Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
An evolving theory of hybrid distribution: Taming a hostile supply network Jule B. Gassenheimer a,⁎ , Gary L. Hunter b,1, Judy A. Siguaw c,2 The contribution of this paper - research suggests that close relationships between buyers and sellers can lead to competitive advantage (e.g., Jap, 2001), but has not investigated how one supplier–buyer channel relationship might impact another such relationship. Propose that social capital, structural holes, trust, and distributive fairness can be used to govern the effectiveness of cooperation and competition among hybrid channels and yield higher performance within the supply network. A corresponding propositional inventory is offered. The existence of exchange relationships in the supply networks - Rather than focusing on a specific set of actors, supply networks are characterized by sets of purposeful and connected exchange relationships, which may change over time as specific actors are involved, deactivated, or reactivated in the performance of production tasks.” Andersen and Christensen (2005, p. 1261) Gaining the competitive advantage amongst the distributors - Customers, however, increasingly demand goods and services from a variety of different channels (Alba et al., 1997; Anders, 2000) and suppliers attempt to address these demands by making their products available through channels that could potentially overlap (Lassar & Kerr, 1996). Therefore distributors are likely to be aggravated that their supplier is cooperating with a competitor, resulting in strained relationships between the supplier and its distributors (Sa Vinhas & Anderson, 2005). Firms, which prove best at managing the relationships within such networks, can increase efficiencies while appealing to a number of markets (e.g., Bonner, Kim, & Cavusgil, 2005). This can establish a competitive advantage. What is a hybrid supply network? Hybrid distribution cuts across the supply network adding a horizontal structure, which can include competitive as well as cooperative links between channels in an attempt to reach an expanded customer market. We need only look to the popular business press to realize the difficulties suppliers have encountered when attempting to govern multiple types of distribution within their supply network. Examples of Compaq, HP are given as well as record companies, in anticipation of additional profits, began using Internet subscription music services (e.g., Napster 2.0) despite the expected loss of business to brick and mortar retailers (Burrows, 2003). In all of these examples, the supplier failed to appropriately manage the impact of its hybrid distribution strategies and thus damaged its relationship with current members of the supply network. Hybrid distribution, as a supplier-directed decision, is intended to benefit the supplier by increasing multi-market competition (Antia, Bergen, & Dutta, 2004; Purohit, 1997). A residual effect, however, is the potential creation of overlapping markets that may cannibalize existing distributors' customer bases (cf., Choi, 2003; Russell, 1999). Channel hybridization, therefore, may disrupt relations within the supply chain and can be viewed as detrimental to one or more partners (Hibbard, Kumar, & Stern, 2001), potentially threatening the effectiveness of the supply network (e.g., Anderson & Weitz, 1992). 1.1. Networks, social capital and structural holes Central to network theory is the positions of parties inrelation to the rest of the network. For example, a supplier in a supply chain holds a nodal position and may act as a broker connecting different distributors in the network. These indirect power connections may occur through social or knowledge linkages that the supplier intentionally helps establish (Burt, 2004). Alternatively, network parties may be relatively isolated or distant, having little or no connections to others in the network outside of the broker. Where parties in a network have few or no interconnections, the network is said to have ‘structural holes’ (Burt, 1992). Structural holes represent two forms of spatial gaps: social relationship distance and knowledge distance (Roy, Sivakumar, & Wilkinson, 2004). Social relationship distance incorporates the concept of proximity or feelings of nearness. Knowledge distance captures the diversity of knowledge between groups. Suppliers want to increase the structural holes in the distributor–distributor relationships, suppliers want few structural holes in their supplier–distributor relationships as an absence of structural holes is indicative of a strong relationship and assures ease of accurate information transference. To effectively execute this strategy, the supplier must make use of its social capital through its brokerage function. Suppliers, because they bridge the structural holes between types of distributors, are perfectly positioned to identify and capitalize on opportunities and to collect and disseminate a wider variety of information. Social capital represents the value created between channel partners in the supply network (Burt, 1992) How do suppliers strengthen their position in the network? Reducing structural holes between the supplier and distributors and increasing structural holes between types of distributors strengthen the supplier's brokerage status within the supply network through an improved supplier–distributor social relationship and information flow, while decreasing direct information sharing between distribution types. Increasing structural holes between the supplier and distributors and reducing structural holes between types of distributors weaken the supply network by diluting the supplier–distributor social relationship and knowledge sharing, while simultaneously encouraging greater information sharing, and possibly overembeddedness and redundancy, between types of distribution (Burt, 1992, 2004). Therefore, suppliers want to sustain their social capital by taking a brokerage position and being solely responsible for creating and transferring value. 1.2. Trust In hybrid distribution where customer markets frequently overlap causing greater pressures between competing distributors operating within the same supplier network, shared goals become less obvious, coordinated efforts often go astray, and economic self-interest is perceived to drive supply network decisions. Consequently, the network and social capital literatures underscore the importance of trust in changing perceptions and sustaining cooperative relationships within network environments where partners (e.g., multiple distributors) compete (e.g., Granovetter, 1985; Uzzi, 1997). Once distributors trust the supplier, cooperation generally follows as distributors feel less threatened to pursue, what is argued to be, mutually compatible interests (Jap, 1999; Petersen, Ragatz, & Monczka, 2005). Not surprisingly, trust increases social capital and has been found to affect simultaneous relationships, at least within an intra-organizational context (Burt, 1992; Golicic et al., 2003). 1.3. Distributive fairness Distributive fairness refers to perceptions of fairness based on how earnings and outcomes are distributed (e.g., Kumar, Scheer, & Steenkamp, 1995; Miles & Klein, 1998). See the model below. 2. A model and propositions for governing hybrid channel interactions we suggest that trust be used to govern relationships (see also Andaleep, 1996; Keysuk, 2000). We propose two crucial factors in sustaining or increasing trust within the channel relationship when hybrid distribution is introduced to the supply network. These two factors – credible commitments and distributive fairness – have been selected because of their ability to leverage value in relationships and encourage cooperation, even when faced with competitive situations that could be viewed as possible threats (Brown et al., 2000; Ghoshal & Moran, 1996; Ouchi, 1980). Also, propose that credible commitments directly influence distribution fairness and indirectly influence trust and provide a foundation for ultimately plugging structural holes between the supplier and distributor, and governing the redundancy or structural holes between types of distributors (e.g., Lawler & Yoon, 1996). Credible commitments are specific actions or investments by a supply chain partner that demonstrate good faith (i.e., trustworthiness) and bind relationships (Anderson & Weitz, 1992; Frazier & Lassar, 1996). They produce mutual competitive advantages and improve joint performance and relationship continuity (Jap, 2001). Credible commitments also signal to distributors that the competition embedded in the hybrid distribution system holds long-term benefits for all involved in the supply network. The level of investment directed at those financially weakened by hybridization, when used effectively, increases perceptions of fairness, initially neutralizes favoritism, and diminishes the likelihood of opportunistic behavior (e.g., Anderson & Weitz, 1992). Anderson and Weitz (1992) found a positive relationship between suppliers' investments in credible commitments and distributors' perceptions of supplier fairness. Types of credible commitments that suppliers provide to distributors include exclusive rights to represent the supplier in a particular area, investments in training distributors' employees, promotions that link suppliers and distributors in the minds of customers, and the establishment of common ordering systems (Anderson & Weitz, 1992; Fein & Anderson, 1997; Frazier & Lassar, 1996). While suppliers should strive to decrease structural holes between themselves and distributors they should also increase structural holes between distributors. Increasing structural holes between distributors suggests non-redundancy. Types of credible commitments that suppliers provide to distributors include exclusive rights to represent the supplier in a particular area, investments in training distributors' employees, promotions that link suppliers and distributors in the minds of customers, and the establishment of common ordering systems (Anderson & Weitz, 1992; Fein & Anderson, 1997; Frazier & Lassar, 1996). Focus on branded variants and compensation schemes as two alternative credible commitments for not only creating perceptions of fair solutions, but also regulating directly structural holes and indirectly trust. 2.2. Branded variants - The use of credible commitments in the form of branded variants directly increases the distributors' perceptions of the supplier's distributive fairness, increases structural holes between types of distributors, and indirectly increases distributor trust in the supplier. Branded variants identify branded products that assume nonequivalent forms across distribution outlets (Bergen, Dutta, & Shugan, 1996; Shugan, 1989). For example, Lexmark could produce a traditional line of printers for retailers, such as Best Buy and Circuit City, while creating a different model for distribution through Internet merchandisers, such as Dell, which then sell the Lexmark branded printer in a bundled package with its Dell computer. A branded variant strategy allows the supplier to grant exclusive distribution rights for that particular variation of the product in that area while maintaining some of the benefits of intensive distribution via other variations of the same product throughout the market. By eliminating overlapping markets, the supplier will enhance distributor perceptions of distributive fairness. We assert that branded variants, when serving as credible commitments increase the financially weakened distributor's perceptions of the supplier's distributive fairness, as well as reduce market redundancy between distribution types. In effect, structural holes between types of distributors are increased while the diversity of markets served is enhanced. 2.3. Compensation schemes - The use of credible commitments in the form of compensation schemes directly increases the distributors' perceptions of the supplier's distributive fairness, decreases structural holes between the supplier and the distributors, and indirectly increases trust in the supplier. Compensation or reward schemes can also be used as credible commitments to increase perceptions of the supplier's distributive fairness and decrease structural holes between the supplier and distributors (Burt, 1992). Compensation schemes, therefore, are designed to temporarily recompense distribution types for the loss of customers to other distribution types, thereby, facilitating perceptions of distributive fairness. For example, MetLife typically provides additional compensation to existing insurers when adding a new channel that competes for the same customers (Roberts, 1999). Based on the prisoner's dilemma principle, allmembers of the supply network are potentially better off if everyone works harder (Axelrod, 1984; Weitzman & Kruse, 1991). The distributors, after being compensated for lost business, should believe that the supplier holds their interest at heart and place a greater emphasis on their non-overlapping markets. Believing in these future returns increases perceptions of the supplier's distributive fairness and decreases structural holes between the supplier and distributors. If future supply chain returns are not perceived valuable enough, the temptation exists to free ride the network as one type of distributor's rewards depends on another type's efforts (e.g. Williamson, 1985). 2.4. Distributive fairness and trust - Distributors' perceptions of the supplier'sdistributive fairness increase trust in the supplier. In that channel hybridization often results in overlapping markets with the potential for detrimental changes in performance outcomes, we turn to distributive fairness, “the perceived fairness of the distribution of outcomes” (Hauenstein, McGonigle, & Flinder, 2001, p. 39), as a prerequisite to trust; especially when distributors have been weakened by hybrid distribution. Equality, need and equity represent the rules of fairness and provide suppliers alternative approaches for allocating rewards and, in turn, a means of creating alternative perceptions among types of distributors (e.g., Gassenheimer, Houston et al., 1998). Another rule of allocation is based upon the needs of each party. In this case, self-interest must take a backseat to the interests of others, even when doing so damages one's own interest (Sabbagh, 2001). Should weakened distributors' demand decline, the distribution rule of need suggests that the supplier compensate these financially weakened distributors for remaining in the relationship. Distributors with greater needs receive a larger share of the supply network's surplus resources and rewards. Assisting the financially weakened distributor also reinforces that the supplier can be trusted to right any wrong between the supplier and the weakened distributor. 2.5. Trust, structural holes, and cooperation: - The greater the distributor trust in the supplier, the fewer the structural holes between the supplier and the distributors. The greater the structural holes between the supplier and distributors, the less the cooperation between the supplier and the distributors. The greater the structural holes between types of distributors, the greater the cooperation between the supplier and the distributors. The greater the distributor trusts in the supplier, the greater the cooperation between the supplier and the distributors. Trust, at some level, is presumed to exist in relationships, which require collaboration and information sharing (Ahuja, 2000); consequently, trust should characterize the supplier– distributor relationship. First, research indicates that trusting another is easier than not trusting (Droege, Anderson, & Bowler, 2003). Second, sanctions can be used against those who choose to behave in an untrustworthy manner (Brockner & Siegel, 1996), and third, trustworthy behavior is required in order to maintain the reputation of the organization (Burt & Knez, 1996). The challenge for the supplier is to prevent trust transfer from the supplier–distributor relationship to the distributor– distributor relationship. Uzzi (1997) notes that the party who serves as a bridge between previously unconnected groups may create a union between those groups. Hence, while the effect of trust on supply chain structural holes has not been previously investigated, trust transfer between individuals increases the strength of ties between parties and closes any structural hole that had previously existed (McEvily et al., 2003). Extending this finding to supply networks suggests that unique information flows within the supply network would be constrained and the effectiveness of the supply network in terms of non-redundancy would be weakened (McEvily et al., 2003; Uzzi, 1997). Thus, suppliers must seek to maintain structural holes between types of distributors when the goal is non-redundancy of information and markets. To ensure social and knowledge distance between distributors, suppliers must erect communication barriers between types of distributors, including, but not limited to, the primary use of different communication channels, a different business language (e.g., traditional business acronyms are varied from one type of distribution channel to another), and different formal communication paths (Kelly, 2000). That is, trust encourages social relationships and the dissemination of knowledge across firms, while structural holes restrain such behaviors. The joint use of trust in conjunction with the regulation of structural holes should then foster a cooperative environment between supplier and distributor, but encourage a competitive but non-zero sum relationship between distributors (e.g., DiMaggio & Powell, 1983). 2.6. Structural holes and supply network performance - Suppliers that maintain structural holes between types of distributors by brokering the relationship will improve supply network performance Competition alone is often viewed as a lose–lose game in which all players may suffer from a decline in financial performance. Indeed, Dozoretz and Matanovich (2002) argue that under strict conditions of competition not only are rivals worse off, but so are customers because competitors do not have the financial gains to invest in improvements that would benefit customers. Moreover, competitive actions may lower earnings of their entire industry (Dozoretz & Matanovich, 2002). Structural holes can be maintained between distributor types when the supplier serves as the broker of social relationships and information, in turn, resulting in improved hybrid supply network performance. For example, Procter and Gamble uses radio frequency identification (RFID) tags on many of its products. The tags allow the supplier to track product information throughout the supply network. Procter and Gamble have been pioneers in the field of RFID (Jewell, 2005). The devices allow suppliers to collect information from different distribution channels and subsequently they can serve as brokers of such information. 2.7. Cooperation and supply network performance - Cooperation between the supplier and the distributors will be positively associated with supply network performance. Increased cooperation between a supplier and its distributors should enhance supply network performance. An extensive body of research stretching back to the 1960s indicates that channel cooperation has a positive influence on channel performance (e.g., Mallen, 1967; Pearson, & Monoky, 1976). In a more recent era, Jap (1999) and Petersen et al. (2005) offer evidence that close collaboration between distributors and suppliers can increase profits and serve as a competitive advantage, while Morris and Carter (2005) find that cooperation improves channel efficiency. Cooperative partnerships also increase performance by cutting the cost of bringing goods to the customer (Buzzell & Ortmeyer, 1995).