Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
1 MF807 Fall 2008 Prof. Thomas Chemmanur Topic Note on Market Efficiency 1. Capital Market Efficiency The purpose of the capital markets is to transfer funds between lenders (savers) and borrowers (producers) in such a way that all projects which create value (in the sense that they are positive NPV projects) are funded (and therefore implemented). To do this in a proper manner, capital markets have to be informationally efficient. In an efficient capital market, prices fully and instantaneously reflect all available relevant information: this means that when assets are traded, prices are accurate signals, which can be used by investors for capital allocation. Why is it important that markets be efficient? I will illustrate why with an example. Consider the case of an entrepreneur who has a promising project which can generate cash flows with a present value of $ H. The investment required for this project is $1. The NPV of this project is then $ (H - 1). We know that whenever a project has a positive NPV, it makes sense to invest in it. Assume that our entrepreneur's project is a positive NPV project: ie., H - 1 > 0. Now, if our entrepreneur approaches the stock market to raise capital for his project, and if the stock market is informationally efficient, then the entrepreneur can get $ H for the entire equity in his company, and can therefore undertake the project. However, consider the case where the stock market is not informationally efficient, and investors are unable to tell the difference between our entrepreneur's 'good' project and other projects with present value of cash flows equal to $L. (Assume that these projects also 2 have an investment requirement of $1, with NPV = $(L -1) < 0 : ie., these are negative NPV projects). Assume further that even though investors can't tell the two projects apart, they know, when faced with any project, that there is a 50% chance that the project is of either type. Then, even if our H type entrepreneur approaches the stock market, he will get only the average value across good and bad projects, ie., (H + L)/2 for the entire equity in his company. Then, if (H + L)/2 < $1, our entrepreneur with the good project will not be able to undertake it! This is an important problem when markets are not informationally efficient: all positive NPV projects will not get funded. Thus an efficient market is one in which entrepreneurs get the "true" price for the securities they sell to investors. If an entrepreneur sells securities in an efficient market, the transaction is neither a positive NPV transaction nor a negative NPV transaction. It is a zero NPV transaction, so that investors get exactly what they paid for. When can we expect to find an efficient market? We can expect markets to be efficient when information is widely and cheaply available to investors, there are a large number of traders so that each trader is insignificant compared to the market as a whole and there are relatively low transactions costs involved in trading so that investors will trade to take advantage of any mispricing they observe, leading prices to reflect all information available with investors. 2. Three possible levels to which capital markets may be efficient The ideal of market efficiency in the example I discussed above is quite strong: 3 this implied that no investor can earn excess returns using any information, whether publicly available or not. This form of the efficient markets hypothesis is usually called strong form efficiency. Usually, real world capital markets are not strong form efficient. For example, we know from academic studies and reports in the press that people who trade on insider information are able to make handsome profits for themselves, which is a violation of strong-form efficiency. Academic studies have tested three different hypotheses about market efficiency, depending on the type of information with respect to which market efficiency is defined: 1. Weak-form efficiency: A market is weak-form efficient if current prices fully reflect all the information contained in past prices (or equivalently, return data). Thus, if the market is even weak-form efficient, no investor will be able to earn excess returns by developing trading rules based on historical price or return information. Thus, weakform efficiency precludes investors earning abnormally high returns by using "filter rules"; it also precludes technical analysts (e.g., chartists) from earning abnormally high returns. 2. Semistrong-form efficiency: A market is semi-strong efficient if the prices of all securities reflect all publicly available information (this includes past price and return data as well as other publicly available information such as the annual reports of companies, investment advisory data such as the "Heard on the Street" column in the Wall Street Journal or ticker tape information). Therefore, if the market is efficient in the semi-strong sense, no investor can earn excess returns using any publicly available information. 3. Strong-form efficiency: A market is strong-form efficient if the current price of all 4 securities reflects all available information, whether such information has been publicly released or not. This implies that even those who trade on insider information will not be able to earn excess returns in a market which is strong-form efficient. It should be clear from the above definitions that the three hypotheses above are nested: i.e., if a market is strong form efficient, it is also semi-strong form efficient and weak form efficient; if it is only semi-strong form efficient, it is also weak form efficient (since the past history of prices is also a part of publicly available information). Extensive empirical tests in many financial markets have shown that, while most of these are not strong-form efficient, almost all are semistrong-form efficient. 3. Characteristics of an efficient capital market We can test whether capital markets (eg. the stock market) are in fact efficient by checking whether the observed behavior of market prices conform to that predicted by the different forms of the efficient markets concept. For example, if the stock market are weak form efficient, we should not be able to predict (forecast) future stock prices. Neither should there be any consistent pattern in stock returns. If there are any such patterns, investors can trade using technical trading rules called "filter rules" to take advantage of such patterns and make abnormal profits. In practice, academic studies have shown that markets are efficient enough that it is not possible to make such profits using filter rules (if we also include the transactions costs involved in trading). Also, changes in stock prices are quite random, so that the time series of stock returns resembles a random walk. (If prices reflect all available information, then prices will change only when new information arrives. But new information, by definition, is 5 something that cannot be predicted ahead of time. Therefore, price changes cannot be predicted ahead of time, and are random). Another implication of market efficiency is that there can be no financial illusions: We know from our study of stock and bond valuation that investors should only be concerned with cash flows when valuing these securities, not accounting figures. However, quite often firm managers devote considerable time and effort to ensure that their earnings report presents the best picture possible to stockholders, in the hope that this will have a favorable impact on the stock price. If markets are efficient, on the other hand, this should not be the case, and prices should not be affected irrespective of the way in which earnings figures are presented in the accounting reports. Here again, several academic studies in different contexts have shown that this is indeed the case, and it is difficult to affect security prices through cosmetic changes which do not affect the firm's cash flows. 4. Market efficiency, security analysts and portfolio managers If markets fully reflect all available information, what is the role of security analysts? If information generation is costless, indeed they do not have any useful role in an efficient market. However, we know that producing information is costly. Thus if nobody undertakes information production, prices will not contain any information. Thus, when information production is costly, the role of security analysts is to undertake information production, and earn a fair return on this activity. However, security analysts compete with each other, so that if the return to security analysis becomes large, new individuals will enter the analysis business so that on average, they 6 get a fair return. In fact, in a market with costly information, security analysts have an important role to play in making markets efficient. There are two kinds of analysts: the technical analysts study the past price record, and try to exploit patterns in the past series of prices, until these patterns disappear from prices. Fundamental analysts study the business of the firm and other available public information about the firm being evaluated to unearth undervalued securities. They will then trade to exploit such opportunities, so that prices come back in line with true underlying values. Another implication the efficient markets hypothesis is for mutual fund portfolio managers. Mutual funds are companies which hold portfolios of stocks and other securities. Investors who invest in these funds thus invest in a large portfolio, whose composition is changed from time to time at the discretion of the managers of these funds. Mutual funds claim that they provide two kinds of services to their clients: First, they help an investor to diversify, thus reducing the amount of unsystematic risk he must face. Second, they claim they are able to use their professional expertise in selecting the securities which constitute the portfolio held by the fund and thus to earn abnormally high returns (abnormally high relative to the risk of the fund). This second claim is contradictory to the semi-strong form of the efficient markets hypothesis unless, for some reason, mutual fund managers can consistently obtain information that is not publicly available. How can we test the claims made by mutual fund managers? One way to test this is using the Capital Asset Pricing Model. The capital asset pricing model states that if all investors have identical information, the expected return on any asset should be linearly related to its systematic risk measured by ß. Specifically, 7 (1) ri = rF + βi( rm - rF) Therefore, assuming that the CAPM is true, we can use expected return as predicted by the CAPM as a benchmark to evaluate the actual performance of portfolio _ managers. Let r A be the actual average return obtained on the portfolio over the period over which we want to evaluate the portfolio's performance. Then, define ξi by, (2) ξi = rA - ri = rA - [rF + βi( rm - rF)] ξi can be thought of as the "abnormal performance" of the i th portfolio in the period under consideration. Then, if ξi > 0, the portfolio over-performed compared to its riskiness during this period; if ξi < 0, the portfolio under-performed. Most academic studies have found that while there are some portfolios which have consistently positive ξ s, the average value of ξ across all available mutual funds, N i i / N is negative (where N is the number of funds in the sample, and the return data used is net of operating costs of the fund). This means that, on average, mutual funds under-perform corresponding to the risk of their portfolio! Thus, while some fund managers indeed seem to have a comparative advantage in producing information, we cannot say that the semi-strong form of the efficient markets hypothesis is rejected in this case also. 5. How should we think about market efficiency? The topic of market efficiency is rather controversial, perhaps because it is not well-understood. It is important to emphasize that market efficiency is not a question 8 with a "yes" or "no" answer. It is best to ask, "to what degree is this market informationally efficient?" rather than "is this market informationally efficient or not?" In an efficient market, investors rapidly pounce on new information, analyze it effectively, revise their expectations about the future cash flows from holding various securities, and buy or sell securities accordingly. This, in turn, implies that in such a market, prices will rapidly adjust to new information, and current prices will fully reflect all available information. Thus, market efficiency does not imply that the market has any magical qualities in the sense that prices reflect some measure of true value as yet unknown to everybody; neither does it preclude any large changes in asset prices (in fact, precisely the opposite: it implies that prices will change rapidly as new economically relevant information becomes available). The degree of informational efficiency in any financial market is an empirical question, which can be tested based on suitable data in that particular security market with respect to a given context; we cannot make blanket statements about the efficiency or otherwise of security markets. In general, it has been found that the capital markets in the more developed economies are more efficient; the greater the number of market participants, the greater the speed with which investors can make transactions, and the cheaper such transactions are, the more informationally efficient the market.