Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
EC225 Russian Industrialisation [email protected] Spring Term, 2003/04 Lecture 14. Perestroika to Katastroika This lecture considers the Soviet economy at the end of the 1980s; it describes how economic developments unfolded in such a way that a difficult situation unfolded rapidly into a catastrophe. Part 9. The End of the Soviet Model The purpose of these lectures is to describe and analyse the end of the Soviet model of state socialism in Europe. Why did the Soviet economy collapse? Was the collapse inevitable and predictable, or was it contingent or accidental? Where has it left Russians and Russian society today? Overview Djankov, Simeon, Edward Glaeser, Rafael la Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer (2003). “The New Comparative Economics.” Journal of Comparative Economics 31(4), 595-619. Ellman, Michael, and Vladimir Kontorovich, eds (1998). The Destruction of the Soviet Economic System: an Insiders’ History, especially chapter 2 by Ellman and Kontorovich, “What We Learn From the Insiders.” Hanson, Philip (2003). The Rise and Fall of the Soviet Economy: an Economic History of the USSR since 1945, chapter 9. Harrison, Mark (2002). “Coercion, Compliance, and the Collapse of the Soviet Command Economy.” Economic History Review 55(3). Treml, Vladimir G., and Ellman, Michael (1993). “Debate: Why Did the Soviet Economic System Collapse?” Radio Free Europe/Radio Liberty Research Report, 2(23), available in class. 1 After Brezhnev: a “Pre-Crisis Situation”? Table 1. Soviet Leaders, 1924 to 1991 Lenin Stalin Khrushchev Brezhnev Andropov Chernenko Gorbachev Died January 1924 Died March 1953 Retired October 1964 Died November 1982 Died February 1984 Died March 1985 Resigned December 1991 Table 2. Soviet Growth Rates, 1950 to 1987 GDP per Industry Consumer Food head and con- durables products struction 1950-64 1954-73 1973-82 1982-87 3.9 3.5 0.9 1.2 8.2 5.7 2.5 2.6 10.5 10.0 5.1 5.5 2.7 3.1 1.1 –1.8 Source: Harrison (2002). 2 The Gorbachev Factor “Restructuring”: Perestroika, 1987 After the death of Brezhnev and two stopgap successors the Politburo appointed its youngest member to bring the Soviet system up to the end of the millenium. Gorbachev already had a reputation as an innovative leader, and so he proved to be, but he also displayed many traditional features. Most obvious was his tendency to try to solve problems by all means available, whether or not they were calculated to be consistent and compatible with his central objectives. It was two years before it became absolutely obvious even to the most sceptical Cold Warrior that he was a new phenomenon in Soviet life. § “Acceleration”: uskorenie § “Openness”: glasnost’ § “New thinking” § Limits to “new thinking”: full employment Assault on Planning Industrial reform, 1987: firms to be rewarded for using capacity profitably; last attempt at a Chinese style transition to a market economy? § Planners to limit output targets to share of firms' activity declining from 70 to 30 per cent. § Firms to sell residual output on the market, without guarantee of finding a seller, on self financing basis. Immediate problems: § Ministerial officials supportive of acceleration and aiming to fulfill ministerial plans failed to cut claims on firms' output § Firms continued to lack, or claimed to lack, spare capacity to allocate to market output § Firms’ failure to find a market and cover costs remained without penalty, i.e. not forced to lay off workers, or go bankrupt § No differential reward to expanding market-oriented activity; firms with potential for profitable market-oriented activity continued to lack interest in making efforts required to realise it. Assault on the Ministries Gorbachev identified the failures of the “era of stagnation” with the accretion of ministerial power. Think of three levels of power: § Government § Ministries § People as producers and consumers Assault on the Party From 1987 Gorbachev identified the party nomenklatura as the major obstacle to reform. The system was opened up to electoral competition, and in 1989 there were relatively free elections in which the communist party suffered major losses to democrats and Gorbachev supporters. 3 4 Unintended Financial Consequences Foreign Policy Table 2. Soviet Monetary Growth, 1971 to 1990: the Increase in Cash in Circulation, Billion Rubles Defensive Sufficiency Gorbachev rejected the principle of Mutual Assured Destruction through nuclear overkill. The forecast of a nuclear winter and extermination of human life following a largescale atomic exchange being popularised by Carl Sagan had a devastating impact on the thinking of Soviet military and political leaders. The Soviet Union moved to end the Cold War through multilateral nuclear disarmament. End of Empire Gorbachev made it clear that the fate of each East European satellite lay in its own hands. He took halting steps towards greater independence for the Baltic states but here his coalition began to disintegrate and he began to lose control of police actions on the ground. In the rest of the USSR he tried to hold the Union together and proposed a new Union treaty with greater Republican rights and emphasising the voluntary character of the Union. This issue ended in the conservatives’ putsch of August 1991, the emergence of El’tsyn as the effective leader of democratic forces in Russia, and the collapse of the Soviet Union, formalised at the end of 1991. Gorbachev was completely sidelined and the communist party temporarily banned. Perestroika had ended in catastrophe and Gorbachev, much admired abroad, was despised at home for his contradictory policies and indecisiveness. Billion rubles 1971-85 (annual average) 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 Per cent of cash in circulation, beginning of year 3.3 3.9 5.9 11.7 18.3 26.6 .. 6 8 15 21 25 Source: Ellman and Kontorovich (1992), 121 Table 3. The USSR Budget Deficit, 1985 to 1989 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 The financial deficit The monetary deficit Billion rubles Billion rubles 15.3 47.4 54.4 82.6 82.9 Per cent of GNP 2.0 5.9 6.6 9.4 9.0 13.9 45.5 52.5 80.6 80.8 Per cent of GNP 1.8 5.7 6.4 9.2 8.7 Source: Ellma n and Kontorovich (1992), 114. The financial deficit is the gap between outlays and current tax revenues (variant 3 in the source). The monetary deficit (variant 2 in the source) is that part of the financial deficit not financed by sales of government bon ds to the public, i.e. the part that was monetised . 5 6 Lecture 15. Why Did the Economy Collapse? This lecture considers the underlying dynamics of the Soviet economic collapse, analysing it as the outcome of a game of strategy played by a dic tator and a producer. Was the Soviet System Unstable? Figure 1. Soviet and Former Soviet Real GDP per Head, 1928 to 1998 $US and 1990 prices, log scale 10000 1000 1928 1938 1948 1958 1968 1978 1988 1998 Source: Maddison (1995), 200, and (2000), 278. 7 Economic Evidence § Soviet productivity was rising until the collapse § The productivity trend was stable § From the 1920s to the 1980s GDP per head rose by a factor of five, real consumption by less § Returns to accumulation diminished; diminished more sharply than they should have by international standards; more sharply still after the mid-1970s; but were not negative. § Until the mid-1970s the Soviet economy was catching up but not yet overtaking the advanced capitalist countries § After the mid-1970s Soviet productivity growth ceased to catch up; remained positive; did not fall to zero. Reservoirs of Loyalty § Dissident opposition was always narrow. § Emigres revealed substantial loyalty to basic Soviet values. § Gorbachev-era surveys show that while significant majorities favoured the concepts of perestroika and a market economy, most continued to support state ownership of heavy industry and state guarantees of basic incomes and jobs; they did not want consequences of a market economy such as free prices, unemployment, or rich people. Summary According to the evidence the Soviet political economy, while not dynamic and not problem- free, was stable and had many attributes of legitimacy. Still it collapsed. Why? 8 The Nature of Command A High-Effort Equilibrium The Command System § Dictator gave orders to producers § Output depended on producers’ effort § Distribution of output between producer and dictator depended on the degree and character of coercion § Coercion was unrestrained by law (Gorbachev: “our state is not yet law-governed”; Stalin: “the plan is the law”). Coercion: Three Aspects § Mobilisation: the dictator extracted output from producers, returned a basic wage to producers, and allocated the rest to government objectives of national development and defence. § Monitoring : the dictator made producers account for inputs and outputs through planning, statistics, and police work. Otherwise, how could the dictator know he was getting it all? If planners didn’t monitor, the producers would convert part of the output into their personal income by consuming it directly or diverting it to illegal markets. However, monitoring was costly because it required planning, accounting, statistics, and police work. Thus planners had to choose: monitor and pay monitoring costs, or don’t monitor but let producers steal a share of the rents. § Incentives. The dictator’s income depended crucially on producers’ effort. The harder producers worked, the bigger the dictator’s surplus. He had to invent artificial rewards and punishments big enough to overcome the dislike of effort. Then producers could choose whether to supply effort and receive a reward, or withhold effort and pay a penalty. Summary The command system did not mean absence of choice. Planners decided how much coercion, and producers decided how much effort. If producers had had no choices, there would have been no need for an incentive system. A former Soviet official told the British journalist We need to understand the William Keegan: “We used to work in a centrally logic of the dictator’s controlled system where they told you what to produce. Now they’ve stopped telling us what to decisions, but the dictator produce, so we don’t produce anything” (The needs first to understand the Observer, 18 October, 1998). logic to which producers will respond. This is because each will act strategically, taking into account the other’s response. Figure 2. The Producers’ Choice: Work or Shirk 9 Producers work hard IF Gain from working hard IS GREATER THAN Cost of working hard IF work hard AND monitoring is STRICT THEN IF work hard AND monitoring is LAX THEN Gain reward for working hard Avoid penalty for not working hard Spend effort working hard No rewards gained No penalties avoided Effort is spent working hard Work hard IF Reward gained + penalty avoided ARE GREATER THAN Cost of effort DON'T work hard ever Figure 3. The Dictator’s Choice: Monitor or Let Shirk and Steal The dictator monitors IF Effort is high AND Effort is low AND Costs of monitoring and rewards ARE LESS THAN output stolen + future output lost if don't monitor Cost of monitoring IS LESS THAN output stolen if don't monitor 10 Two Applications What Happened under Perestroika? Who triggered the collapse: producers or the dictator? In theory there are two possibilities: § Producers could have withdrawn effort in protest at inadequate incentives. Evidence? § Maybe the dictator responded to rising monitoring costs by shutting down the monitoring system. Remember: when the dictator doesn’t monitor, producers always choose low effort. Evidence? Summary The dictator abandoned the command economy, but producers signalled that the time had come. Trends in Monitoring Costs The stability of high output depends partly on monitoring costs. Changes in production that make monitoring more costly can narrow and eventually eliminate the scope for a high-output equilibrium. When monitoring collapses, effort will collapse too. Figure 4. High Effort Equilibrium Conditions Reward costs Rents protected reward maximum Effort costs reward minimum Monitoring costs Table 1. Party Membership, Share in Working Population Early 1920s 1940 1956 1973 1986 <1 3 7 11 15 11 12 Conclusions § Command economies are not intrinsically unstable. Stability is conditional and conditions for an equilibrium of high effort based on high coercion can be identified. These conditions may keep the income (but not necessarily welfare) of all parties better off than if monitoring and effort are allowed to collapse. § Second, the Soviet economy was stable until it collapsed. Possibly adverse trends in monitoring costs ensured that one day it would collapse. But eventual collapse could not have been forecast on the basis of the command economy’s intrinsic properties alone. § The dictator’s surrender triggered Soviet collapse; workers’ resistance provided a signal but did not force his hand. Lecture 16. The Economy In Transition This lecture considers the Russian economy in transition. All transitional economies experienced an initial fall in output, but whereas the central and east European economies tended to stabilise and recover quickly the economies of the former Soviet Union tended to display much worse outcomes. In Russia stabilisation took much longer and recovery has only begun. The initial expectations of western economists seem to have been let down by a missing factor required for low market transaction costs: institutional quality or social capital. The Collapse of Output Figure 1. Real GDP Per Head: Transitional Economies, 1950 to 1991 Real GDP per head, dollars 10000 Czechoslovakia Hungary USSR Poland Bulgaria Yugoslavia Romania 1000 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 Source: Maddison, A. (1995), Monitoring the world economy, 1820 -1992, appendix D Factors in the collapse of output: § The end of coercion § Disintegration § Continuation of the soft budget constraint 13 14 Hyperinflationary Trends Everywhere the collapse of the old system was associated with a sharp rise in the price level, as price controls were lifted. In some countries, mostly in the former Soviet Union, this was translated into a hyperinflationary impulse, which resulted in further destruction of the supply side.Causes of this were the same as of the previous European hyperinflation of the 1920s, brought about by the disintegration of empires and autocratic regimes (German, Austro-Hungarian, Russia): burgeoning demands for government expenditure, plus collapse of revenue (economic activity and institutions). In Russia following factors were involved: § Fiscal crisis § Monetisation of the deficit § Inflation expectations and flight from money § Effects on supply 15 Stabilisation, Restructuring, and Institutions At first western economists thought two things were required but with experience a third thing was added. § Stabilisation: stopping the fall of output and rise of prices. § Restructuring : reorganising the allocation of resources so as to satisfy social choices more efficiently. Economists debated whether these could be done simultaneously in a so-called “Big Bang”, or in sequence by means of a strategy of “gradualism”. § Institutions : with hindsight we find that, given sufficient institutional underpinning stabilisation and restructuring could be done either simultaneously or in sequence; it didn’t much matter which. On the other hand without institutional foundations, neither could be done at all. Why do institutions matter? Rising prices and falling output meant a negative supply shock. The supply shock and disintegration were caused by the destruction of the old transaction mechanism and the failure to replace it with another: in other words there was a sharp rise in transaction costs. In a well functioning exchange economy, transactions are cheap because of three institutions: § rule of law: ownership rights are protected and contracts are enforced. § trust: buyers and sellers share confidence in money and do not have to know each other personally to trust that exchange will be enforced. § competition: many sellers compete, information is widespread, transactions are transparent. 16 Transition Achievements Transition Achievements Measured Against Institutional Possibilities Figure 2 Figure 3. The Institutional Possibilities Frontier Losses from Private Disorder Real GDP, percent of 1989 120% Private orderings 100% Poland Czech R. 80% Independent judges Slovak R. Hungary Romania Bulgaria 60% Kazakstan Russia Regulatory state Ukraine 40% 20% 1989 1992 1995 IPF 1998 Source: EBRD (2000), Transition Report Update, May. Figures for 1999 are provisional and those for 2000 are forecasts. Transition in Central and Eastern Europe What progress has been achieved across the region? For some countries transition was painful but the pain is mostly in the past and recovery is under way. Whether or not they adopted a Big Bang or gradualism has made little difference to long run outcomes. Transition in Russia The Russian inflation followed four phases. § Inflation § Stabilisation without restructuring § Banking crisis § Reintegration of banking and industry 17 State ownership Losses from Dictatorship Source: Djankov et al. (2003), 599. The position of the IPF depends on civic capital which reflects the ease with which a given society achieves cooperation among its members. Example: the transaction costs associated with raising taxes to provide public goods. 18 Figure 4. Institutional Possibilities and Transition Losses from Private Disorder • Russia, 1995 CEE, • 1995 • • Russia, 1990 CEE, 1990 Losses from Dictatorship Source: Djankov et al. (2003), 608. Djankov et al. suggest that the IPF may become flatter as a result of economic development. Implications: They conclude that the outcomes of reform in a given country should be measured against its institutional possibilities, not against an abstract model of a market economy. Implications: 19