Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Are there Spillover Effects between Coastal and Non-Coastal Regions in China ? Jean-François BRUN, CERDI-IDREC, Université Blaise Pascal Jean-Louis COMBES, CERDI-IDREC, Université d’Auvergne Mary-Françoise RENARD, CERDI-IDREC, Université d’Auvergne Draft paper 1 Abstract. The evolution of regional policy between Mao’s era and Deng’s era generated a lot of debates concerning the inter-provincial disparities and the trade-off between efficiency and equity. The topic of this paper is to explore the existence of regional growth spillover effects as expected by Deng’s policy. After reviewing the theoretical underpinnings of these effects, we test with panel data on the period 1981-1998 if the growth of Coastal provinces affects the growth of Inland provinces. We also test if these effects are equally spread over all the Inland provinces. We observe a relative failure to boost development of Western provinces from Coastal regions growth. It appears as a mistake to wait for spillover effects to be sufficient to reduce disparities between Chinese provinces in the short run. This result has some implications in terms of political economy. Key words. China, growth, regions, spillover effects, panel data. JEL classification. O53, O40, R58. 2 Since the beginning of the 80’s, the regional dimension has been crucial in the Chinese policy. It is obvious that the size and the geography of the country lead to emphasise the role of the regions (or provinces). Moreover, China has a very hierarchical administrative organisation. A main fact is that the relaxation of the control by the Central State gave more responsibilities to the regions. Reform has altered the relationships between Center and Provinces. First, Central Government has moved from policy of control through direct administration of the economy to one based on macro-economic management (see Goodman and Segal, 1994). Second, the fiscal relationships between Center and Provinces changed drastically, giving more power to the latter. At the beginning of the Mao’s period, the regions were characterised by wide disparities that the development strategy had the objective to curtail. The First Plan (1953-1957) stipulated that the new industrial bases had to correct for the supposed irrational spatial distribution of Chinese industry. Consequently, the local authorities have been called to build up relatively independent industries and have been encouraged to promote self-reliance. “Unlike previous Chinese governments, the communist leadership was able to tap a powerful war-state to rectify China’s regional imbalance” (Yang, 1997). So, one of the main goal was to reduce inter-regional imbalances. At the same time, there was also a strong desire to enhance China’s National Defence and then most of the considerations have been of military strategy. So, most of investments have been devoted to the inland regions and not to the richer coastal ones. Nevertheless, at the end of this period, coastal regions kept their superiority in terms of infrastructure and skills. The regional policy changed with Deng Xiao Ping who reversed the strategy and emphasised the international trade openness and so, the valorisation of regional comparative 3 advantages. For that, the government chose to experiment the “Open Door Policy” in two provinces: Guangdong and Fujian. They had relationships with Hong Kong, United States and Europe even during the Mao’s period. The Central Government gave them some advantages, especially by creating Special Economic Zones. This policy was reinforced by the creation of 14 coastal cities which have been given preferential treatment. The objective was to promote growth in coastal regions with the idea that there will be spillover effects between these regions and inland regions. The Sixth (1983-1986) and Seventh (1986-1991) Plans were based on the assumption that economic development tended to diffuse spatially through technological transfers. Even if this hypothesis has been discussed, “the Chinese leadership has opted to favor growth at the expense of some equity, at least in the short and intermediate run” (Yang, 1997). The international openness of coastal regions has been very important during the 80’s but the inter-regional protectionism has been maintained, so that the Central Government had to take some measures to try to reduce it. Hence, among others, these local trade barriers acted against the political strategy of promoting the diffusion of growth. This paper explores the existence of these growth spillover effects. In the first part, we will review the theoretical underpinnings of these effects. In the second part, we will test, with panel data, on the period 1981-1998, if the growth of coastal-provinces affects the growth of Inland provinces. We will also test if these effects spread equally over all the non-coastal provinces. I. A Theoretical Analysis of Provincial Spillover Effects. Provincial spillovers can emerge from three kinds of externalities: 4 (i) demand side externalities, in the sense that marginal productivity of capital depends on the beliefs of the province’s investors about the demand in other provinces, especially in coastal provinces which have the highest level of income per capita. (ii) trade externalities because trade is more intensive when transaction costs are decreasing, and then coastal regions economic activity enhances the domestic trade in all China and consequently the growth of inland provinces. (iii) supply side externalities which result from technical knowledge and managerial skill diffusion. In a long term growth perspective, we may suppose the predominance of this kind of externalities. Supply spillovers may be channelled by domestic trade between coastal and non-coastal provinces. Technological innovations embodied in foreign capital goods (Grossman and Helpman, 1991) diffuse to inland provinces from coastal provinces imports. Moreover, the competition on national market may incite inland producers to adopt the technology of coastal producers. An other important channel is foreign direct investments (FDI), as domestic firms imitate technologies created by foreign firms (de Mello, 1997). With the “Open Door Policy”, the coastal provinces and notably, Guangdong and Fujian have been allowed to attract FDI and so local firms captured some benefits (learning by doing, technological transfer, intermediate goods demand and access to foreign markets). Some firms notably from inland regions, 5 relocated part of their production process to try to get the same benefits. It is a way to diffuse this type of externalities from coastal to inland regions. When a coastal province invests in an innovative project, the latter can be considered as a free countrywide market study that improves economic information available to inland provinces. Moreover, there must exist an imitation process of policies between provinces. It is easy to understand why good policies may be copied (for instance household responsibility system, attraction of FDI). This process may be observed in a lot of countries but in the case of China it has been strongly encouraged by the Central Government whose target was to experiment a policy on coastal regions and “Open Cities” and then extended it to other provinces. But, bad policy may also be contagious according to local government rent-seeking. At least, an inland province may benefit from public capital goods provided by coastal provinces. When a province invests in roads, telecommunications, airports and ports, other provinces are favoured, as price exclusion is not possible. The same mechanism is at work concerning public investments in human capital, i.e. health and education. It is certainly the case with Special Economic Zones which concentrated most part of the investments in infrastructure, finance, tourism, whose objective was the diffusion of the benefits. 6 II. An Empirical Analysis of Regional Spillover Effects. A. The data. The test of regional spillover effects is based on the estimation of a growth equation derived from the empirical framework proposed by Barro (1991). The growth rate of real GDP per capita (GROWTHit) is regressed on three categories of variables: (i) the initial value of a state variable, ie the logarithm of initial real GDP per capita (GDPit) which is a proxy for the initial physical capital stock; (ii) control variables allowing for different steady states between provinces, (iii) provincial variables catching spillover effects. Notably, because of diminishing returns, the expected effect of the initial GDP per capita on the dependent variable is negative. Thus, poor provinces grow faster to their own steady state than wealthier ones (β-conditional convergence). Among control variables, the international economic environment is captured by the rate of growth of the real GDP of industrial countries (ICGROWTHt). It is expected to catch international overall economic situation1. A positive sign is expected. 1 To catch this effect, other variables were included in the regression such as: terms of trade, the rate of growth of the real GDP of China’s trade partners, none appeared significant. 7 Two variables are linked to demography: the population (POPit) and the population growth rate (POPGRit) of the province. The former should affect economic growth positively through economies of scale, for instance in the innovation activity. The latter is a rough proxy for the reproduction rate and so, should affect negatively the economic growth as high fertility implies an increase in the opportunity cost of economic activity (Barro and Sala-I-Martin 1995). According to the link between local branches of the Central Bank and the local governments, the monetary policy of each regions was very influenced by the regional governments. For this reason, a regional inflation rate is included. Inflation (INFLAit) generates distortions in the structure of relative prices. These distortions lead to an inefficient allocation of resources. Moreover, inflation is positively correlated to its variability, which increases risks for decision making. At least, inflation drives resources to governments and public spending may be less efficient than private spending. So, we expect a negative impact of inflation on GDP growth (Brun, Chambas and Combes, 1998). The share of direct foreign investments in fixed capital investment (FDIit) is included in the regression. A social or private productivity gap between domestic and foreign investments may explain a positive influence of FDI on economic growth. Several mechanisms can play a role. First, FDI promote technological transfers from industrial countries. Second, FDI may strengthen the managerial skills of domestic firms. Third, the access to world market is more easy for Chinese products (Chen, Chang, and Zhang, 1995). At least, FDI proxy the international openness of the provinces which strengthens the competitiveness, extends the scale of markets and promotes the access to more technological intensive intermediate goods. 8 State-owned enterprises are experiencing rather poor performances. The main explanation is the lack of adaptability to market rules: redundant employees, obsolete technologies, poor managerial skills and social and political constraints (Chen and Feng, 2000). So, importance of state-owned enterprises is measured by the ratio between state-owned staff and workers and total number of employed persons (SOEit). It is expected to exert a negative impact on growth. To test if the coastal real GDP growth rate affects the real GDP per capita growth rate of non-coastal provinces, we calculate the unweighted mean of coastal growth rate. Then, the resulting variable is multiplied by a dummy for each province. This method allows to catch up spillover effects different for potential receiving provinces. As usual in the literature, two types of inland provinces are distinguished: central (CENTRALit) and western (WESTERNit)2. As coastal growth may also affects coastal provinces, we calculate for each coastal province a coastal growth excluding this province (COASTALit) 3. The data set includes 28 provinces and so 168 observations as each province is described by 6 observation points covering the following periods: 1981-1983, 1984-1986, 1987-1989, 1990-1992, 1993-1995 and 1996-1998. The sample concerns the post-reform area, where the growth of each province largely results of their own structural characteristics and on decentralized policy choice. For instance, local authorities directly manage Township and Village Enterprises. 2 Central provinces are: Heilongjiang, Jilin, Inner Mongolia, Shanxi, Henan, Anhui, Hubei, Jiangxi and Hunan. Western provinces are: Xinjiang, Qinghai, Sichuan, Gansu, Shaanxi, Guizhou and Yunnan. Tibet, Ningxia and Chongqing are exclused because of lack of data. 3 For instance, for Beijing, the coastal growth mean is calculated on the following provinces: Liaoning, Tianjin, Hebei, Shandong, Jiangsu, Shanghai, Zhejiang, Fujian, Guang,dong, Hainan and Guangxi. 9 Data come from Comprehensive Statistical Data and Materials on 50 Years of New China (Department of Comprehensive Statistics of National Bureau of Statistics, China Statistics Press, 1999). The industrial growth rate and exchange rate are taken from International Financial Statistics Yearbook 2000 (IMF). B. The Estimation Method. The econometric method is based on panel data techniques (Islam, 1995) contrary to Chen and Feng (2000) who use cross-sectional data. A fixed effects estimator is applied, it allows to take into account some unobserved provincial heterogeneity. The random effects model has been rejected because of the correlation between provincial effects and explanatory variables. A White test rejects the null of homoskedasticity at the 10% level and thus the variancecovariance matrix is corrected for heteroskedasticity. The null of no serial correlation cannot be rejected. A RESET test does not detect at the 10% level a wrong specification. C. The Results. GROWTHit = 0.26 – 0.07.GDPit + 0.003.ICGROWTHt - 2.91.POPGRit (0.0) (0.0) (0.16) (0.007) + 5.54E-09.POPit – 0.13.INFLAit + 0.11.FDIit – 0.60.SOEit (0.004) (0.005) (0.06) (0.004) + 0.34.WESTERNit + 0.54.CENTRALit + .0.61.COASTALit (0.27) (0.05) (0.007) R2 adjusted = 0.60 10 P values are between brackets. Underlined coefficients, which are elasticities, are averaged over coefficients for provinces. All variables take the expected sign4. More particularly, the coefficient for initial GDP per capita is significant and negative, so, we cannot reject the hypothesis of conditional β-convergence between provinces. Guillaumont and Boyreau Debray (1996), Jian, Sachs and Warner (1996), Chen and Fleisher (1996) and Chen and Feng (2000) report similar results. 5 Of course, this result does not mean a trend towards a reduction of the GDP per capita inequalities between provinces. In fact, conditional β-convergence conducts to different provinces steady-state level per capita output. For instance, the high level of FDI in coastal regions gives them a higher level of welfare in the long run. Investment decisions are endogenous to growth. So, after controlling, the variable of investment only captures the autonomous part of investment. Hence, it appears that the investment ratio does not increase the explanatory power of the equation6. The weak significance of the variable ICGROWTHt reflects the low dependence of the Chinese economy vis-à-vis the rest of the world. The growth of coastal provinces affects differently the grouping of provinces considered. Regarding western regions, the impact is positive but non-significant. On the reverse, coastal 4 We also test without success the impact of initial human capital with a variable calculated as the number of students enrolled in tertiary schools relative the total population. Unfortunately, we do not dispose of the correct denominator, which should be the total population of the corresponding age group. Moreover, variables like that of Barro and Lee (1993) are not available for Chinese provinces. 5 Cf. Naughton (2001) for a discussion of these results. 11 growth acts positively and significantly on central provinces. Moreover, spillover effects can be observed within coastal provinces. So, this result tends to show that coastal growth benefits in an unequal way to inland provinces. Central provinces seem to take more advantages than western provinces from coastal development. With a different theoretical framework (coreperiphery model), and a different method (detection of spatial auto-correlation), Ying (2000) does not reject the hypothesis of an unequal diffusion of coastal growth between inland provinces. For instance, he observes that the spillover effects are more evident for the provinces near Guangdong. Some explanations can help to understand our results. The first one is that location and geography matter in the diffusion of growth (Moreno and Trehan, 1997) either via transportation costs or via monitoring costs (confidence, common knowledge) which decrease with cultural proximity probably correlated with geographical proximity. The second one is that some kinds of spillovers are particularly effective in cities (Glaeser, Kallal, Scheinkman, and Shleifer, 1992). The reason is due to agglomeration effects, certainly more developed in the central provinces, where there are more cities than in western provinces. The third explanation probably comes from differences in the level of development. The western regions may be not benefit from the coastal growth as the economic distance reduces, even annihilates, regional spillovers. 6 An attempt to use instrumental variables techniques for investment did not permit to show a significant impact of investment. 12 III. Conclusion. This paper will be prolonged in three ways. First, it will be useful to explain for each inland province, the coastal contribution to economic growth. Second, it will be pertinent to identify more precisely which coastal regions are the sources of spillovers. Third, the spillover effects will be more appraised with infra regional data. Nevertheless, our results allow us to draw some remarks. The relative failure to boost development of western provinces from coastal regions growth or ladder step policy, shows that it is an illusion to hope that spillover effects may be sufficient in the short term to reduce disparities between Chinese provinces. Now, the stake is crucial for Chinese social stability and to avoid the risks of fragmentation and inter-regional massive migrations. This observation conducts the Central Government to give the priority to public investment in western regions in the next Five Years Plan (2001-2005). The target is to help these provinces to take more profit from their international comparative advantages. We may think that if an outward looking strategy is implemented by every region, less disparities may be expected. But anyway, the Central Government will keep a crucial role by its redistribution policy through public finance ie structural transfers. IV. References. Barro R.J., 1991, “Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries” Quarterly journal of Economics, 106, 407-443. 13 Barro R.J. and Lee J.W.,1993, “International Comparisons of Educational attainment”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 32, 363-394. Barro R.J. and Sala-I-Martin X., 1995, Economic Growth, New-York, McGraw-Hill. Brun J.-F., Chambas G. and Combes J.-L.,1998, “Politique fiscale et croissance”, Revue d’Economie du Développement, 2, 115-125. Chen J. et Fleisher B., 1996, “Regional Income Inequality and Economic Growth in China”, Journal of Comparative Economics, 22, 141-164. Chen B. and Feng Y., 2000, “Determinants of Economic Growth in China: Private Enterprise, Education, and Openess”, China Economic Review, 11, 1-15. Chen C., Chang L. and Zhang Y. 1995, “The Role of Foreign Direct Investment in China’s Post-1978 Economic Development”, World Development, 23(4). De Mello L.R., 1997, “Foreign Direct Investment in Developing Countries and Growth: a Selective Survey”, Journal of Development Studies, 34(1), 1-34. Glaeser, E.L., Kallal H.D., Scheinkman J.A. and Shleifer A., 1992 “ Growth in Cities ” Journal of Political Economy, 100, 1126-52. Goodman D.S.G. and Segal G., ed., 1994, China Deconstructs, Politics, Trade and Regionalism, Routledge, London. Grossman G.M. and Helpman E., 1991 Innovations and Growth in the Global Economy, MIT Press, Cambridge. Guillaumont P. and Boyreau Debray G.,1996,“La Chine et la convergence”, Revue d’Economie du Développement, 1/2, 33-67. Islam N.,1995, “Growth Empirics: A Panel Data Approach”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 1127-1170. Jian T., Sachs J. and Warner A., 1996, “Trends in Regional Inequality in China”, China Economic Review, 7(1), 1-21 Marshall A., 1919, Industry and Trade, French translation 1934, M. Giard, Paris. 14 Moreno R. and Trehan B., 1997, “Location and the Growth of Nations” Journal of Economic Growth, 2, 399-418. Naughton B., 2001, “Provincial Economic Growth in China: Causes and Consequences of Regional Differentiation” in Renard M.-F. Renard M.F., ed., 2001, China and its Regions: Economic Growth and Reform in Chinese Provinces, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham. Yang D.,1997, Beyond Beijing, Liberalization and the Regions in China, Routledge, London. Ying L.G., 2000, “Measuring the Spillover Effects: Some Chinese Evidence”, Papers in Regional Science, 79, 75-89. 15