoff in terms of a non- dS2 (t) = S2 (t) {µ2 dt + σ 21 dW1 (t) + σ 22 dW2 (t)} , tradable asset, which was an explicit function of another where W1 (t) and W2 (t) are independent Brownian mo- tradable. tions, and µi and σ ij are constants, i, j = 1, 2. Find The existence of Q implies a common market price of risk the vector γ of market prices of risks, and check that γ t , which determines the change of measure via the CMG e−rt S1 (t) and e−rt S2 (t) are both martingales under the theorem. For example, if two tradable asset prices S1 (t) and measure Q defined by this γ. S2 (t) are driven by the same Brownian motion Wt : 2. Suppose that S1 and S2 are geometric Brownian motions, dS1 (t) = µ1t S1 (t)dt + σ 1t S1 (t)dWt , driven by the same Brownian motion Wt . Show that if dS2 (t) = µ2t S2 (t)dt + σ 2t S2 (t)dWt , then γt = both are tradable asset prices, but with a different market price of risk, then an arbitrage opportunity exists. µ1t − rt µ − rt = 2t , σ 1t σ 2t 6