Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
C European Historical Economics Society 2011 European Review of Economic History, 15, 443–474. doi:10.1017/S1361491611000037 First published online 25 March 2011 Remittances, capital flows and financial development during the mass migration period, 1870–1913 R U I E S T E V E S ∗ A N D D A V I D K H O U D O U R - C A S T É R A S ∗∗ ∗ Department of Economics, University of Oxford, Oxford OX1 3UQ, UK, and CEMPRE – Centro de Estudos Macroeconómicos e de Previsão, Oporto, Portugal, [email protected] ∗∗ OECD Development Centre, 2 rue André Pascal, 75775 Paris Cedex 16, France, [email protected] This article addresses the question whether the substantial financial flows received by emigration countries contributed to domestic financial development in peripheral Europe before 1914. We quantify a sizable and significant relation between remittances and measures of financial development that is both larger than the contribution of other international capital flows and the best estimates of the same relation today. Given that financial development is regularly included among the conditions for economic growth and catch-up of developing nations, this article adds to our understanding of the multiple impacts of the mass migration phenomenon on the economies of emigration countries. 1. Introduction At the end of the nineteenth century, the majority of European countries formed a periphery of developing nations catching up with the developed core. Like today, the high volatility of foreign capital flows was a factor of instability for the ‘emerging economies’ of eastern and southern Europe and of Scandinavia. But unlike contemporary developing nations, which face restrictive immigration policies, pre-1914 European countries benefited from almost unfettered access to the international labour market. New World countries, which had a huge need for labour, acted as magnets for would-be migrants. As a result, movements of labour played a more significant role than today in terms of international convergence (Taylor and Williamson 2006). Migration flows were also at the origin of large money transfers that emigrants sent to their relatives or brought back with them when returning home. The contemporary and historical literature on remittances emphasizes their contribution to the consumption and investment decisions of families left behind and consequently to the catch-up process (Hatton and Williamson 2005). Some authors focus on the role of remittances as a mechanism for international risk sharing in relation to the well-known 444 European Review of Economic History paradox about consumption co-movements across nations (Backus et al. 1992). Thus, Fenoaltea (1988) argues that Italian remittances helped with financing current account deficits, especially after 1887, when international capital inflows began to decrease. In the same vein, Esteves and KhoudourCastéras (2009) show that remittances reduced the incidence of financial disturbances (sudden stops and current account reversals) among peripheral European countries integrated in the gold standard. This article takes a different perspective on the relevance of remittance flows before World War I by analysing their effects on financial development. Our working concept of financial development follows on the long tradition of identifying it with the change in financial structure, as inferred from consolidated balance sheets (Golsdmith 1969; Rajan and Zingales 2003). Recent literature relates remittances to financial development in developing countries, finding that they are either substitutes (Calderón et al. 2007; Giuliano and Ruiz-Arranz 2009) or complements (Aggarwal et al. 2006; Martínez Pería et al. 2007). Our purpose is to investigate the significance of remittances in promoting late nineteenth-century financial development in eight peripheral countries, with relatively limited access to international lending. Other than sharing the characteristics of emerging economies, these eight countries are singled out in this study because of their relevance in the context of European emigration. On average, they represented around 60 per cent of the total outflow of European migrants between 1880 and 1913 (data from Ferenczi and Willcox 1929). The historical literature provides estimates of remittances for four of these countries: Austria–Hungary, Italy, Portugal and Spain. The first contribution of this article is to estimate remittances for four additional countries (Finland, Greece, Norway and Sweden), based on indirect evidence from the emigration process itself and the economic conditions that emigrants encountered in destination countries. We then investigate the statistical relation between remittance flows and standard measures of the development of the local financial institutions. Our findings imply that there is a complementary relation between remittances and financial development, as the size of remittances has a positive impact on our measures of financial development. This suggests that international migration contributed to the catch-up process before 1914, by means other than income convergence. 2. The interaction between remittances and financial development 2.1. Substitutes or complements? Current discussions on the relation between remittances and financial development are based on the question of whether they are substitutes Remittances, capital flows and financial development 445 or complements. According to the substitutability hypothesis, remittances partially offset the lack of financial development in emigration countries by allowing poor people to invest in high-return projects. On the other hand, the complementarity hypothesis argues that there is a positive interaction between remittances and financial development. High levels of financial development help migrants send more money home and, in turn, a significant inflow of remittances stimulates the interest of financial institutions and public authorities. This brings about higher levels of competition between financial intermediaries, as well as institutional reforms aiming at channelling remittances towards productive investment. The main arguments in favour of the substitutability hypothesis are presented by Giuliano and Ruiz-Arranz (2009), who analyse the respective roles of remittances and the financial sector in promoting economic growth. They show, based on a data set of 73 developing countries over the period 1975–2002, that the impact of remittances on growth is stronger when financial markets are underdeveloped. Remittances are supposed to release credit constraints in countries where credit markets are imperfect. This result is confirmed by Calderón et al. (2007), who find that the effect of remittances on growth is inversely related to financial depth in Latin America. But there is also evidence of complementarity. Mundaca (2005) and Bettin and Zazarro (2008) find that the more developed the financial sector, the higher the impact of remittances on growth. They interpret the results as evidence that financial institutions help channel remittances towards productive investment projects, particularly in the case of small and mediumsized businesses. These studies also find that remittances have a higher impact when used as collateral for loans from financial intermediaries. Most statistics on remittances underestimate the real value of money transfers to developing countries, either because they do not take into account money transfer operators, such as Western Union, or because they exclude informal channels (de Luna Martínez 2005). In this respect, countries with better financial development should receive – or at least measure – more (official) remittances. But beyond the mere accounting aspect, broad and deep financial markets contribute to reducing transfer costs, hence increasing remittance flows, while a stable and reliable banking system leads migrants to remit through formal channels (Aggarwal et al. 2006). By contrast, inefficiencies in the financial sector, expressed as delays in money transfers, high intermediation costs, or unfavourable exchange rates, tend to curb remittance inflows (Ratha 2005). Remittances also play a key role in strengthening financial institutions in developing countries. They contribute to increasing the demand for financial services, not only for deposit accounts, but also, as remittances exceed the immediate needs of families, for savings accounts. Such demand is met by new financial institutions through a double process of deepening and widening; banks and other money transfer operators open more branches 446 European Review of Economic History in migration-intensive areas, and offer more services. This increase in competition for financial services decreases intermediation costs to the benefit of the recipients. The fact that migrants’ families receive stable and significant remittances also facilitates their access to loans, making possible the expansion of the domestic credit market. Aggarwal et al. (2006) use balance of payments data for 99 developing countries over the period 1975–2003 to show that remittances contribute to increasing the ratio of bank credit to the private sector and the share of bank deposits, as a percentage of GDP. In their estimates, an increase of remittances worth 1 per cent of GDP generates a rise in credit of around 0.3 per cent, and between 0.5 and 0.6 per cent in the deposits variable. Martínez Pería et al. (2007) study 25 Latin American and Caribbean countries over the same period and similarly conclude that the impact of remittances is positive, although the effect is smaller than in other developing regions. An explanation is that recurrent crises in Latin America created a climate of distrust in the banking system, such that remitters were less prone to use the financial system than in other regions. Nevertheless, the same authors provide micro-level evidence from 19 household surveys conducted in 11 countries showing that the probability of using financial services, namely bank accounts and credit, is higher among households that receive remittances than in the rest of the population. 2.2. The impact of remittances on pre-1914 European financial development Although there is very little literature on the effects of remittances on the nineteenth-century financial sector, the substantial amount of money sent by migrants to their families raises the question of whether the two were not related, at least in the European periphery. Informal channels were quite common during the nineteenth century. Migrants used to send banknotes or even coins through the ordinary mail (Semmingsen 1978). They also entrusted envelopes with money inside to acquaintances travelling back home, or carried their savings themselves when returning –temporarily or definitively (Douki 2001; Magee and Thompson 2006a). But, as the migration phenomenon spread, remitters required more reliable transfer systems, and official intermediaries blossomed. The Western Union Company, the quintessence of today’s remittance business, began its money transfer activities in 1871. Several ethnic banks also appeared, like the Emigrant Industrial Savings Bank, oriented towards the Irish community in New York (Ó’Gráda 1998) or the Bank of Italy in San Francisco (Mittone 1984). The newly created intermediaries developed links with European financial institutions and extended their activities to the countries of emigration. Remittances, capital flows and financial development 447 In Spain, due to the lack of banks outside Madrid and Barcelona, many mercantile houses began to offer remittance services, by setting up direct relations with trading partners overseas or by acting as local correspondents for national or even foreign banks. With time, these ‘merchant-bankers’ specialized in such operations and progressively turned into banking houses or became integrated into the branch network of larger banks (García López 1992). New banks also appeared and specialized in remittance activities, such as the Banco Hispano Americano and the Crédito Ibero Americano, which opened their doors in 1901 and 1903, respectively.1 In other cases, foreign banks entered the domestic market in order to take advantage of the remittance business, such as the Banco Español del Río de la Plata, an Argentinian bank that opened several branches in Spain at the beginning of the twentieth century. Financial reforms were sometimes encouraged by public authorities. In Italy, the 1901 law on emigration aimed at channelling remittances through official financial institutions to protect migrants and their families against untrustworthy intermediaries, and to use these funds to finance development projects. One significant measure was to expand the post office network in rural areas, so that migrants’ families could have closer access to financial services (Douki 2001). As recipients were able to save part of the additional income, the need for savings accounts rose in proportion. This was encouraged by the strategy of many European migrants to spend some years in the New World accumulating enough money to buy a farm or a small business when returning to their countries of origin (Magee and Thomson 2006b). In Portugal, the surge of new banking institutions was largely related to remittances, but also to so-called ‘Brazilians’, who returned with a large amount of capital (Alves 1993). In Italy too competition between financial institutions was raging, and local operators faced pressures from national banks (Douki 2001). Savings banks adapted to this new clientele by offering attractive interest rates and the number of account owners consequently increased: the amount of postal accounts deposits went up from 323 m lire in 1890 to 2108 in 1913 (+553 per cent in 23 years). During the same period, the share of emigrants’ savings in total postal accounts went from 0.03 to 4.4 per cent (authors’ calculations based on ISTAT 1958). Remittances also helped migrants’ families free themselves from usury, a common practice in rural Europe (Massulo 2001). Remittances gave rise to an unusual availability of capital that contributed to reducing dependency in two ways. First, direct recipients could use this capital surplus to finance their investment projects, without getting into excessive debt. Second, some 1 As underlined by Hatton and Williamson (1994) and Sánchez Alonso (2000), emigration from Spain really only took off at the beginning of the twentieth century. 448 European Review of Economic History people used their new economic situation to lend money with lower interest rates than usurers. The result was a redistribution of economic power that changed local social structures. 3. Sending money home before World War I 3.1. Data Quantitative information on remittances before World War I is fragmented, both in terms of countries and periods. The existence of micro-data, mainly coming from banks’ or post offices’ balance sheets, helps us to understand better the remitting patterns of emigrants in terms of transfer channels and periodicity. Yet the aggregation of micro-data into macro-series faces several pitfalls: – First, many migrants remitted money through informal channels, or brought their savings with them when returning home (Wyman 1993). As today, these invisible transfers are difficult to estimate. – Second, there is no precise information on the number of emigrants who sent money home and for how long.2 – Third, not all migrants followed the same pattern when transferring money, which complicates the task of estimating the average amount of remittances by country. This depended, among other factors, on the country where migrants went, their professional activities, marital status and on who travelled with them. In addition, the average amount of remittances differed from one country of origin to another.3 Despite these difficulties, several authors provide estimates for some European countries (Austria–Hungary, Italy, Portugal, Spain and the UK) using migration figures and contemporary information on average remittances sent by emigrants (see Appendix A). These studies vary in the amount of direct information extracted from archival sources that they bring to bear on the aggregation problems mentioned above.4 Nevertheless, the 2 3 4 Studies in today’s developing countries show that remittances decrease proportionally to the length of immigrants’ stay. Funkhouser (1995) concludes that remittances between the United States and Nicaragua decrease by three dollars for every month spent in the US. DeSipio (2002) estimates that a 1% increase in time spent by Mexicans in the United States lowers the probability of transferring money home by 2%. Filipski and Taylor (2010) show that the annual rate of decay of remittances to Mexico is about 3.5%. Durand et al. (1996) argue that not only the wages and job situation of migrants, but also their age, level of education, marital status and the number of dependents at home, influence the amount of remittances. De la Brière et al. (2002), based on the Dominican case, find that the magnitude of remittances also depends on migrants’ destination, gender and household composition. To our knowledge, Magee’s (2006a and b) work on remittances to the UK is the most detailed exercise of aggregation of remittances estimates from archival material. Remittances, capital flows and financial development 449 partly unobservable nature of the transactions we try to measure implies that all estimates of remittances are really just approximations to the actual flows, even today (de Luna Martínez 2005). Moreover, for other countries there is very little available information and no published estimates. Fully aware of the pitfalls of such an exercise, we estimate new remittance series for four countries (Finland, Greece, Sweden and Norway), by using all available direct information and following, where possible, the methods used by our predecessors. We can break down this exercise in two steps: first, the estimation of the stock of emigrants abroad likely to remit to country i in year t (Mit ); second, the calculation of the average amount of remittances sent by each emigrant (remit ). The total amount of remittances (remit ) is then given by: remit = Mit × remit The stock of emigrants likely to remit money is based on cumulated past migrant inflows. We are aware that not all migrants sent money home, that a certain proportion of them came back after a few years or even months, and that the propensity to transfer remittances tended to decrease with the passing of time. In order to take heed of these facts we first assume that only male migrants between 14 and 44 years old sent remittances. In general, the youngest migrants came with their parents, while the oldest travelled with their children or joined them later thanks to pre-paid tickets (Jerome 1926). Most women who migrated were married or went to the New World to marry settled immigrants. Men were therefore mostly in charge of those left behind.5 We then consider, following Morys (2005), Prados de la Escosura (2006) and Simon (1960), that most migrants sent money home only during the first five years of their stay. After that, they had either returned home or decided to settle permanently. We also take into consideration short-term migration by deducting from the stock of remitters the number of emigrants who had returned to their home countries in previous years. The number of remitters is therefore defined as follows: 4 i i i i μit−n Eit−n Mt = μt Et + (1 − ρ ) n=1 where Eit is the annual number of emigrants from country i in year t, μit is the share of male migrants between 14 and 44 years old, and ρ i the rate of return to country i.6 5 6 The average share of male migrants between 14 and 44 years old, in the period 1899–1913, was 53% for Norway and Sweden, 57% for Finland, and 89% for Greece (authors’ calculations based on Ferenczi and Willcox 1929). According to the US Immigration Commission (1911, vol. 1, p. 182), the ratio of returnees to immigrants admitted into the United States between 1908 and 1910 was 14% for Norwegians and Swedes, 17% for Finns and 25% for Greeks. 450 European Review of Economic History Then, we calculate the annual level of remittances per remitter from contemporary sources. Since the United States was by far the main destination for the nationals of Greece, Finland, Norway and Sweden (around 95 per cent of Scandinavian emigrants went to the US before World War I), we concentrate on these four countries. We base calculations on the figures given by different sources to set the total amount of remittances in one or more reference years (see Appendix A). We then use our estimate of the annual number of remitters to calculate the average amount of remittances in each country. We extrapolate these per capita values to other years by calculating an index of the expected nominal wages of immigrants from country i in the US (wti ): us wti = 1 − uit wtus · e t i where, uit is the unemployment rate in the US, wtus is the nominal wage index us in the US, and e t i is the exchange rate between the dollar and each domestic currency (see Appendix A). As a result, remit = remiref i wref · wti i where remiref and wref are, respectively, the average amount of remittances to country i and the expected nominal wage index of immigrants in the US in the reference years. In using a single national wage series for the US, we are abstracting from several sources of differentiation across immigrants, according to their education, occupation, country of origin and settlement patterns in the US (Dunlevy and Saba 1992). Although Hatton (2000) and Hatton and Williamson (2005) provide information on the difference in productivity between native and foreign-born workers in the US, such a measure is only available for 1909 and therefore cannot be used.7 As for regional differences, previous research concluded that a wellintegrated labour market was already operating by 1880 in the north-east and north-central regions, which absorbed the vast majority of Scandinavian and Greek migrants to the US (Rosenbloom 1996). Since our estimates of remittances depend on the changes in the wage index, differences in wage levels across regions are less of a concern. 7 In 1909, earnings in industry in the US after 20 years were, respectively, 4.8% and 5.5% higher for Finnish and Scandinavian immigrants than for the native-born workers. By contrast, Greek immigrants earned 7.5% less than native workers (Hatton 2000). Remittances, capital flows and financial development 451 Finally, the total amount of remittances in year t is estimated as: 4 remiref i i i i i i remt = μt Et + (1 − ρ ) μt−n Et−n × · wti i wref n=1 The complete list of remittances series, together with our reconstruction of the stocks of remitters is available from Appendix B. It should be noted that the number of remitters is different from the stock of migrants in the US, as estimated by Hatton (1995). If we follow his method to interpolate foreignborn populations between census years, we conclude that, on average, 12 per cent of Norwegians and Swedes living in the US remitted money home, compared to 33 per cent of Finns and 59 per cent of Greeks.8 By using the 1909 survey of immigrant workers conducted by the US Immigration Commission (1911), we can also estimate the percentage of annual income sent by migrants to their home countries. The figures are: 27 per cent for Swedes, 23 per cent for Greeks, 22 per cent for Norwegians and only 13 per cent for Finns.9 3.2. The stylized facts of pre-1914 remittances Table 1 contains the descriptive statistics of remittances as a share of GDP between 1870 and 1913 for, respectively, four southern European countries (Greece, Italy, Portugal and Spain) and three Scandinavian countries (Finland, Norway and Sweden) plus Austria–Hungary. In the former group of countries, in particular Greece, Portugal and Italy, the weight of remittances grew to very significant levels. By contrast, remittances had a lower contribution in the second group of countries, never reaching 3.5 per cent of GDP in any year. This happens to be the average estimate of contemporary remittances as a fraction of recipient nations’ GDP in 2006 (IFAD 2007). 8 9 These proportions are in direct relation with what we know about the different composition of migrant flows, namely the Scandinavian pattern of emigration by complete families, contrasted with the predominance of males and the high rates of temporary migration among southern European emigrants. According to the data compiled in Ferenczi and Wilcox (1929), only 6% of Greek emigrants to the US between 1899 and 1913 were women, while the corresponding figures were 36% for Finland and 38% for the Scandinavians. The values are relative to the annual income of male workers in manufacturing and industry aged 18 and above. By way of comparison, Magee and Thompson (2006a) estimate that the proportion of average remitter’s income sent as remittances from the US to the UK was between 11.7 and 16% in 1905–9, and between 13.7 and 18.7% in 1910–13. Castillo and Orozco (2008), based on interviews with immigrants in the US from eight Latin American countries, argue that today’s remittances represent around 15% of migrants’ income. 452 European Review of Economic History Table 1. Summary statistics of remittances Country Greece (1876–1913) Italy (1876–1913) Portugal (1870–1913) Spain (1870–1913) Average 0.958 2.662 2.698 1.021 Min 0.005 0.260 1.138 0.268 Max 5.084 5.823 7.071 3.200 Coef. of var. 1.565 0.617 0.423 0.808 Austria–Hungary (1880–1913) Finland (1886–1913) Norway (1870–1913) Sweden (1870–1913) 0.743 1.366 1.253 1.010 0.089 0.325 0.198 0.094 2.212 2.514 3.151 2.098 0.967 0.447 0.594 0.522 Note: Values are expressed as a share of GDP. Source: See text and Appendix A. The coefficient of variation shows that remittances were more stable in Scandinavia and Portugal than in other countries. Nonetheless, remittances were subject to fluctuations, mainly driven by the changes in the stock of remitters. For most countries this measure explains all the variation in total remittances or even over-explains it.10 The exceptions are Norway and Spain, where wage movements explain about 12 per cent of the variation in remittances, and especially Portugal, whose remittance flows were dominated in this period by the swings in the Brazilian exchange rate. This dependence of remittances on migratory flows implies that the former were also generally related to the economic activity in immigration countries, as potential emigrants reacted to the conditions in the labour market in their countries of sojourn. For instance, the US downturn of 1908 brought about a strong increase in unemployment that negatively affected remittances to Europe: between 1907 and 1909, remittances dropped by 11 per cent to Italy, 25 per cent to Sweden, 26 per cent to Norway and 30 per cent to Finland. Similarly, the decrease in remittances to Portugal at the turn of the century (−65 per cent between 1898 and 1902) was largely due to the economic and political problems in Brazil. Remittances also tended to exhibit a countercyclical role in European economies, which is suggestive of an international risk-sharing motive. A drop in domestic economic activity was sometimes accompanied by an increase in remittances, while faster economic growth at home could be followed by a reduction in flows – of emigrants, and remittances. Thus, the strong increase in GDP in Finland in 1897–8 (+10.4 and +10.1 per cent) came with a drop in remittances of 36 per cent between 1896 and 1898. By contrast, the economic recession of 1901–2 (−1.3 in 1901 and −2.5 per cent 10 The latter happens mainly in cases when adverse exchange rate changes contributed negatively to the flow of remittances. We decomposed the contribution of the variables in the estimation formula for Remt (stock of migrants, wage levels and exchange rates) through analysis of covariance. Remittances, capital flows and financial development 453 in 1902) was followed by an increase in remittances of 98 per cent between 1900 and 1902 (+58 per cent between 1901 and 1902). Likewise, after the depression of the Norwegian economy in 1878 (−11.4 per cent) and 1879 (−6.2 per cent), remittances doubled (1878–80), while the period of economic growth during the second half of the 1890s brought about a significant decrease in remittances. A similar pattern is also manifest in Spain, where the strong economic growth of 1877 (+10.3 per cent) entailed a drop in remittances by 19 per cent. By contrast, the crises of 1889 (−8.2 per cent) and 1910 (−4.9 per cent) were offset by an increase in remittances by 42 and 18 per cent, respectively.11 4. Empirical model We will approach our empirical question, that is, the impact of remittances on pre-1914 European financial development, by estimating variants of the following model: Fi ,t = β1 Remi ,t−1 + β2 Xi ,t−1 + αi + ϕt + εi ,t in which Fi,t stands for a measure of financial development of country i in year t, Remi,t is the amount of remittances received from abroad (normalized by GDP), Xi,t is a vector of controls, and α i and ϕ t are country and time effects, respectively. We lag all independent variables to minimize endogeneity concerns, although we will tackle this problem more fully below. In computing financial development at a macro level, we followed two common measures in the literature on financial development: the ratio between narrow money (M1) and GDP and the ratio between total deposits in the banking system and GDP (King and Levine 1993; Rajan and Zingales 2003). By using measures reflecting the size of the liabilities of the consolidated banking system, we implicitly take the view that banks were the main source of financial development in the eight countries in our sample. This is warranted by the traditional contrast in the literature between the bank-based model of financial development, prevalent on the European ‘Continent’, and the market-based ‘Anglo-Saxon’ financial system (Gerschenkron 1962; Goldsmith 1969). To be sure, recent literature has questioned this simple division of financial systems (Fohlin 2007), but data limitations prevented us from exploring the development of securities markets in the countries included in our sample.12 Similarly, we lack data on 11 12 It would be interesting to verify whether the renowned paradox about the excessively low correction of consumption across nations (Backus et al. 1992) extends to the pre-1914 period and, in particular, whether remittances increased the co-movement of consumption levels. That is, however, beyond the scope of this article. Rajan and Zingales’s (2003) database, for instance, although covering measures of stock market development, only starts in 1913. 454 European Review of Economic History Table 2. Summary statistics of financial development (M1) Country Greece (1876–1913) Italy (1876–1913) Portugal (1870–1913) Spain (1870–1913) Average 31.731 21.279 19.534 25.359 Min 17.829 16.182 16.153 20.301 Max 45.258 25.968 23.733 35.729 Coef. of var. 0.178 0.118 0.096 0.141 Austria–Hungary (1880–1913) Finland (1886–1913) Norway (1870–1913) Sweden (1870–1913) 12.603 31.731 7.184 NA 10.321 17.829 5.821 NA 16.965 45.258 8.243 NA 0.099 0.178 0.073 NA Note: Values are expressed as a share of GDP. Source: See Appendix A. Table 3. Summary statistics of financial development (deposits) Country Greece (1876–1913) Italy (1876–1913) Portugal (1870–1913) Spain (1870–1913) Average 17.440 38.171 2.821 3.350 Min 6.663 27.776 1.658 0.453 Max 51.161 48.406 5.388 7.094 Coef. of var. 0.702 0.161 0.329 0.550 Austria–Hungary (1880–1913) Finland (1886–1913) Norway (1870–1913) Sweden (1870–1913) 76.063 33.986 44.139 44.735 37.631 7.033 22.464 5.975 115.918 70.373 69.624 70.885 0.320 0.602 0.336 0.425 Note: Values are expressed as a share of GDP. Source: See Appendix A. banking assets (credit) for all but two of the countries. Nevertheless, there is considerable variation in time and, especially, across countries in the two variables we use, of which summary statistics by country are available in Tables 2 and 3. The sources for these and all other variables can be found in Appendix A. Both indicators aim at measuring the penetration of financial services in the economy. Ideally, we would like to further disaggregate our results by the type of financial instruments available to potential remitters, e.g. savings vs demand or time deposits. For some countries we could separate between types of banking institutions (deposits in commercial and savings banks), but not for others.13 As a result, we use here an aggregate measure of total deposits – in commercial and savings banks – as a proxy for financial development. As mentioned, we normalize our principal right-hand side variable of interest, the level of remittances (as estimated in Section 3), by recipient nations’ GDP. In our base model, we consider three groups of controls. First, we control for country size and economic development, the former 13 See Appendix A for details. Remittances, capital flows and financial development 455 proxied by the natural log of GDP expressed in pounds sterling, and the latter by per capita GDP, also in sterling. Both variables are included to capture the presumption that the development of financial services has fixed costs, which are more easily defrayed in larger and/or richer nations. The level of per capita GDP may also perhaps account for a time-varying component of domestic institutional quality (not captured by country-fixed effects). We will return to this question in more detail later. A second group of variables controls for the degrees of trade and financial openness. Recent literature has emphasized the positive effects of openness on the development of local financial sectors that can tap into larger pools of savings and acquire superior technology and know-how via FDI (Chinn and Ito 2002; Errunza 2001; Levine 2001). We measure trade openness as the export share of GDP and financial openness by the trade account, also normalized by the recipient country’s GDP.14 Finally, we include a third group of variables that account for the well-known negative link between monetary instability (domestic and external) and financial development (Boyd et al. 2001). Participation in the gold standard and inflation rates are the indicators used for this purpose (Battilossi 2006; Carosso and Sylla 1991). The summary statistics of the covariates are reported in Table 4. As we do not have information on all variables for all countries over the whole period, our estimation will be based on unbalanced panels.15 The first set of results for this model can be read from Table 5. The estimation method is pooled OLS with robust standard errors. We also adjusted the model using panel techniques (within estimators) but the point estimates (and significance levels) of the coefficients were virtually identical to the pooled model because the panel variance component was consistently insignificant. The control variables generally behave as expected. Richer nations exhibit higher levels of financial development. The size of the economy also has the expected positive impact, except when we measure financial development by narrow money, which, however, is probably not the best proxy, as it excludes some of the sources of longer-term financing by banks (time and savings accounts). Inflation is detrimental to financial development, but loses significance once we introduce country and time effects. Monetary stability, proxied by the participation in the gold standard, does have the predicted (and sometimes very strong) positive effect on financial development. Openness also shows up with the expected sign, both when measured by 14 15 Even if this is not the best measure of financial openness, we could not find reliable series for the capital account of the majority of countries included in our sample. We use trade instead of current account to avoid double counting remittances in the empirical specification. The results based on a smaller, but balanced sample (1890–1913) are virtually identical to those reported here. 456 European Review of Economic History Table 4. Summary statistics of covariates and instruments Variable M1/GDP Deposits/GDP Log (GDP) GDP per cap. Inflation Gold standard Exports/GDP Trade account/GDP Polity Duration Executive openness Exec. competitiveness Exec. constraints Participation competitiveness Creditors’ rights N 293 321 336 336 352 352 342 342 352 352 352 352 352 352 Average 19.7173 30.9786 4.7838 21.9627 0.3523 0.5170 13.5013 −3.9483 −1.1136 36.8296 2.4489 1.3977 4.6364 2.7472 Max 45.2584 115.9184 7.8325 88.0675 31.9444 1.0000 26.7616 5.5687 10.0000 102.0000 4.0000 3.0000 7.0000 5.0000 Min 5.8209 0.4533 2.1801 4.7533 −95.5124 0.0000 3.017241 −18.2213 −10.0000 0.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 0.0000 St. Dev. 8.4253 26.9532 1.4053 14.9139 7.6662 0.5004 5.7616 4.2702 6.2282 27.8168 0.9944 0.7741 2.1024 1.3102 352 1.5000 2.0000 1.0000 0.5007 Exchange rates Distance cost 270 352 1.0118 70.8182 2.2561 117 0.2138 45 0.2161 19.3987 Notes: Exchange rates are a weighted index of exchange rates of destination currencies against sterling, used as instrument (base 1913 = 1). The distance cost is Isserlis’s (1938) index of tramp shipping freight, also used as instrument (base 1869 = 100). export intensity and the trade account. The estimated effect is again weaker in specifications that use M1 as dependent variable. The size of remittances has a clear impact on financial development with some revealing patterns. The size of the coefficient is much larger when using total deposits as the left-hand side variable than M1. This implies that emigrant money was channelled into the financial sector primarily through longer-maturity accounts. Interestingly, the size of the coefficient of remittances is consistently larger than the estimated impact of aggregate capital flows, as measured by the trade account balance. Although it is difficult to distinguish between remittances (an item of the current account) and the items of the financial account, the smaller coefficient of the latter implies that other capital inflows (portfolio or FDI) contributed less to the development of the domestic financial sector than remittances. These estimates are also larger than the evidence on contemporary trends. Indeed, we estimate a marginal effect of the ratio deposits/GDP to remittances of about 2.4 to 2.7, while Aggarwal et al. (2006), using a sample of 99 developing nations between 1975 and 2003, find an effect of only 0.5 to 0.6. We now consider two variations on this model. The first one explores the possibility that the effect of remittances on financial development may be non-linear. Table 6 re-estimates the full model with country and time effects for two alternative non-linear specifications. In columns (1)–(2) we Table 5. Results (base model) M1/GDP Log (GDP) GDP per capita Inflation Gold standard Exports/GDP Trade account Remittances Country FE Year FE N R2 (1) 23.8927∗∗∗ (2.5735) −0.1219 (0.5325) −0.0116 (0.0573) 0.0474 (0.0732) −8.9413∗∗∗ (1.1545) 0.0764 (0.0946) 0.173 (0.2111) 0.7002 (0.4395) No No 264 0.278 (2) 39.2893∗∗∗ (11.0260) −6.6105∗∗∗ (2.2984) 0.4492∗∗∗ (0.0972) 0.0041 (0.0296) 0.8624 (0.7194) 0.2591∗ (0.1505) −0.0051 (0.1240) 0.4400∗∗ (0.1806) Yes No 264 0.874 (3) 46.8647∗∗∗ (12.7455) −8.5814∗∗∗ (2.5263) 0.4616∗∗∗ (0.1180) −0.0072 (0.0406) 1.6040∗∗ (0.7766) 0.2201 (0.1804) 0.0256 (0.1523) 0.1106 (0.2120) Yes Yes 264 0.89 (4) −82.1432∗∗∗ (4.1821) 6.6122∗∗∗ (0.9084) 1.1262∗∗∗ (0.0627) −0.2457∗∗ (0.1047) 10.2866∗∗∗ (1.4834) 3.2301∗∗∗ (0.1125) −1.1841∗∗∗ (0.1935) 2.6670∗∗∗ (0.4669) No No 293 0.88 Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses. ∗∗∗ indicates significance at 1%, ∗∗ at 5%, ∗ at 10%. (5) −115.1161∗∗∗ (11.3249) 18.6454∗∗∗ (2.3118) 0.6983∗∗∗ (0.1317) −0.1133∗∗ (0.0557) 8.3790∗∗∗ (1.4210) 0.7597∗∗∗ (0.1515) −0.1634 (0.1452) 2.6264∗∗∗ (0.3947) (6) −134.9039∗∗∗ (17.1148) 21.0797∗∗∗ (3.0639) 0.8518∗∗∗ (0.1417) −0.0736 (0.0638) 10.0781∗∗∗ (1.4088) 0.9890∗∗∗ (0.1721) −0.3552∗∗ (0.1525) 2.4227∗∗∗ (0.3740) Yes No 293 0.947 Yes Yes 293 0.967 Remittances, capital flows and financial development Dependent Constant Deposits/GDP 457 458 European Review of Economic History Table 6. Results (nonlinearities) Dependent Constant Log (GDP) GDP per capita Inflation Gold standard Exports/GDP Trade account Remittances Remitt∗ year>1887 Remittances2 Country FE Year FE N R2 M1 (1) 52.1132∗∗∗ (12.3141) −9.2408∗∗∗ (2.4345) 0.4560∗∗∗ (0.1184) −0.0092 (0.0387) 2.3869∗∗ (0.9603) 0.2362 (0.1776) 0.0825 (0.1536) −1.0287∗ (0.6121) 1.1115∗ (0.5902) Yes Yes 264 0.892 Deposits (2) −163.3002∗∗∗ (17.6481) 24.9866∗∗∗ (3.0919) 0.8671∗∗∗ (0.1433) −0.0752 (0.0611) 5.5670∗∗∗ (1.5996) 0.8911∗∗∗ (0.1781) −0.6273∗∗∗ (0.1533) 8.6322∗∗∗ (0.9316) −6.1158∗∗∗ (0.8414) Yes Yes 293 0.971 M1 (3) 44.3363∗∗∗ (12.3255) −8.0267∗∗∗ (2.4404) 0.4295∗∗∗ (0.1141) 0.0046 (0.0390) 1.0281 (0.7485) 0.2166 (0.1674) −0.0843 (0.1493) 2.3910∗∗∗ (0.6808) Deposits (4) −173.979∗∗∗ −19.5141 26.2168∗∗∗ −3.2103 0.7790∗∗∗ −0.1305 −0.0381 −0.0517 10.4932∗∗∗ −1.3542 1.0605∗∗∗ −0.163 −0.6081∗∗∗ −0.1573 5.9437∗∗∗ −1.1139 −0.3859∗∗∗ −0.1209 −0.9295∗∗∗ −0.2224 Yes Yes 264 0.898 Yes Yes 293 0.971 Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses. ∗∗∗ indicates significance at 1%, ∗∗ at 5%, ∗ at 10%. introduced an interaction term for the level of remittances to mark the period when this level rose above 1 per cent of GDP in our sample of countries (1888 onwards). Some evidence of threshold effects for the impact of remittances is found in contemporary and historical literature (Bugamelli and Paternò 2006; Esteves and Khoudour-Castéras 2009). In columns (3)–(4) we simply added a quadratic remittances term. Both variants testify to substantial nonlinearities whereby the impact of remittances on financial development abated over time or as the country became richer. Irrespective of the choice of dependent variable (M1 or total deposits), the results in columns (3) and (4) imply a maximum impact of remittances on financial development when they are in the proximity of 3 per cent of GDP. The results for the remaining controls are not qualitatively changed. The second variation extends the base model by directly including indicators of local institutional quality. In so doing we are once more limited by the availability of data, in this case, by the relative difficulty in finding historical measures of the quality of economic institutions. Consequently, the Remittances, capital flows and financial development 459 Table 7. Results (political and economic institutions) Dependent Constant Log (GDP) GDP per capita Inflation Gold standard Exports/GDP Trade account Remittances Polity Durable Dur. ∗ exec. cons. Exec. comp. Exec. open. Exec. const. Part. comp. M1 (1) 61.1318∗∗∗ (13.4982) −9.5884∗∗∗ (2.6292) 0.3970∗∗∗ (0.1337) −0.0047 (0.0391) 1.5680∗∗ (0.7108) 0.3354∗ (0.1767) −0.1286 (0.1624) −0.2378 (0.2466) 0.6128 (0.4551) 0.0427 (0.0332) 0.0147∗∗ (0.0071) −6.5807∗∗ (2.7546) 5.3165∗∗∗ (1.5956) −1.3161∗∗ (0.5440) −1.6919∗∗ (0.7216) Deposits (2) −99.5434∗∗∗ (17.4657) 9.9022∗∗∗ (3.1688) 0.7545∗∗∗ (0.1527) −0.0365 (0.0678) 10.1903∗∗∗ (1.3073) 1.0812∗∗∗ (0.1690) −0.6123∗∗∗ (0.1549) 1.9483∗∗∗ (0.3805) −2.9176∗∗∗ (0.7349) −0.0773∗ (0.0445) 0.0254∗ (0.0144) 9.7964∗∗ (3.7760) 2.6862 (1.6898) 1.2175 (0.8322) 3.8436∗∗∗ (0.9865) Cred. rights Country FE Year FE N R2 Yes Yes 264 0.909 Yes Yes 293 0.975 M1 (3) 36.5829∗∗∗ (7.0942) −8.5814∗∗∗ (2.5263) 0.4616∗∗∗ (0.1180) −0.0072 (0.0406) 1.6040∗∗ (0.7766) 0.2201 (0.1804) 0.0256 (0.1523) 0.1106 (0.2120) Deposits (4) −41.6731∗∗∗ (9.0367) 21.0797∗∗∗ (3.0639) 0.8518∗∗∗ (0.1417) −0.0736 (0.0638) 10.0781∗∗∗ (1.4088) 0.9890∗∗∗ (0.1721) −0.3552∗∗ (0.1525) 2.4227∗∗∗ (0.3740) 5.1409 (4.0683) −46.6154∗∗∗ (6.655) Yes Yes 264 0.89 Yes Yes 293 0.967 Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses. ∗∗∗ indicates significance at 1%, ∗∗ at 5%, ∗ at 10%. bulk of variables added to the models of columns (1)–(2) in Table 7 refer to political institutions. We extracted six variables from the Polity IV database: the polity democracy score; the durability of political regimes (in years since last change); three scores referring to the executive power – constraints (Exec. const.) on the exercise of this power, competitiveness (Exec. comp.) and openness of nomination (Exec. open.); and a final score for the degree of 460 European Review of Economic History competitiveness in political participation (Part. comp.). One would expect a positive association between the five scores and measures of financial development, along the lines of the political economy of financial regimes (Haber et al. 2003). Because the relation between tenure and institutional quality is unclear, we also interacted the duration of the political regimes with the measure of executive constraints. In Table 7, the coefficient of remittances is still strongly significant and has a size very similar to Table 5. The political markers generally have correct signs. Stability of political regimes also shows up as having a negative impact on its own on financial development. However, when interacted with the index of constraints on the executive it is marginally positive, which suggests that except with the worst possible political institutions, the tenure of political regimes did affect the levels of financial development.16 The only counterintuitive results are those of the model for M1, which reinforces our doubts about the usefulness of this variable as an indicator of financial development. In the last two columns we experimented with a model controlling for the quality of economic institutions. Since we do not have historical measures, we included a popular contemporary measure of economic institutions – the index of creditors’ rights compiled by Djankov et al. (2006). Given that all nations in our sample come from a civil law tradition, we cannot investigate the related hypothesis about the persistence of ‘legal origins’ (La Porta et al. 1997). Nonetheless, if we are to interpret the results of the coefficient on creditors’ rights based on information collected almost a century after our sample period, we need to assume a remarkable degree of persistence in the quality of legal orderings dealing with economic activity. Since this is not the topic of this article, we only notice the very large estimates for this coefficient, which, however, do not affect the direct impact of remittances on financial development. The sign of the coefficient on contemporary creditors’ rights is also counterintuitive in the case of the regression for deposits. 4.1. Outliers and endogeneity There are two main concerns to address in running our model. First, with a small sample in the cross-section dimension we need to worry about the possibility that the results are driven by outlier observations. We took this into consideration by using Li’s (1985) robust estimation method. The results (unreported here) are virtually similar to the base estimates of Table 5. We 16 Because tenure and constraints on the executive are interacted, the interpretation of the coefficient on tenure is conditional on a value of zero for the constraints on the executive (the worst possible in the Polity IV database). Remittances, capital flows and financial development 461 also tried excluding countries (one at a time), without affecting the tenor of the results A more significant concern has to do with the potential for reverse causality and measurement error. Better domestic financial institutions might actually attract more remittances. As already mentioned, many specialized banks were created in this period to attract or improve the efficiency in money transfer. Measurement error could have been introduced by the method used to estimate four of the remittances series, as described in Section 3. It can also follow from the hypothesized reverse causality, as it is not clear whether better financial institutions actually increased the volume of remittances or just diverted a greater share from informal conduits (hard to estimate accurately) to formal and more quantifiable channels. We take heed of these joint concerns through two methods. We initially lag all independent variables by five years, hoping that the passage of time allows us to identify the correct direction of causality. Because the relation between independent and dependent variables may act with some lag, we confirm our results by using instrumental variable estimation. In this specification, remittances are instrumented with measures of economic opportunities in the countries of destination and a proxy for the costs of emigration. The first instrument is an index of the exchange rate of the recipient countries’ currencies against sterling. The rationale for this variable is that emigrants sometimes postponed sending money when the currency of their country of adoption depreciated significantly – in expectation of a future recovery (Esteves and Khoudour-Castéras 2009). In a world increasingly dominated by the gold standard (a regime with meanreverting exchange rates), such expectations were probably rational in the context of an inter-temporal decision-making process. As a matter of fact, Figure 1 suggests a strong relation between exchange rate movements and remittance flows. We weight the currencies comprised in this index by the share of the main destination countries in each nation’s emigration flows, as gathered by Ferenczi and Wilcox (1929). The second instrument is a measure of the cost of distance, namely an index of tramp shipping freights compiled by Isserlis (1938). As imperfect a proxy of the costs of transatlantic migration as this may be, it has a strong and negative relation with remittances (Figure 2). Table 8 reports the results for this model adding five lines – for R2 of the first stage regression, Hansen’s J statistic of overidentification, Anderson’s canonical correlation statistic (relevance of instruments), and for the Cragg–Donald test of weak instruments. Our instruments pass the tests of exogeneity, relevance and weak instruments.17 Both identification methodologies sustain the positive and significant impact of remittances on measures of financial development, with the 17 We use Stock and Yogo’s (2002) critical levels for the Cragg–Donald F statistic. 0 2 Remittances (%GDP) 4 6 8 European Review of Economic History 0 .5 1 1.5 2 2.5 Exchange Rate Index (1=1913) Figure 1. Remittances (share of GDP) and weighted exchange rate indices, 1870–1913 .5 1 1.5 2 2.5 Sources: See text and Appendix A. Average Remittances (%GDP) 462 40 Figure 2. 60 80 Freight Index (100=1869) 100 120 Remittances (share of GDP) and freight index, 1870–1913 Sources: See text and Appendix A. For each year we plot the average remittance level in the eight countries of the sample. Remittances, capital flows and financial development 463 Table 8. Results (causality) Five-year lags Identification Dependent Constant Log (GDP) GDP per capita Inflation Gold standard Exports/GDP Cur. account Remittances Country FE Year FE N R2 F stat (1st stage) Hansen J stat p-value Anderson can. corr. stat Cragg-Donald F stat M1 (1) 46.2105∗∗∗ (16.8825) −8.3984∗∗ (3.3578) 0.5750∗∗∗ (0.1445) −0.0035 (0.0372) 2.0194∗∗∗ (0.6047) 0.102 (0.1436) 0.1919 (0.1376) −0.0366 −0.3067 Yes Yes 233 0.897 Instrumental variables Deposits (2) −85.1102∗∗∗ (21.1743) 18.5932∗∗∗ (4.3388) 0.5888∗∗ (0.2374) −0.0925 (0.0719) 11.6708∗∗∗ (1.3715) 0.0405 (0.2167) −0.1022 (0.1715) 2.8373∗∗∗ −0.6117 M1 (3) 56.7873∗∗∗ (14.2696) −9.2218∗∗∗ (2.4093) 0.4615∗∗∗ (0.1002) −0.0116 (0.0409) 2.6650∗∗∗ (0.7917) 0.2299 (0.1896) −0.0529 (0.1679) 0.7010∗ −0.3873 Deposits (4) −159.7375∗∗∗ (17.9422) 22.4710∗∗∗ (2.8483) 0.8902∗∗∗ (0.1331) −0.1373∗∗ (0.0560) 8.7826∗∗∗ (1.4991) 0.9186∗∗∗ (0.1796) −0.2531 (0.1658) 3.1476∗∗∗ −0.647 Yes Yes 258 0.97 Yes Yes 229 0.89 16.368 1.069 0.301 112.642∗∗∗ Yes Yes 253 0.968 18.851 1.815 0.178 120.834∗∗∗ 57.822∗∗ 62.752∗∗ Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses. ∗∗∗ indicates significance at 1%, ∗∗ at 5%, ∗ at 10%. coefficients rising in value and significance relative to the base model. Table 9 details the first stage results of the IV estimation, which confirm the strong relation between the remittance level and our instruments. Furthermore, the fact that the IV estimate of the remittances effect is larger than the OLS also provides some evidence in favour of the substitution hypothesis between remittances and local financial development. According to these results, the real causal effect of remittances on financial development is underestimated by OLS due to the negative partial reverse effect of financial and economic development on the flow of remittances. In any case, the complementarity between remittance flows and local financial development clearly outweighs the substitution effect. 464 European Review of Economic History Table 9. First stage results of IV estimation Dependent Constant Log (GDP) GDP per capita Inflation Gold standard Exports/GDP Trade account Exchange rates Distance cost N R2 M1 (1) −6.7268∗ (3.8822) 1.4178∗∗∗ (0.4735) −0.0541∗∗∗ (0.0166) −0.0054 (0.0099) 1.2140∗∗∗ (0.1911) −0.039 (0.0271) 0.0566∗∗ (0.0234) 2.7482∗∗∗ (0.4632) −0.0361∗∗∗ −0.0133 229 0.775 Deposits (2) −2.1607 (3.5648) 0.7869∗ (0.4592) −0.0597∗∗∗ (0.0184) −0.004 (0.0090) 1.3587∗∗∗ (0.1703) −0.00004 (0.0257) 0.0308 (0.0201) 2.6149∗∗∗ (0.4841) −0.0363∗∗∗ −0.0106 253 0.786 Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses. ∗∗∗ indicates significance at 1%, ∗∗ at 5%, ∗ at 10%. Exchange rates are a weighted index of exchange rates of destination currencies against sterling, used as instrument (base 1913 = 1). The distance cost is Isserlis’s (1938) index of tramp shipping freight (base 1869 = 100). 5. Conclusion The evidence in this article furthers our understanding of the economic role of remittances during the age of mass migration. Other than the effects on the demographic composition of the labour force, wage convergence, consumption and savings patterns, and financial stability, we confirm the positive influence of remittances on domestic financial development. The more-than-proportional estimate of their impact on measures of the penetration of financial services also underscores the relative size of this impact, as compared with the (less-than-proportional) effect from other foreign financial flows. This result is remarkably stable across alternative modelling scenarios and when controlling for potential endogeneity and measurement error in our estimates of aggregate remittances. Our measured results are also larger than the best estimates for the contemporary effect of remittances. The marginal effect of the ratio deposits/GDP hovers between 2 and 3 in our sample, compared to 0.5/0.6 in Aggarwal et al. (2006), despite the fact that the ‘emerging economies’ of the nineteenth century started the build-up of their financial sectors from levels Remittances, capital flows and financial development 465 of development similar to present-day large recipients of remittances.18 Part of the difference may be due to sample composition effects, as the recent study includes emerging economies but also less-developed nations that have had a harder time at building up their financial sectors and are less open to foreign capital. But it is likely that the potential for positive spillovers is limited today by restrictive immigration policies, which pre-1914 peripheral European nations (unlike Asian countries) were relatively spared. Our findings suggest that public authorities in today’s developing countries should try to maximize the impact of remittances by adopting policies aiming at promoting financial democracy, that is, policies that facilitate the access to bank services, provide information about the remittance market, and ensure greater transparency in the financial system (Orozco and Fedewa 2006; Terry and Wilson 2005). Insofar as financial development has positive repercussions in terms of economic growth, such policies should also contribute to accelerating the catch-up process of emigration countries. Acknowledgements The opinions expressed and arguments employed in this article are the sole responsibility of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the OECD or of the governments of its member countries. The authors would like to thank the editors, two anonymous referees, and the participants at the 24th Annual Congress of the European Economic Association, Barcelona, the 8th Conference of the European Historical Economics Society, Geneva, the 58th Meeting of the French Association of Economic Sciences (AFSE), Nanterre, and at seminars in the Universities of Geneva and Lille for helpful comments. The authors are also grateful to Agnès Bénassy-Quéré, Martine Carré-Tallon, Marc Flandreau, Olena Havrylchyk and Marc Weidenmier for valuable comments on previous drafts; and to Rita Hjerppe, George Kostelenos and Ilkka Lavonius for generous sharing of data. The usual disclaimer applies. References A GGARWAL , R., D EMIRGÜÇ -K UNT , A. and M ARTÍNEZ P ERÍA , M. S. (2006). Do workers’ remittances promote financial development? Policy Research Working Paper 3957, World Bank. A LVES , J. (1993). Os ‘Brasileiros’: emigração e retorno no Porto Oitocentista. Porto: Facultade de Letras da Universidade do Porto. A UTIO , J. (1992). Valuuttakurssit Suomessa 1864–1991. Katsaus ja tilastosarjat. Bank of Finland: Discussion Paper no. 1/92. B ACKUS , D., K EHOE , P. and K YDLAND , F. (1992). International real business cycles. Journal of Political Economy 100, pp. 745–75. 18 In our sample, total deposits/GDP averages 30.9% (max 115.9%, min 0.5%). In Aggarwal et al.’s (2006) study for 1975–2003, the corresponding figures are 29.2% average, max 161.4%, min 1.7%. 466 European Review of Economic History B ALLETTA , F. (1978). Emigrazione Italiana, cicli economici e rimesse (1876–1976). In G. Rosoli (ed.), Un secolo di emigrazione italiana, 1876–1976. Rome: Centro Studi Emigrazione, pp. 65–96. B ÄRLUND , R. (1992). Finland’s balance of payments, 1890–1913. Discussion Papers 42(92), Bank of Finland. B ATTILOSSI , S. (2006). The determinants of multinational banking during the first globalisation 1880–1914. European Review of Economic History 10(3), pp. 361–88. B ECKMAN , E. (1883). Amerikanska studier. Stockholm: Z. Haeggströms förlagsexpedition. B ETTIN , G. and Z AZZARO , A. (2008). Remittances and financial development: substitutes or complements in economic growth? Mimeo, Università Politecnica delle Marche. B OYD , J., L EVINE , R. and S MITH , B. (2001). The impact of inflation on financial sector performance. Journal of Monetary Economics 47, pp. 221–48. B UGAMELLI , M. and P ATERNO , F. (2006). Do workers’ remittances reduce the probability of current account reversals? CEP Discussion Paper no. 714. C ALDERÓN , C., F AJNZYLBER , P. and L ÓPEZ , H. (2007). Remittances and growth: the role of complementary policies. In P. Fajnzylber and H. López (eds.), Remittances and Development: Lessons from Latin America. Washington, DC: World Bank, pp. 335–68. C AROSSO , V. and S YLLA , R. (1991). US banks in international finance. In R. Carmeron and B. I. Bovykin (eds.), International Banking, 1870–1914. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 48–71. C ARRERAS , A. and T AFUNEL , X. (eds.) (2005). Estadísticas históricas de España. Siglos XIX–XX. Bilbao: Fundación BBVA. C ARTER , S. et al. (eds.) (2006). Historical Statistics of the United States: Earliest Times to the Present. Millennial edition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. C ASTILLO , N. and O ROZCO , M. (2008). Latino Migrants: A Profile on Remittances, Finances, and Health. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. C HINN , M. and I TO , H. (2002). Capital account liberalization, institutions and financial development: cross-country evidence. NBER Working Paper no. 8967. C OTULA , F. (1996). I bilanci delle aziende di credito, 1890–1936. Rome: Laterza. DE LA B RIÈRE , B., S ADOULET , E., DE J ANVRY , A. and L AMBERT , S. (2002). The roles of destination, gender, and household composition in explaining remittances: an analysis for the Dominican Sierra. Journal of Development Economics 68(2), pp. 309–28. DE L UNA M ARTÍNEZ , J. (2005). Workers’ remittances to developing countries: a survey with central banks on selected public policy issues. Policy Research Working Paper 3638, World Bank. D E M ATTIA , R. (1990). Storia delle operazioi degli istituti di emissione italiani dal 1845 al 1936 attraverso i dati dei loro bilanci. Rome: Banca diItalia. D E S IPIO , L. (2002). Sending money home . . . for now: remittances and immigrant adaptation in the United States. In B. Lindsay Lowell and R. de la Garza (eds.), Sending Money Home: Hispanic Remittances and Community Development. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield, pp. 157–87. D JANKOV , S., M C L IESH , C. and S HLEIFER , A. (2006). Private credit in 129 countries. Journal of Financial Economics 84(2), pp. 299–329. Remittances, capital flows and financial development 467 D OUKI , C. (2001). Le territoire économique d’une région d’émigration: campagnes et montagnes lucquoises, du milieu du XIXE siècle à 1914. Revue d’histoire moderne et contemporaine 2/3, 642–291. D UNLEVY , J. and S ABA , R. (1992). The role of nationality-specific characteristics on the settlement patterns of late nineteenth century immigrants. Explorations in Economic History 29, pp. 228–49. D URAND , J., K ANDEL , W., P ARRADO , E. and M ASSEY , D. (1996). International migration and development in Mexican communities. Demography 33(2), pp. 249–64. E ITRHEIM , J., K LOVLAND , T. and Q VIGSTAD , J. F. (eds.) (2004). Historical monetary statistics for Norway 1819–2003. Oslo: Norges Bank, Occasional Paper no. 35. E RRUNZA , V. (2001). Foreign portfolio equity investments, financial liberalization and economic development. Review of International Economics 9(4), pp. 703–26. E STEVES , R. and K HOUDOUR -C ASTÉRAS , D. (2009). A fantastic rain of gold: European migrants’ remittances and balance of payments adjustment during the gold standard period. Journal of Economic History 69(4), pp. 951–85. F ENOALTEA , S. (1988). International resource flows and construction movements in the Atlantic economy: the Kuznets cycle in Italy, 186–1913. Journal of Economic History 48(3), pp. 605–37. F ERENCZI , I. and W ILLCOX , W. (1929). International Migrations, vol. 1: Statistics. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research. F ILIPSKI , M. and T AYLOR , E. (2010). Migration policies and rural welfare in Mexico and Nicaragua. Mimeo, OECD Development Centre. F LANDREAU , M. and Z UMER , F. (2004). The Making of Global Finance, 1880–1913. Paris: OECD. F OHLIN , C. (2007). Finance Capitalism and Germany’s Rise to Industrial Power. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. F REITAS , J. J. (1878). Crise monetaria e política de 1876 – causas e remedio. Porto: Livraria Moré. F UNKHOUSER , E. (1995). Remittances from international migration: a comparison of El Salvador and Nicaragua. Review of Economics and Statistics 77(1), pp. 137–46. G ARCÍA L ÓPEZ , J. R. (1992). Las remesas de los emigrantes españoles en América. Siglos XIX y XX. Colombres, Asturias: Fundación Archivo de Indianos. G ERSCHENKRON , A. (1962). Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective: A Book of Essays. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. G IULIANO , P. and R UIZ -A RRANZ , M. (2009). Remittances, financial development, and growth. Journal of Development Economics 90(1), pp. 144–52. G ODINHO , V. (1978). L’émigration portugaise XVe-XXe siècles. Revista de História Económica e Social 1, pp. 5–32. G OLDSMITH , R. (1969) Financial Structure and Development. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. H ABER , S., R AZO , A. and M AURER , N. (2003). The Politics of Property Rights Political Instability, Credible Commitments, and Economic Growth in Mexico, 1876–1929. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 468 European Review of Economic History H ATTON , T. (1995). A model of Scandinavian emigration. European Economic Review 39, pp. 557–64. H ATTON , T. (2000). How much did immigrant ‘quality’ decline in late nineteenth century America? Journal of Population Economics 13, pp. 509–25. H ATTON , T. and W ILLIAMSON , J. G. (1994). Late-comers to mass emigration: the Latin experience. In T. Hatton and J.G. Williamson (eds.), Migration and the International Labor Market, 1850–1939. London: Routledge, pp. 53–71 H ATTON , T. and W ILLIAMSON , J. G. (2005). Global Migration and the World Economy: Two Centuries of Policy and Performance. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. H JERPPE , R. (1989) The Finnish Economy 1860–1986. Growth and Structural Change. Helsinki: Bank of Finland. H OPPU , K. W. (1920). Suomen maksubilanssi. Yhteiskuntataloudellinen Aikakauskirja 14, pp. 7–21. H OVDE , B. J. (1934). Notes on the effects of emigration upon Scandinavia. Journal of Modern History 6(3), pp. 253–79. IFAD (2007). Sending Money Home. Worldwide Remittances Flows to Developing and Transition Economies. Rome: International Fund for Agricultural Development. IMF (2009). International Financial Statistics – September 2009. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. I SSERLIS , L. (1938). Tramp shipping cargoes, and freights. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 101(1), pp. 53–146. ISTAT (1957). Indagine statistica sullo sviluppo del reddito nazionale dell’Italia dal 1861 al 1956. Annali di statistica series VIII, vol. 9. ISTAT (1958). Sommario di statistiche storiche italiane: 1861–1955. Rome: Istituto Centrale di Statistica. J EROME , H. (1926). Migration and Business Cycles. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research. J OHANSSON , Ö. (1967). The Gross Domestic Product of Sweden and its Composition 1861–1955. Stockholm: Almqvist and Wiksell. K INDLEBERGER , C. (1985). A Financial History of Western Europe. London: Allen and Unwin. K ING , R. and L EVINE , R. (1993). Finance and growth: Schumpeter might be right. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, pp. 717–37. K OMLOS , J. (1987). Financial innovation and the demand for money in Austria-Hungary, 1867–1913. Journal of European Economic History 16(3), pp. 587–605. K OSTELENOS , G., V ASILIOU , D., K OUNARIS , E., P ETMEZAS , S. and S FAKIANAKIS , M. (2007). Gross Domestic Product 1830–1939, Sources of Economic History of Modern Greece, Quantitative Data and Statistical Series. Athens: KEPE and Historical Archives of the National Bank of Greece (in Greek). L A P ORTA , R., L OPEZ DE S ILANES , F., S HLEIFER , A. and V ISHNY , R. (1997). Legal determinants of external finance. Journal of Finance 52, pp. 1131–50. L AZARETOU , S. (1993). Monetary and fiscal policies in Greece: 1833–1914. Journal of European Economic History 20(2), pp. 441–53. L EVINE , R. (2001). International financial integration and economic growth. Review of International Economics 9(4), pp. 684–98. Remittances, capital flows and financial development 469 L I , G. (1985). Robust regression. In D. C. Hoaglin, F. Mosteller and J. Tukey (eds.), Exploring Data Tables, Trends, and Shapes. New York: Wiley. M ADDISON , A. (2003). The World Economy: Historical Statistics. Paris: OECD. M AGEE , G. and T HOMPSON , A. (2006a). Lines of credit, debts of obligation: migrants’ remittances to Britain, c. 1875–1913. Economic History Review 59(3), pp. 539–77. M AGEE , G. and T HOMPSON , A. (2006b). The global and local: explaining migrant remittances flows in the English-speaking world, 1880–1914. Journal of Economic History 66(1), pp. 177–202. M ARTÍNEZ P ERÍA , M. S., M ASCARÓ , Y. and M OIZESZOWICZ , F. (2007). Do remittances affect recipient countries’ financial development? In P. Fajnzylber and H. López (eds.), Remittances and Development: Lessons from Latin America. Washington, DC: World Bank, pp. 171–215. M ASSULO , G. (2001). Economia delle rimesse. In P. de Bevilacqua, A. Clementi and E. Franzina (eds.), Storia dell’emigrazione italiana, vol I: Partenze. Rome: Donzelli, pp. 161–83. M ATA , M. E. (2002). As crises financeiras no Portugal contemporâneo: uma perspectiva de conjunto. In S. Matos Campos (ed.), Crises em Portugal nos séculos XIX e XX. Lisbon: Centro de História da Universidade de Lisboa, pp. 38–55. M EARS , E. (1923). The unique position in Greek trade of emigrant remittances. Quarterly Journal of Economics 37(3), pp. 535–40. M EISSNER , C. (2005). A new world order: explaining the international diffusion of the gold standard, 1870–1913. Journal of International Economics 66(2), pp. 385–406. M ITCHELL , B. R. (2003). International Historical Statistics: Europe 1750–2000. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. M ITTONE , L. (1984). Le rimesse degli emigrati sino al 1914. Affari sociali internazionali 4, pp. 125–60. M OLIN , A. (1905). Svenska spörsmål och kraf. Stockholm: Geber. M ORYS , M. (2005). The classical gold standard in the European periphery: a case study of Austria–Hungary and Italy, 1870–1913. PhD dissertation, London School of Economics and Political Science. M UNDACA , G. (2005). Can remittances enhance economic growth? The role of financial markets development. Mimeo, University of Oslo. N UNES , A., M ATA , E. and V ALÉRIO , N. (1989) Portuguese economic growth 1833–1985. Journal of European Economic History 18(2), pp. 291–330. Ó’G RÁDA , C. (1998). Immigrants, savers and runners: the emigrant industrial savings bank in the 1850s. Department of Political Economy Paper no. 98/2, University College Dublin. O’R OURKE , K. and W ILLIAMSON , J. G. (1999). Globalization and History. The Evolution of a Nineteenth-Century Atlantic Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. O ROZCO , M. and F EDEWA , R. (2006). Leveraging efforts on remittances and financial intermediation. INTAL-ITD Working Paper 24, Inter-American Development Bank. P ARSONS , C., S KELDON , R., W ALMSLEY , T. and W INTERS , A. (2007). Quantifying international migration: a database of bilateral migrant stocks. Policy Research Working Paper 4165, World Bank. 470 European Review of Economic History P RADOS DE LA E SCOSURA , L. (2006). La posición exterior de la economía española, 1850–1935. Mimeo. R AJAN , R. and Z INGALES , L. (2003). The great reversals: the politics of financial development in the 20th century. Journal of Financial Economics 69(1), pp. 5–50. R ATHA , D. (2005). Workers’ remittances: an important and stable source of external development finance. In S. M. Maimbo and D. Ratha (eds.), Remittances: Development Impact and Future Prospects. Washington, DC: World Bank, pp. 19–51. R EIS , J. (1990). A evolução da oferta monetária portuguesa 1854–1912. Lisbon: Banco de Portugal. R OMER , C. (1986). Spurious volatility in historical unemployment data. Journal of Political Economy 94(1), pp. 1–37. R OSENBLOOM , J. (1996). Was there a national labor market at the end of the nineteenth century? New evidence on earnings in manufacturing. Journal of Economic History 56(3), pp. 626–56. S ALAZAR , A. (1916). O ágio do ouro, sua natureza e suas causas, 1891–1915. Coimbra: Imprensa da Universidade. S ÁNCHEZ A LONSO , B. (2000). European emigration in the late nineteenth century: the paradoxical case of Spain. Economic History Review 53(2), pp. 309–30. S CHNEIDER , J., S CHWARZER , O. and Z ELLFELDER , F. (1991). Europäische und nordamerikanische Devisenkurse 1777–1914. Stuttgart: Franz Steiner. S CHRIER , A. (1958). Ireland and the American Emigration 1850–1900. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press. S EMMINGSEN , I. (1978). Norway to America: A History of the Migration. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota. S IMON , M. (1960). The United States balance of payments, 1861–1900. In W. Parker (ed.), Trends in the American Economy in the Nineteenth Century. Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 629–711. S TOCK , J. and Y OGO , M. (2002). Testing for weak instruments in linear IV regression. NBER Technical Working Paper no. 284. T AYLOR , A. and W ILLIAMSON , J. G. (2006). Convergence in the age of mass migration. European Review of Economic History 1(1), pp. 27–63. T ERRY , D. and W ILSON , S. (2005). Beyond Small Change: Making Migrant Remittances Count. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. US D EPARTMENT OF H OMELAND S ECURITY (2009). 2008 Yearbook of Immigration Statistics. Washington, DC: Office of Immigration Statistics. US I MMIGRATION C OMMISSION (1911). Reports. 61st Congress, 3rd Session, Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office. V ALÉRIO , N. (ed.) (2001). Estatísticas históricas portuguesas. Lisbon: Instituto Nacional de Estatística. V ERNON , J. (1994). Unemployment rates in postbellum America: 1869–1899. Journal of Macroeconomics 16(4), pp. 701–14. W ILLIAMSON , J. (1995). The evolution of global markets since 1830: background evidence and hypotheses. Explorations in Economic History 32(2), pp. 141–96. W YMAN , M. (1993). Round Trip to America: The Immigrants Return to Europe, 1880–1930. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Remittances, capital flows and financial development 471 Appendix A: Data sources Remittances series were already available for four countries in our sample: Austria– Hungary and Italy (Morys 2005), Portugal (Mata 2002) and Spain (Prados de la Escosura 2006). The series for Finland, Greece, Norway and Sweden were estimated from information on stocks of remitters in the US, the amounts sent per remitter from the US in reference years, and on US wages converted to local currencies. The information on emigration flows to build up the stocks comes from Ferenczi and Wilcox (1929) for all countries except Greece (Carter et al. 2006). The reference values for the average amount of money sent per remitter were established from the following sources: – For Greece, Mears (1923) estimates that in 1913 29 m drachmae entered the country as remittances. To recover the per remitter amount, we divided this value by our estimate of the stock of Greek remitters in 1913. – For Finland, Bärlund (1992), based on information from Hoppu (1920), gives figures of remittances sent, both formally and informally, by Finnish emigrants from Canada and the United States between 1909 and 1913. The average annual amount of remittances was 21.9 m markkaa during this period and we extrapolated this average to the years before 1908. – For Norway and Sweden, we used information on two reference years. The US Immigration Commission (1911, vol. 37) contains an estimate of the total remittances sent by ‘Scandinavians’ in 1907 (25 m dollars). The same source breaks down this amount by banks, international money orders, and an adjustment based on extra ‘figures obtained from reliable sources’ (p. 276). In apportioning this total amount by the emigrants of the two countries, we followed three steps. (1) We divided the common value of banking remittances according to information on the per remitter amount of banking transfers gathered by the Commission from a sample of banks. This amount is practically identical for the two nationalities: $29.77 for the Norwegians and $25.03 for the Swedes. (2) We added up the values of international money orders, which were reported by country instead of ‘race’. (3) We applied the same proportional adjustment used by the reporters of the Commission to convert the visible amounts to the total remittances. Lastly, Beckman (1883; quoted by Hovde 1934) estimates, using data from American banks, that Sweden received around 3 m dollars (11.2 m kronor) in 1882. Given the similarity in the per remitter amounts in 1912 between Norway and Sweden, we used the same imputed per remitter amount in 1882 for Norway. Data on US wages come from Williamson (1995), adjusted by unemployment rates from Romer (1986) and Vernon (1994). Exchange rates (number of local currency units per pound sterling) were calculated from Schneider et al. (1991) and Flandreau and Zumer (2004), with the following exceptions: Autio (1992) for Finland; Lazaretou (1993) for Greece; Eitrheim et al. (2004) for Norway; and Carreras and Tafunel (2005) for Spain. For Sweden we used the series prepared by Håkan Lobell and available from the Bank of Sweden website at: www.riksbank.se/templates/Page.aspx?id=27402 472 European Review of Economic History Money supply (M1) series (m of local currency units) were obtained from Komlos (1987) for Austria–Hungary; Kostelenos et al. (2007) for Greece; Reis (1990) for Portugal; Carreras and Tafunel (2005) for Spain. Data for Finland were kindly provided by Jaakko Autio. For Norway we used the M0 series listed in Eitrheim et al. (2004) since the authors comment that demand deposits were but a small portion of the total money stock (around 2 per cent of M2) before 1914. De Mattia (1990) follows similar arguments in applying a definition of M1 that is actually closer to M0. We use his series for Italy. We were not able to find a M1 series for Sweden. Deposits in commercial banks (m of local currency units) were collected from Komlos (1987) for Austria–Hungary; Mitchell (2003) for Finland, Spain and Sweden; Kostelenos et al. (2007) for Greece; Cotula (1996) for Italy; Eitrheim et al. (2004) for Norway; and Reis (1990) for Portugal. Deposits in savings banks (m of local currency units) have the same sources except for Austria–Hungary (Mitchell 2003) and Finland, for which we used statistics kindly communicated by Risto Herrala and Vappu Ikonen. There is also no series for Portugal. Nominal GDP figures (in m local currency units) were gathered from Flandreau and Zumer (2004) for Austria–Hungary; Hjerppe (1989) for Finland; Kostelenos et al. (2007) for Greece; ISTAT (1957) for Italy; Mitchell (2003) for Norway; Nunes et al. (1989) for Portugal; Carreras and Tafunel (2005) for Spain; and Johansson (1967) for Sweden. Population series (thousands) were taken from Mitchell (2003) for Austria– Hungary; Maddison (2003) for Finland, Italy, Norway and Sweden; Kostelenos et al. (2007) for Greece; Valério (2001) for Portugal; and Carreras and Tafunel (2005) for Spain. Foreign trade statistics (in m local currency units) were taken from Mitchell (2003) with the following exceptions: Finland (Hjerppe 1989); Portugal (Valério 2001); and Spain (Carreras and Tafunel 2005). Inflation was calculated from price series (usually GDP deflators) taken from Flandreau and Zumer (2004) for Austria–Hungary; Hjerppe (1989) for Finland; Kostelenos et al. (2007) for Greece; ISTAT (1957) for Italy; Michell (2003) for Norway; Valério (2001) for Portugal; Carreras and Tafunel (2005) for Spain; and Johansson (1967) for Sweden. Gold standard participation was coded from Flandreau and Zumer (2004) and Meissner (2005). Political variables were taken from the database of the Polity IV project available at: www.systemicpeace.org/polity/polity4.htm Creditors rights is an index compiled by Djankov et al. (2006) available at: www.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/shleifer/dataset Exchange rates (instruments) for the USA, France, Austria–Hungary, Argentina and Brazil were taken from Flandreau and Zumer (2004). Appendix B. Remittances and number of remitters, by nationality Portugal Remittances 1.88 2.14 2.53 2.76 2.81 3.16 2.80 2.81 2.59 2.46 2.55 2.61 2.64 2.73 2.72 2.37 2.54 2.88 3.34 3.91 3.34 2.32 3.74 3.72 4.51 Greece Remitters 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.08 0.08 0.09 0.08 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.16 0.19 0.19 0.32 0.36 0.54 1.11 1.06 1.37 2.17 2.30 2.59 3.45 Finland Remittances Remitters 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.003 0.003 0.004 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.01 2.89 5.51 6.55 8.19 10.97 12.54 12.95 15.52 13.37 Norway Remittances Remitters 0.06 0.11 0.13 0.17 0.23 0.26 0.27 0.32 0.27 33.23 33.42 31.73 25.17 20.20 16.70 12.11 9.87 11.47 19.49 29.82 41.70 49.11 51.82 49.18 44.32 41.05 40.73 39.10 37.58 37.43 35.85 34.77 30.61 Sweden Remittances Remitters Remittances 0.26 0.25 0.24 0.20 0.16 0.14 0.09 0.08 0.09 0.15 0.25 0.39 0.58 0.70 0.66 0.69 0.61 0.53 0.67 0.78 0.69 0.65 0.57 0.41 0.15 0.13 0.08 0.07 0.10 0.24 0.40 0.61 0.89 1.04 0.92 1.00 0.98 0.97 1.34 1.74 1.64 1.57 1.34 0.96 19.22 14.99 10.86 8.54 13.45 30.09 47.23 66.41 74.81 76.44 68.24 63.16 65.37 74.37 78.05 83.25 87.48 85.44 81.40 70.67 Remittances, capital flows and financial development Austria– Hungary Italy Spain Year Remittances Remittances Remittances 1870 0.71 1871 0.70 1872 0.79 1873 0.90 1874 1.14 1875 1.04 1876 3.99 1.19 1877 4.05 1.23 1878 4.21 1.00 1879 0.96 1.06 1880 0.99 1.19 1.06 1881 1.51 1.51 0.99 1882 1.76 2.10 1.12 1883 1.95 3.11 1.24 1884 2.49 3.57 1.31 1885 2.41 4.04 1.14 1886 2.53 4.44 1.42 1887 2.94 5.60 1.87 1888 3.30 8.38 2.32 1889 3.18 9.29 3.24 1890 4.10 10.00 2.48 1891 4.99 11.20 2.83 1892 5.60 9.62 3.23 1893 2.57 9.89 3.56 1894 1.77 9.32 2.96 473 474 Italy Remittances 9.60 10.69 11.37 12.09 11.50 11.47 13.58 16.89 20.66 23.19 25.64 32.15 37.76 36.68 33.19 32.60 29.84 33.06 38.04 Spain Remittances 2.27 2.60 2.70 2.56 3.01 3.20 3.11 2.76 3.20 4.20 5.47 6.92 7.73 9.69 10.28 12.13 12.48 14.67 13.67 Portugal Remittances 4.71 5.31 6.76 7.64 6.73 4.98 4.07 3.35 3.54 3.31 2.27 2.12 2.20 3.85 3.37 3.68 4.91 4.02 3.63 Greece Remitters 3.33 4.40 3.98 5.22 5.87 8.31 11.28 16.79 25.97 31.37 35.69 46.75 69.56 71.14 71.35 84.23 88.80 77.64 78.83 Remittances 0.01 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.03 0.04 0.06 0.09 0.15 0.23 0.34 0.59 0.90 0.85 0.99 1.23 1.25 1.10 1.14 Finland Remitters 12.69 12.96 10.41 7.89 13.78 16.64 20.34 31.41 37.20 36.08 40.04 42.39 39.03 32.74 37.90 38.64 33.85 31.35 38.99 Remittances 0.27 0.26 0.22 0.17 0.30 0.37 0.47 0.74 0.90 0.84 0.97 1.08 0.98 0.76 0.69 0.86 0.93 0.84 0.98 Norway Remitters 28.49 25.03 19.30 12.99 13.51 15.87 18.70 25.88 35.51 41.75 45.75 49.44 50.09 41.33 39.32 38.44 33.73 27.63 28.01 Remittances 0.53 0.41 0.36 0.27 0.32 0.42 0.56 0.84 1.21 1.31 1.64 2.05 1.99 1.52 1.53 1.48 1.25 1.03 1.07 Sweden Remitters 64.47 54.76 40.33 27.09 28.39 29.27 32.05 43.50 55.93 57.73 59.84 60.32 53.88 40.99 41.60 43.36 40.19 37.59 41.17 Remittances 1.21 0.91 0.77 0.58 0.69 0.79 0.96 1.44 1.95 1.84 2.19 2.55 2.19 1.54 1.65 1.70 1.52 1.43 1.61 Notes: Remittances in m pounds sterling; remitters in thousands. The Greek remittance series is shorter than the stock of remitters because we only have drachmae exchange rates after 1875 from Lazaretou (1993). Sources: See Appendix A. European Review of Economic History Year 1895 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 1904 1905 1906 1907 1908 1909 1910 1911 1912 1913 Austria– Hungary Remittances 2.08 2.93 2.52 3.45 4.45 7.02 9.86 13.18 16.29 17.25 21.66 29.71 35.80 43.26 32.75 42.41 52.12 51.89 49.89