Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Why the Fed’s $4.1 trillion balance sheet isn’t creating inflation Market Outlook | March 2014 merchandise is the velocity. In order to double the number of parcels delivered one can either double the number of trucks, double their delivery speed or a combination of both. Velocity is assumed to be roughly constant by monetarists. This relationship between money supply, its velocity and the dollar value of GDP is not controversial because it is an identity and therefore must always hold in hindsight. However, concluding from it that the Fed’s balance sheet expansion must automatically lead to high inflation is problematic on several counts: In spite of the IMF’s recent warning about reemerging deflationary risk, especially in the eurozone, a recurring question in many client conversations is: Why hasn’t US inflation reared its ugly head following the massive injection of Fed liquidity of about USD 3.2 trillion since Lehman’s collapse? The notion that inflation should be much higher than the paltry 1.6% recorded in the Consumer Price Index (CPI) in January emanates from the deeply entrenched monetarist school of thought exemplified by its founder, the late Milton Friedman, and his claim that “inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon.” By clarifying the monetarist framework, its key assumptions and some popular misconceptions about it, we explain why this simple rule of thumb has not been useful to understand the path of inflation in this cycle. To make our point, we start with the monetarist framework, which relies on a classic relationship that links the money supply to the dollar value of Gross Domestic Product (GDP). The latter captures both the quantity of goods and services produced in the economy and their price level. The key is to understand that the missing link between money supply and GDP is the speed at which the money supply is turned over to generate purchases of goods and services. Economists call this turnover rate the velocity of money. The velocity of money can be thought of as the number of times a dollar in circulation is used in transactions during a given period. To illustrate this relationship, think of a courier service. The number of packages corresponds to GDP, the fleet of vehicles is money supply and the speed at which the trucks deliver First, an important misconception concerns the right measure of money supply. The money supply the Fed controls directly by expanding its balance sheet is called central bank money (or M0) and represents currency in circulation (all bank notes and coins) and bank reserves held at the Fed. It is not the money supply concept used in the monetarist framework. Economists usually rely on broader monetary aggregates (called M1 or M2), which include checking and savings accounts and which therefore represent the money supply in the broader financial system to which not only banks but also businesses and consumers have access. They therefore have a much stronger connection with GDP. During the Great Recession, the massive credit crunch that affected the financial system broke the usual link between central bank money and broader monetary aggregates. So while the Fed has pumped about USD 3.2 trillion into the banking system, M1 and M2 have grown at a much more moderate pace (see Fig. 1), suggesting a much tamer inflation outlook than M0 would. Second, a key assumption made by monetarists is that the velocity of money is stable or fairly constant over time. In practice, this is not the case. In fact, money velocity has fallen from about 2 before the Great Recession to about 1.6 recently, a 20% reduction (see Fig. 2). Therefore, over this period we have in effect seen a 20% deflationary shock that helps absorb the growth in money supply, as a constant money supply would have led to a 20% decrease in purchases of goods and services over a comparable time period. The decline in the velocity of money is largely a result of the credit crunch in the financial system as businesses and consumers struggled to obtain financing for purchases. This credit crunch is still in the process of resolving itself. Third, monetarists believed that the increase in money supply would eventually show up in a proportionate increase in the prices of goods and services, as it was unlikely to provide a lasting boost to the quantities of goods and services produced or real GDP. The implicit assumption behind this claim is that the economy was already operating close to full capacity or full employment, so that any stimulation of aggregate demand would hit capacity constraints and lead to price increases rather than an increase in real GDP. But the depth of the Great Recession has left the US economy operating well below its long-run potential. The Congressional Budget Office estimates that the US economy is currently operating about 3.8% below its potential, the largest gap since the 1980s, excluding the recent recession. This is crucial, since price pressures cannot easily emerge when the economy is operating far below potential. Under such circumstances, the rational response by businesses to accelerating consumer demand is to increase production and gain market share, not to increase prices. The link between the clogged credit system, the abundant slack in resource utilization (labor and capital) and low inflation is well understood by the Fed. This is why the Fed was emboldened to embark on QE3, why its exit strategy is a slow and gradual one and why the first rate hike in this cycle is unlikely to happen before mid-2015. From an investment perspective, this supports our preference for stocks over bonds over a tactical horizon. The mere fact that we are in the process of exiting ultra-loose monetary policy suggests that Treasury bond yields will continue to rise over the next 12 months, creating pressure across bond markets. However, without any significant inflation risk, the prospect for a massive sell-off in bonds appears very limited. For equities, on the other hand, an accelerating economy combined with a slow Fed exit creates a sweet spot for this asset class. With valuations now at their historical average levels, investors should not count on equities becoming more expensive via multiple expansions as the key driver of returns, as was the case in 2013. However, with earnings likely to grow at about 8% this year, even flat valuations should allow equities to outperform bonds and cash. Let’s talk about it The above was taken from CIO Wealth Management Research’s UBS House View: Investment Strategy Guide (March 2014). To obtain a copy of this report and discuss how its research insights can help you make better investment decisions, please contact a UBS Financial Advisor. ©UBS 2014. The key symbol and UBS are among the registered and unregistered trademarks of UBS. All rights reserved. UBS Financial Services Inc. is a subsidiary of UBS AG. Member FINRA/SIPC. MOC_Mar_2014_public