* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Timothy Kehoe - Banco Central do Brasil
Fei–Ranis model of economic growth wikipedia , lookup
Monetary policy wikipedia , lookup
Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup
Productivity improving technologies wikipedia , lookup
Business cycle wikipedia , lookup
Productivity wikipedia , lookup
Rostow's stages of growth wikipedia , lookup
Long Depression wikipedia , lookup
Carlos Viana de Carvalho, “Unconventional Policies during the Crisis and Expectations of Inflation and Growth: A Cross-Country Analysis” Marco Del Negro, “The Great Escape? A Quantitative Evaluation of the Fed's Non-Standard Policies” Timothy J. Kehoe University of Minnesota, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, and National Bureau of Economic Research XIV Annual Inflation Targeting Seminar Banco Central do Brasil May 2012 A central question for a central banker (at least for Ben Bernanke): What could the Fed have done to prevent the Great Depression of 1929‒1939 in the United States? A central question for a central banker (at least for Ben Bernanke): What could the Fed have done to prevent the Great Depression of 1929‒1939 in the United States? Answer of Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz, Monetary History of the United States: Untimely death of Benjamin Strong, Jr., the Governor of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, in October 1928, left the Fed effectively leaderless, during the Great Depression. Aggressively expansionary monetary policy would have prevented the worst of the Great Depression. These papers are first steps to confirming this view: Carlos Carvalho, Stefano Eusepi, and Christian Grisse have an imaginative and innovative approach to teasing out the impact of unconventional monetary policy and fiscal stimulus on expectations of inflation and economic growth, at least on the part of forecasters. They find that such policies were effective. Marco Del Negro, Gauti Eggertsson, Andrea Ferrero, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki combine innovative monetary theory with cutting edge DSGE modeling to develop a model of unconventional monetary policy and sue it to analyze the impact of Fed policy following the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September 2008. They argue that Fed policy was effective in avoiding another Great Depression. Great Depressions of the Twentieth Timothy J. Kehoe and Edward C. Prescott www.greatdepressionsbook.com Cole and Ohanian, “The Great Depression in the United States from a Neoclassical Perspective,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, Winter 1999. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Conference, October 2000. Special Issue of Review of Economic Dynamics, January 2002. Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century, July 2007. 15 studies by 26 researchers using the same methodology Great depressions 1930s United States, United Kingdom, Canada, France, Germany Contemporary Argentina (1970s and 1980s), Chile and Mexico (1980s), Brazil (1980s and 1990s), New Zealand and Switzerland (1970s, 1980s, and 1990s), Argentina (1998-2002) Not-quite-great depressions Italy (1930s), Finland (1990s), Japan (1990s) Kehoe and Prescott define a great depression to be a large negative deviation from balanced growth. They set the growth rate in the balanced growth path to be 2 percent per year, the growth rate of output per working-age person in the United States during the twentieth century. Real GDP per working-age person in the United States Great depressions in the 1930s: Detrended output per person 110 100 Germany Index (1928 = 100) France 90 United States 80 70 Canada 60 50 1928 1930 1932 1934 1936 1938 Great depressions in the 1980s: Detrended output per working-age person 110 Index (1980 = 100) 100 Chile Brazil 90 80 Mexico 70 Argentina 60 50 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 Great depressions methodology Crucial elements: Growth accounting and dynamic general equilibrium model Growth accounting decomposes changes in output per working-age person into three factors: a productivity factor a capital factor an hours-worked factor Great depressions methodology Crucial elements: Growth accounting and dynamic general equilibrium model Growth accounting decomposes changes in output per working-age person into three factors: a productivity factor a capital factor an hours-worked factor Keynesian analysis stresses declines in inputs of capital and labor as the causes of depressions. Balanced growth path In the dynamic general equilibrium model, if the productivity factor grows at a constant rate, then the capital factor and the hours-worked factor stay constant and growth in output is due to growth in the productivity factor. Twentieth century U.S. macro data are very close to a balanced growth path, with the exception of the Great Depression and the subsequent World War II build-up. Growth accounting for the United States 250 output index (1960=100 ) 200 productivity 150 hours worked 100 capital 50 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Growth accounting for the United States 140 index (1929=100) productivity capital 120 100 output 80 hours worked 60 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 We use a dynamic general equilibrium model to model the responses of households and firms — in terms of capital accumulation and hours worked — to changes in productivity and changes in government policy. We take the path of the productivity factor as exogenous. Comparing the results of the model with the data, we can identify features of the depression that need further analysis. Example: The Great Depression in the United States. Growth accounting for the United States 140 index (1929=100) productivity capital 120 100 output 80 hours worked 60 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 Growth accounting for the United States 140 productivity index (1929=100) 120 100 80 60 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 Growth accounting for the United States 140 index (1929=100) 120 100 output 80 60 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 Growth accounting for the United States 140 capital index (1929=100) 120 100 80 60 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 Growth accounting for the United States 140 index (1929=100) 120 100 80 hours worked 60 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 Conclusions A simple dynamic general equilibrium model that takes movements in the productivity factor as exogenous can explain most of the 1929-1933 downturn in the United States. The model over predicts the increase in hours worked during the 1933-1939 recovery. Need for Further Study The decline in productivity 1929-1933. The failure of hours worked to recover 1933-1939. How could the authors of these papers convince me that Ben Bernanke saved the United States — and the rest of the world — from another Great Depression? Carlos: More of theory, more distinction between different types of policies. It is not clear to me if your results back up Marco and his coauthor’s mdoeling work or not. Marco: An event study with growth accouting, feeding in time series for key exogenous variables. More of a thoery for diffiernt liquidity characteristics of assets. Growth Accounting in the United States 115 productivity 110 105 output capital 100 95 labor 90 85 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 Some questions for the authors: Is it clear that the Great Recession is over? Why are some assets more liquid than others? Are Greek government bonds liquid? (Yiting Li, Guillaume Rocheteau, and Pierre-Olivier Weill, 2011, and Pablo Kurlat, 2010) What are the costs and benefits of expansionary policies? Moral hazard?