Download general assessment of the macroeconomic situation

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Financialization wikipedia , lookup

International monetary systems wikipedia , lookup

Global saving glut wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
OECD Economic Outlook, Volume 2015 Issue 2
© OECD 2015
Chapter 1
GENERAL ASSESSMENT
OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
9
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Introduction
Global growth prospects have clouded this year. A further sharp slowdown in
emerging market economies (EMEs) is weighing on global activity and trade, and subdued
investment and productivity growth is checking the momentum of the recovery in the
advanced economies. Supportive macroeconomic policies and lower commodity prices are
projected to strengthen global growth gradually through 2016 and 2017, but this outcome is
far from certain given rising downside risks and vulnerabilities, and uncertainties about
the path of policies and the response of trade and investment.
The outlook for the EMEs is a key source of global uncertainty at present, given their
large contribution to global trade and GDP growth. In China, ensuring a smooth rebalancing
of the economy, whilst avoiding a sharp reduction in GDP growth and containing financial
stability risks, presents challenges. A more significant slowdown in Chinese domestic
demand could hit financial market confidence and the growth prospects of many
economies, including the advanced economies. For EMEs more broadly, challenges have
increased, reflecting weaker commodity prices, tighter credit conditions and lower
potential output growth, with the risk that capital outflows and sharp currency
depreciations may expose financial vulnerabilities. Growth would also be hit in the euro
area, as well as Japan, where the short-run impact of past stimulus has proved weaker than
anticipated and uncertainty remains about future policy choices.
There are increasing signs that the anticipated path of potential output may fail to
materialise in many economies, requiring a reassessment of monetary and fiscal policy
strategies. The risk of such an outcome underlines the importance of implementing
productivity-raising structural policies, alongside measures to reduce persisting negative
supply effects from past demand weakness in labour markets and capital investment,
whilst ensuring that macroeconomic policies continue to support growth and stability.
Early and decisive actions to spur reductions in greenhouse gas emissions via predictable
paths of policy including tax reforms, or public investment programmes, or action on
research and development might also help to support short-term growth and improve
longer-term prospects, as discussed in Chapter 2.
The outlook
Global growth has eased to around 3% this year, well below its long-run average. This
largely reflects further weakness in EMEs (Figure 1.1). Deep recessions have emerged in
Brazil and Russia, whilst the ongoing slowdown in China and the associated weakness of
commodity prices has hit activity in key trading partners and commodity exporting
economies, and increased financial market uncertainty. Global trade growth has slowed
markedly, especially in the EMEs (Figure 1.2), and financial conditions have become less
supportive in most economies (Figure 1.3). Growth in the OECD economies has held up this
year, at around 2%, implying a modest reduction in economic slack, helped by an upturn in
private consumption growth. However, business investment remains subdued, raising
10
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Figure 1.1. Global GDP growth is set to recover slowly
Year-on-year percentage changes
%
%
8
8
World
OECD
non-OECD
7
7
6
6
5
5
4
4
3
3
2
2
1
1
0
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
0
2017
Source: OECD Economic Outlook 98 database.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295759
questions about future potential growth rates and about the extent to which stronger
growth in the advanced economies can help to overcome cyclical weakness in the EMEs.
Global growth is projected to strengthen slowly over the course of 2016-17, against a
background of subdued inflationary pressures (Table 1.1).
●
Supportive macroeconomic policies (Annex 1.1), lower commodity prices and a further
steady improvement in labour market outcomes should continue to underpin the upturn
in the advanced economies, with OECD GDP growth projected to average 2¼ per cent per
annum over the next two years (Figure 1.4). The decline in oil prices since mid-2014
could add between ¼ and ½ percentage point to OECD GDP growth in 2016, with the
further drop of over 20% since June 2015 contributing around 0.1-0.2 percentage point of
Figure 1.2. Global import volume growth has slowed this year
Y-o-y % changes
8
Y-o-y % changes
8
World
OECD
non-OECD
6
6
4
4
2
2
0
0
-2
-2
-4
Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4
Q1
2012
Q2
Q3
Q4
Q1
2013
Q2
Q3
2014
Q4
Q1
Q2
Q3
-4
2015
Source: OECD Economic Outlook 98 database.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295763
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
11
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Table 1.1. The global recovery will gain momentum only slowly
OECD area, unless noted otherwise
Average
2003-2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2015
2016
Q4 / Q4
2017
2017
Per cent
Real GDP growth1
World2
4.0
3.2
3.3
2.9
3.3
3.6
2.8
3.6
3.5
OECD2
United States
Euro area
Japan
1.7
1.8
0.9
0.8
1.2
1.5
-0.3
1.6
1.9
2.4
0.9
-0.1
2.0
2.4
1.5
0.6
2.2
2.5
1.8
1.0
2.3
2.4
1.9
0.5
1.9
2.1
1.6
1.1
2.4
2.6
1.9
1.4
2.2
2.3
2.0
-0.1
Non-OECD2
China
6.7
10.5
5.0
7.7
4.7
7.3
3.7
6.8
4.2
6.5
4.6
6.2
3.5
6.6
4.6
6.4
4.6
6.1
Output gap3
-0.3
-2.5
-2.2
-1.8
-1.2
-0.6
Unemployment rate4
7.0
7.9
7.3
6.8
6.5
6.3
6.8
6.4
6.3
Inflation5
1.0
1.4
1.5
0.8
1.5
1.9
0.9
1.6
2.1
-4.6
-4.1
-3.8
-3.3
-2.8
-2.3
5.6
3.3
3.4
2.0
3.6
4.8
1.4
4.4
4.9
Fiscal balance6
Memorandum Items
World real trade growth
1. Year-on-year increase; last three columns show the increase over a year earlier.
2. Moving nominal GDP weights, using purchasing power parities.
3. Per cent of potential GDP.
4. Per cent of labour force.
5. Private consumption deflator. Year-on-year increase; last 3 columns show the increase over a year earlier.
6. Per cent of GDP.
Source: OECD Economic Outlook 98 database.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933296655
Figure 1.3. Financial conditions in advanced economies have become less supportive
OECD financial conditions index
8
6
8
United States
Japan
Euro area
6
4
4
2
2
0
0
-2
-2
-4
-4
-6
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
-6
Note: The OECD Financial Conditions Index is a weighted average of real short and long-term interest rates, real exchange rate, bank
credit conditions, household wealth and the yield spread between corporate and government long-term bonds. A unit increase (decline)
in the index implies an easing (tightening) in financial conditions sufficient to produce an average increase (reduction) in the level of GDP
of ½ to 1% after four to six quarters. See details in Guichard et al. (2009). Based on available information up to 30 October 2015.
Source: OECD Economic Outlook 98 database; Thomson Reuters; and OECD calculations.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295776
12
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Figure 1.4. GDP growth projections for the major economies
A. Real GDP growth in the OECD
Y-o-y % changes
3.0
B. Real GDP growth in the non-OECD
2014
2015
2016
2017
2.5
Y-o-y % changes
8
2014
2015
2016
2017
6
2.0
4
1.5
2
1.0
0
0.5
-2
0.0
-4
-0.5
OECD
Japan
United States
non-OECD
Euro area - 15
China
Brazil
-6
Indonesia
India
Russia
Source: OECD Economic Outlook 98 database.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295788
this.1 Growth in the United States is set to remain relatively solid, at around 2½ per cent
per annum, with strong household consumption growth and a moderate upturn in
private sector investment outweighing the impact of the US dollar appreciation over the
past year and weaker energy sector activity. The so far muted recovery in the euro area
is set to strengthen somewhat, with GDP growth at around 1¾-2% per annum over
2016-17, helped by the continued accommodative monetary policy stance and the
stimulatory impact of lower oil prices. Fiscal support of up to ¼ per cent of GDP to assist
asylum seekers should provide a small additional stimulus to demand. The outlook for
Japan remains softer than in other advanced economies, despite an anticipated upturn
in real wage growth. This reflects a larger drag exerted by weak external demand,
especially in Asia, and strong fiscal headwinds, particularly from the further
consumption tax increase planned for 2017. Given the modest upturn projected in
domestic and global activity, a gentle strengthening of investment spending is projected
in the OECD economies over 2016-17. Business investment growth is projected to rise by
just under 4¼ per cent per annum in the next two years, after rising by an estimated 3¼
per cent per annum over 2014-2015.
●
Growth in the EMEs is projected to turn up through 2016-17, helped initially by the easing
of the sharp downturns in 2015 in the major commodity producers and the small open
Asian economies. Even so, growth prospects are likely to continue to diverge in the large
EMEs (Figure 1.4). A gradual slowdown is projected to continue in China, with GDP
growth easing to 6¼ per cent by 2017 and import penetration declining. New fiscal
measures announced this year, worth up to 1½ per cent of GDP, along with small
additional measures in the next two years should help to support demand but will check
the pace at which the economy rebalances. Growth prospects in India should remain
relatively robust, provided further progress is made in implementing structural reforms.
1. Estimates relative to a baseline with oil prices held at their mid-2014 levels, based on simulations
using the NiGEM global macroeconomic model, augmented with OECD estimates of supply
responses in OECD net oil exporters and the United States. Oil prices are assumed to be $50 per
barrel from the fourth quarter of 2015 onwards.
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
13
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
This reflects the more positive outlook for investment and consumption and its position
as a major net importer of commodities. Despite large currency depreciations, recovery
will be only gradual in Brazil and Russia as confidence firms after an initial stabilisation
of activity, given soft external demand, still high inflation and limited space for
macroeconomic policy support. Growth in Indonesia should pick up slowly, helped by
the implementation of plans to boost infrastructure investment.
Inflationary pressures remain weak in the major OECD economies and in China, but
have edged up in several other EMEs, particularly those in which large currency
depreciations have occurred.
●
Headline consumer price inflation has fallen in recent months in the OECD economies,
following the further sharp decline in commodity prices, and market-based measures of
inflation expectations have edged down further. Core inflation has remained
comparatively stable, at low levels, reflecting persistent economic slack and weak import
prices, particularly in the United States where the effective exchange rate has
appreciated by around 15% over the past year. In the absence of significant further
moves in commodity prices, exchange rates and inflation expectations, core inflation
(excluding food and energy prices) should generally remain weak over the next two years
in the advanced economies, edging up marginally as economic slack declines and the
transitory effects of past changes in commodity prices and exchange rates fade
(Figure 1.5). Inflation is projected to be around 1¾ per cent by the latter part of 2017 in the
United States, where the recovery is relatively advanced, but remain between 1¼ and 1½
per cent in euro area and Japan.2
Figure 1.5. Inflation is likely to remain weak
Annual rate of change in core consumer prices
%
%
2.0
2.0
1.5
1.5
1.0
1.0
0.5
0.5
0.0
0.0
United States
Japan
Euro area - 15
-0.5
-1.0
2013
2014
-0.5
2015
2016
2017
-1.0
Note: Consumer prices excluding food and energy. The private consumption deflator is used for the United States. Data for Japan exclude
the estimated impact of the consumption tax increases in April 2014 and April 2017.
Source: OECD Economic Outlook 98 database.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295790
2. The assumed rise in the consumption tax rate in Japan will boost the consumer price level by
around 1¼ percentage point in April 2017.
14
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
●
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Amongst the major EMEs, consumer price inflation is set to remain relatively low in
China and India, helped by weak import price pressures. Inflation is projected to remain
stronger for some time in countries such as Russia, Brazil and Indonesia, due to the
impact of sizeable past currency depreciations and, in Russia, sanctions, although
widening economic slack should eventually help to ease cost pressures.
Labour markets should continue to improve in the major OECD economies (Table 1.2).
●
The OECD-wide unemployment rate has declined by 1 percentage point since 2013,
amidst improved job growth. A further decline of ½ percentage point is projected over
2016-2017, with employment continuing to rise by just under 1% per year (Table 1.2). This
pace is below that observed in 2014-15, with demographic factors limiting the feasible
pace of job growth in the United States and Japan (Aaronson et al., 2014). Unemployment
is projected to decline to, or stay below, pre-crisis rates in the United States and Japan,
but remain comparatively high in the aggregate euro area (Figure 1.6), where persisting
negative supply effects from past demand weakness are relatively strong and there
remains considerable cross-country dispersion in labour market developments.
●
Wage pressures are set to remain moderate, although some upturn is likely as price
inflation and productivity growth pick up and unemployment declines (Figure 1.6).
Labour market slack is, however, more extensive than suggested by claimant-based
unemployment rates alone. Broader measures of unemployment, incorporating parttime workers who want to work full-time and inactive persons wanting to work (but not
actively seeking a job), remain well above pre-crisis norms in many economies, including
the United States and the euro area. This may help to damp wage growth for some time
to come.
Table 1.2. OECD labour market conditions will improve slowly
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
Percentage change from previous period
Employment
United States
Euro area
Japan
OECD
1.8
-0.6
-0.3
1.0
1.0
-0.6
0.7
0.7
1.6
0.6
0.6
1.3
1.7
0.9
0.2
1.2
0.9
1.0
-0.3
0.9
0.7
1.1
-0.2
0.9
Labour force
United States
Euro area
Japan
OECD
0.9
0.7
-0.6
1.0
0.3
0.2
0.3
0.7
0.3
0.1
0.2
0.7
0.8
0.2
0.0
0.7
0.3
0.4
-0.4
0.5
0.7
0.5
-0.3
0.6
Unemployment rate
United States
Euro area
Japan
OECD
8.1
11.3
4.3
7.9
7.4
11.9
4.0
7.9
4.7
10.4
3.2
6.5
4.7
9.8
3.1
6.3
Source:
Per cent of labour force
6.2
11.5
3.6
7.3
5.3
10.9
3.4
6.8
OECD Economic Outlook 98 database.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933296668
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
15
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Figure 1.6. Labour market outcomes should improve gradually in the major OECD economies
A. Unemployment rate
B. Compensation per employee
% of labour force
14
OECD
United States
Japan
Euro area - 15
12
2014
2015
2016
2017
Y-o-y % changes
3.5
3.0
10
2.5
8
2.0
6
1.5
4
1.0
2
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
OECD
0.5
Japan
United States
Euro area - 15
Source: OECD Economic Outlook 98 database.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295803
●
The large inflows of new asylum seekers in Europe could also influence labour market
outcomes through the next two years. Their impact will depend on the support that can
be given to help new refugees integrate, the extent to which regulations allow them to
enter the labour force and their skill mix (Box 1.1). Labour force growth in the euro area
is projected to rise to 0.5% per annum over 2016-17, from 0.2% per annum over 2013-15,
helped in part by stronger supply in Germany as a result of net immigration from outside
the EU. At the margin, this could ease emerging wage pressures in the comparativelytight German labour market. In the longer term, net immigration from outside the EU
can also help to moderate demographic pressures due to population ageing.
Box 1.1. The labour market and fiscal impact of the European refugee surge
Europe is facing its biggest refugee inflow since World War II. Estimating the number of arrivals remains
very challenging, but over one million asylum applications could be received this year in the European
Union (EU), up from 630 thousand applications in 2014, with an estimated 350-450 thousand people likely
to be granted refugee or other humanitarian status (equivalent to 0.07-0.09% of the EU population). Large
inflows of asylum seekers are also continuing in Turkey, where the number of registered refugees from
Syria alone is now above 2 million, having risen so far in 2015 by over 350 thousand people. Additional
sizeable arrivals seem possible over 2016-17, including from follow-on migration arising from “friends and
family” type effects (Mitchell et al., 2011).
The numbers and the heterogeneity of the new refugees make this inflow particularly difficult to address
(OECD, 2015d,e). Asylum seekers are arriving from a diverse group of countries (across MENA, South Asia
and Eastern Europe), and with a varied range of skills. This has put a strain on processing and settlement
systems, and raises the challenges involved in integrating new arrivals into societies. The upfront costs of
integrating asylum seekers are also likely to be higher than for economic migrants. The numbers of new
entrants have also resulted in some temporary border closures within the Schengen area. Appropriate
policy choices in host countries can help to minimise the possible short-run challenges of absorbing a
16
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Box 1.1. The labour market and fiscal impact of the European refugee surge (cont.)
sudden large inflow of new asylum applicants and maximise the longer-run benefits that might result. A
key point is to ensure that there are no barriers that prevent newly-accepted refugees from ultimately
moving to locations in the EU that reflect economic conditions rather than other differences.
The new surge of asylum seekers into the European Union comes on top of an already-sizeable number
of economic migrants into the area, although both are small relative to aggregate EU population (see figure
below). In 2014, there were nearly 1 million immigrants to the EU-28 from non-member countries. The
number of individuals who gained refugee or other humanitarian status, on a first-time decision basis, was
around 160 thousand, less than half of the numbers expected in 2015, with further decisions likely in 2016.
The new EU arrivals in 2015 seem likely to largely settle in three economies – Germany (where around 900
thousand new asylum seekers are anticipated), Austria and Sweden (where 140-190 thousand new asylum
seekers are projected this year and 100-170 thousand in 2016). Most other EU economies will receive a small
number of new arrivals.
Effects on fiscal positions
Estimating the economic impact on host-nations of the sharp rise in refugees is difficult for a number of
reasons: there is limited research on the impact of large refugee inflows on advanced economies, with most
research focusing on the impact of increased total immigration (of which the share of refugees is usually
quite small); different countries have different lags associated with the time it takes to process asylumseekers, and further lags and restrictions may be associated with the ability for refugees to enter into local
labour markets. The unprecedented nature and uniqueness of the current crisis makes it difficult to draw
lessons from previous episodes.
Estimates of the short to medium-term fiscal impact of total immigration are quite varied across studies,
but usually small, with some indicating net fiscal benefits and others net fiscal costs to host countries
(OECD, 2013b; Dustman and Fratini, 2014). Short-term expenditure required to help support newly-arrived
asylum seekers include: humanitarian assistance to provide food and shelter and basic income support;
up-front expenditures associated with necessary language training and schooling; steps to identify the true
skills of migrants and the expenditures associated with processing additional asylum claims. Additional
support may be required in the medium term to assist new entrants enter the labour market. A possible
longer-term benefit from the new arrivals is that they will help to improve the sustainability of pension
systems, particularly in economies where there might otherwise be pressures due to population ageing.
In most of the main countries affected by the present surge of asylum seekers, the additional
expenditures announced so far have been relatively modest. Germany has projected an additional ¼ per
cent of GDP support this year and ½ per cent of GDP support per annum through to 2017 to meet initial
needs of newly-arrived immigrants and to integrate them in the labour market. Austria projects that
spending on refugees and asylum seekers will rise from 0.1% of GDP in 2014 to 0.15% of GDP in 2015 and
0.3% of GDP in 2016. Sweden, which has been a major host country for refugees for a number of years, has
budgeted for additional spending in 2016 of 0.9% of GDP to improve the integration of newly-arrived
immigrants. Hungary, an important transit country into the Schengen area, has announced additional
spending of 0.1% of GDP in 2015, to cover costs associated with the new flows of refugees. Since 2011, the
Turkish government has provided aid to Syrian refugees amounting to 0.8% of 2014 GDP. The European
Commission has announced funding of €9.2 billion to address the refugee crisis over 2015-16 (0.1% of EU
GDP).
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
17
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Box 1.1. The labour market and fiscal impact of the European refugee surge (cont.)
The number of refugees into Europe is rising
but still small compared with total net migration
In per cent of total EU population as at the beginning of the year
%
0.30
%
0.30
Net migration¹
Refugee and other humanitarian protection²
0.25
0.25
0.20
0.20
0.15
0.15
0.10
0.10
0.05
0.05
0.00
2005-2008
2009-2013
2014
0.00
Net migration is calculated as the residual from the change in total population, subtracting births and adding deaths. For the
purpose of comparisons over time, statistical adjustments for Italy in 2012 and 2013 have been subtracted from the total net
migration figures for EU28.
Data from 2008 onwards refer to the number of positive first-time decisions in a given year. Pre-2008 data represent the number of
total decisions (first-time or otherwise). 2007 data do not include estimates for Belgium, Italy or the Netherlands.
Source: Eurostat; and ISTAT.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295939
These additional fiscal measures should provide a modest boost to aggregate demand, provided they are
not offset by budgetary cuts elsewhere, with most of the public funds spent on non-tradable goods and
services. In addition, the marginal propensity to consume of refugees will likely be quite high, given their
low income levels. In the European economies as a whole in 2016 and 2017, the boost to aggregate demand
could be worth between 0.1 and 0.2% of GDP.
Effects on labour markets
The initial impact of higher asylum seekers on the labour force will depend upon the success of asylumseekers in gaining refugee status, the length of the application process, and whether or not they will enter
the labour force. These factors vary considerably across EU countries, types of immigrants and over time.
In general, the effects on host country labour markets should build up over time as refugees become better
integrated.
18
●
In Germany the period of time taken to obtain refugee status declined to under 5½ months by the first
half of 2015 (Newhouse, 2015), compared to an average processing time of close to a year as of 2012.
●
Refugees are eligible to enter the labour markets of host countries. Asylum applicants may also be able
to enter host country labour markets, but this varies across countries. For example, asylum seekers in
Sweden are eligible to enter the labour force immediately, including via apprenticeship and training
schemes, in Germany there is a 3-month wait (after application), in France a 9-month wait and in the
United Kingdom a 12-month wait.
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Box 1.1. The labour market and fiscal impact of the European refugee surge (cont.)
For the European Union as a whole, the labour market participation rate of those born in non-EU
countries has, on average, been marginally lower than for EU citizens, at around 70-75% (Eurostat, 2015), but
this varies considerably by the age, skills and gender of migrants.
The impact of refugee arrivals on the destination labour market will depend on current labour market
conditions and institutions, the skills and characteristics of the new arrivals, and labour and product
market regulations.
●
A prompt evaluation of the existing skill-sets of recent arrivals will allow authorities to better relocate
migrants to local areas where demand outstrips supply for the specific type of labour. Skill matching
tends to be a problem for immigrants, more generally, as they tend to be more overqualified for their
jobs than native workers in host nations (OECD / European Union, 2015). Ensuring a wider recognition
of the foreign qualifications of immigrants would also help (OECD, 2014b).
●
Ensuring that immigrants are included in active labour market programmes can enable them to make
a quick transition into employment (OECD, 2012; OECD, 2014b).
●
More generally, there is a need to ensure that new arrivals are eventually able to move freely across
different EU countries. This should help to increase the longer-term supply-side benefits of the new
arrivals.
●
Employment protection legislation (EPL) may affect the ability of refugees to enter the labour force and
find employment and also the extent of their participation in the informal economy. Some countries,
including Germany and Austria, have been proactive in addressing labour market access concerns for
refugees (OECD, 2015e).
●
Product market regulation (PMR) can also affect the integration of newly arrived refugees into the
labour market. More regulated product and labour markets can mean that an increase in the labour
force share of immigrants weakens the employment prospects of the native population in the shortterm, although this effect typically disappears in the medium-term (Jean and Jimenez, 2007).
●
The sharp increase in refugees into Turkey in recent years is thought to have affected both informal
and formal labour markets (Del Carpio and Wagner, 2015); refugees have displaced informal domestic
workers but have pushed formal wages up through increased demand for goods and services.
Main issues and risks for economic prospects
The weakness of global trade
A key uncertainty stems from the unexpectedly sharp slowdown in world trade
growth this year, to an estimated 2%. Over the past five decades there have been only five
other years in which global trade growth has been 2% or less, all of which coincided with a
marked downturn of global growth (Figure 1.7). In part, the current trade slowdown reflects
weaker global GDP growth. But the slowdown has been more pronounced than might have
been expected on the basis of past relationships with global output growth, even given the
post-crisis decline in the elasticity of trade to output. In the early stages of the recovery,
moderate trade growth largely reflected weak demand in the advanced economies,
especially in the trade-intensive euro area (Ollivaud and Schwellnus, 2015). More recently,
the weakness stems from the EMEs. A substantial proportion of the overall slowdown in
global trade growth this year relative to 2014 is accounted for by a decline in import
volumes in the non-OECD economies (Figure 1.2), reflecting both weaker demand growth
and a reduction in import intensity. This has contributed to weaker external demand in the
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
19
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Figure 1.7. Global trade growth is unusually weak this year
Year-on-year percentage changes
%
%
15
15
World Trade growth
World GDP growth
12
12
9
9
6
6
3
3
0
0
-3
-3
-6
-6
-9
-9
-12
1965
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
2015
-12
Note: Global trade is goods plus services trade volumes. Global GDP growth in purchasing power parities.
Source: OECD Economic Outlook 98 database.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295818
advanced economies. All told, the slowdown in non-OECD import demand this year and
next, relative to earlier projections (OECD, 2015a), is likely to reduce OECD GDP growth by
0.4 percentage point per annum, all else equal.
There are a number of factors contributing to the weakness in non-OECD trade:
●
Import volumes have fallen this year by over 10% in Brazil and over 20% in Russia,
reflecting deep recessions and, in Russia, the continued impact of sanctions. These
declines account directly for just under one-third of the slowdown in non-OECD import
volume growth between 2014 and 2015 (Figure 1.8).
Figure 1.8. Non-OECD import volume growth has fallen sharply this year
Contributions to year-on-year growth of total non-OECD import volumes
% pts
7
% pts
7
China
Dynamic Asia Economies
Brazil & Russia
Other
non-OECD
6
5
6
5
4
4
3
3
2
2
1
1
0
0
-1
-1
-2
-2
-3
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
-3
Source: OECD Economic Outlook 98 database.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295824
20
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
●
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Softer import volume growth in China also accounts directly for just under one-third of
the slowdown in non-OECD import volume growth between 2014 and 2015. This reflects
both a sharp decline in Chinese export volume growth this year and the changing
composition of domestic demand (Figure 1.9):
❖ The decline in Chinese export volume growth, which reflects both weaker external
demand and a significant appreciation of the real exchange rate, is depressing imports
because of the relatively high import content of exports. This could account for around
one-half of the estimated slowdown in Chinese import volume growth from 7% in 2014
to just under 2% in 2015 under standard assumptions, as around one-third of Chinese
exports comprise imported goods and services.3 China’s loss in market share this year
is concentrated in countries whose currencies have depreciated relative to the
renminbi, including euro area countries and Japan (Figure 1.10).
❖ The rebalancing of the economy (see below) has reduced the overall import intensity
of growth, as the import intensities of consumption and service sector activity are
lower than for investment and industrial activity. The slowdown in investment growth
has in particular reduced the demand for commodity imports. Trade data for China
covering the first eight months of 2015 suggest that the quantity of imported metals
rose only marginally relative to 2014. Crude petroleum imports rose by almost 10%, but
the quantity of coal and cotton imports declined by over 30%.
❖ These developments have reinforced the longer-term tendency over the past decade
for Chinese firms to make greater use of domestically-produced intermediate inputs
in place of foreign inputs (Constantinescu et al., 2015).
❖ Even with these factors considered – rebalancing towards consumption, a higher share
of domestic intermediates and weaker external demand – Chinese import volumes
have been very weak this year relative to final expenditure, after growing broadly in
Figure 1.9. Significant changes are occurring in Chinese trade flows
A. Import penetration is now declining
%
B. Export growth has slowed sharply
%
35
15
Index 2014 = 1
1.3
Export growth
Export market growth
Relative export prices
30
10
1.2
5
1.1
0
1.0
25
20
15
Imports relative to total final expenditure
Imports relative to domestic demand
10
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016
-5
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
0.9
Note: Total final expenditure is the sum of domestic demand and exports.
Source: OECD Economic Outlook 98 database.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295834
3. Export volume growth is estimated to have slowed by around 8 percentage points between 2014
and 2015. All else equal, this would slow import volume growth by around 2.7 percentage points.
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
21
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Figure 1.10. Chinese merchandise export growth to selected partner countries
Percentage changes, US dollar values, 2015H1 over 2014H1
%
%
10
10
5
5
0
0
-5
-5
-10
-10
-15
World
United States
Japan
Euro area
Major EMEs¹
Dynamic Asia²
-15
Note: Information based on Chinese partners imports.
1. Major EMEs are Brazil, Russia, India and Indonesia.
2. Dynamic Asia is: Hong-Kong, China; Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand and Chinese Taipei.
Source: Thomson Reuters.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295847
line with respect to total final expenditure in the 2006-14 period. For 2015 as a whole,
the projected increase in import volumes (goods plus services) is only around onethird of the growth of total final expenditure.
●
The slowdown in China has damped external demand for other Asian economies,
including Japan and Korea, reflecting the integrated nature of manufacturing supply
chains in East and South-East Asia (Figure 1.11). In 2014, over a third of all merchandise
imports in China came from regional trading partners. Direct trade exposures to China
are generally weaker in the United States and the euro area, although both economies
are more heavily exposed to weaker demand in China’s main trading partners.
●
Many commodity exporters are also relatively heavily exposed to weaker demand in
China, including Chile, Australia and New Zealand. Rebalancing in China has weakened
global commodity prices and the export revenues of commodity producers, with the past
investment boom having left China as the largest source of demand in many commodity
markets, accounting for most of the increase in global demand over the past fifteen years.4
●
The on-going accumulation of trade restrictions in the major economies may also be a
factor behind the continued softening of global trade intensity, although this is unlikely
to be able to account for much of the precipitate drop in trade growth this year.5
4. China accounted for around one-half of total global demand for metals such as aluminium, copper,
nickel and zinc in 2014 and most of the overall increase in global demand since 2000. It also
accounted for 12% of global crude oil demand in 2014 and around one-half of global coal
consumption, and a substantial share of the rise in global demand since 2000. Around 80% of the
increase in global imports of soybeans, coffee and cotton since 2000 is also accounted for by China
(World Bank, 2015).
5. The number of trade restrictive measures introduced by G-20 countries since the onset of the crisis
now covers around 6% of G-20 merchandise imports (OECD/WTO/UNCTAD, 2015), although the
number of new measures introduced per month slowed slightly in the most recent six-month
period. The number of trade facilitation measures introduced has, however, not yet slowed,
although they cover only around 1% of G-20 merchandise imports.
22
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Figure 1.11. Trade linkages with China in 2014
Merchandise exports to and imports from China as a per cent of GDP
Singapore
Korea
Malaysia
Chile
Thailand
Saudi Arabia
Australia
New Zealand
Philippines
Japan
South Africa
Germany
Russia
Indonesia
Brazil
Colombia
Belgium
Switzerland
Euro area
Canada
Sweden
Argentina
Austria
France
United States
India
Italy
United Kingdom
Mexico
Spain
Turkey
Export ratio
Import ratio
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Source: International Monetary Fund Direction of Trade Statistics; and OECD calculations.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295859
Global trade growth is projected to recover gradually over the projection period, rising
broadly in line with global output growth in 2016, and by 4¾ per cent in 2017 (Table 1.3).
This would imply a rise in the trade elasticity of global growth to around 1⅓, compared with
an elasticity of around 2 prior to the financial crisis. In the OECD economies, as well as
India and Indonesia (both part of the other non-OECD in Figure 1.8), the composition of
demand is likely to slowly become more trade-intensive, as fixed investment growth picks
up relative to final consumption growth. New fiscal measures to boost infrastructure
spending in China should also help to strengthen import growth in China somewhat.
Aggregate demand will also benefit moderately from the projected fading of the present
weaknesses in many commodity producers, including Brazil and Russia. In the medium
term, the new Trans-Pacific Partnership agreement will help to boost trade growth and
global activity (Petri and Plummer, 2012). A successful conclusion to the current
negotiations on the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Agreement would provide a
further boost.
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
23
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Table 1.3. World trade will strengthen gradually
Goods and services trade
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
Percentage change from previous period
1
World trade
3.3
2.6
2.0
3.4
4.0
3.8
2.0
3.4
4.0
3.6
3.5
4.0
4.8
4.6
4.7
Trade prices2
OECD exports
OECD imports
Non-OECD exports
Non-OECD imports
0.3
-0.5
-1.8
-0.7
-1.3
-1.5
-2.9
-1.9
-12.5
-13.7
-10.8
-7.6
0.3
0.0
-0.6
0.3
1.1
1.0
2.1
2.4
Current account balances
United States
Japan
Euro area
OECD
China
-2.3
0.8
2.8
-0.1
1.6
-2.2
0.5
3.3
0.0
2.1
-2.8
2.9
3.7
0.1
2.7
-3.0
3.3
3.7
0.1
2.6
OECD
United States
Japan
Euro area
Non-OECD
China
Major oil producers
Rest of the world
World
-25
-377
40
371
383
148
281
-46
358
0
-390
23
432
362
220
169
-27
362
32
-517
124
438
260
303
-38
-4
293
35
-588
143
452
261
318
-34
-23
296
OECD exports
OECD imports
Per cent of GDP
-2.5
3.3
3.8
0.2
3.0
USD billion
94
-450
138
436
245
323
-69
-9
339
Note: Regional aggregates include intra-regional trade.
1. Growth rates of the arithmetic average of import volumes and export volumes.
2. Average unit values in dollars.
Source: OECD Economic Outlook 98 database.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933296671
The slowdown in China and associated spillovers
The outlook for China is an important vector for global growth and uncertainty, given
its large and rising contribution to trade, investment and activity.6 The large fall in Chinese
share prices since June, along with an unexpected adjustment in the exchange rate pricing
mechanism, have added to concerns about a possible sharp growth slowdown and
domestic financial fragilities, and have raised volatility in global financial markets.
Reported GDP growth has continued to moderate in 2015, to just over 6¾ per cent, as the
economy transitions from industrial to services-based growth and deals with the
6. The share of China in global import demand for goods plus services is now around 9¾ per cent, up
from around 2% in the mid-1990s. Thus, a sharp slowdown in China would now have larger
spillover effects than before.
24
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
imbalances in property and heavy industries and the high debt levels in local government
and the corporate sector (OECD, 2015c). Achieving a smooth unwinding of these
imbalances presents challenges, raising the risk that an abrupt slowdown could occur with
adverse effects for the global economy. Hence, a closer look at the economic transition in
China is warranted.
Reflecting ongoing rebalancing, consumption (public plus private) has become a
relatively more important source of growth in China than fixed investment (Figure 1.12),
even though the growth rate of both types of expenditure is now weaker than in the past.
The services sector is now the main driver of economic growth, whilst industrial
production growth has slowed sharply to the weakest rate since 2008. At the same time, the
easing of total final expenditure growth, with export volumes declining, is prompting
concerns that the slowdown in China could be deeper and progressing more rapidly than
initially thought, with negative spillover effects via trade and financial linkages.
●
Trade linkages understate the extent to which many advanced economies are exposed to
a slowdown in China, given the additional direct sales in China by the foreign affiliates
of parent companies from these countries. For instance, sales by US foreign affiliates in
China amounted to $364 billion in 2013, over twice the value of bilateral exports of goods
and services to China from the United States. Sales of the local subsidiaries of Japanese
manufacturers in China in 2014 were also almost double Japanese merchandise exports
to China. Weaker demand growth in China may thus hit the revenues and profitability of
many multinational companies, and hence their share prices, even if the parent
companies do not produce goods and services that are exported to China.
●
Direct financial linkages with China are also rising rapidly, but generally remain small
relative to total global linkages. Outstanding cross-border banking sector claims on
Chinese residents were around $760 billion as of the first quarter of 2015 (on an ultimate
Figure 1.12. Rebalancing is continuing in China
A. Expenditure shares of GDP (nominal)
B. Contribution to annual GDP growth ²
%
%
55
Total consumption ¹
Gross capital formation
9
Total consumption ¹
Gross capital formation
8
50
7
6
45
5
4
40
3
35
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2
Note: Shares do not add to 100 since the net exports share is not included in the chart.
1. Total consumption includes both public and private consumption.
2. Dots represent the contribution to the growth of GDP in the first three quarters of 2015 relative to a year earlier.
Source: OECD Economic Outlook 98 database; National Bureau of Statistics (China); and Thomson Reuters.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295864
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
25
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
risk basis), 3.1% of total cross-border claims by BIS-reporting banks. China has become
the leading location for international foreign direct investment flows in recent years
(OECD, 2015b), but only hosts around 4¼ per cent of the total global inward FDI stock
(excluding that located in Hong Kong). Nevertheless, financial spillovers may be stronger
than these data suggest, as demonstrated by the sharp reaction in global financial
markets to the large correction in Chinese share prices since June and the unexpected
depreciation of the renminbi against the US dollar in August. This was particularly
pronounced in Japan, where share prices fell sharply.
Faced with signs of a slowdown, the Chinese authorities have announced major
stimulus measures, including a range of monetary and financial policy changes to support
asset prices, credit and activity, as well as new fiscal measures worth up to 1½ per cent of
GDP. The new fiscal measures, which are about one-quarter the size of those introduced in
2009 during the global financial crisis, are largely intended to finance additional
infrastructure spending, particularly on transport networks. This support is projected to
help hold up demand, with GDP growth expected to slow modestly to 6¼ per cent by 2017,
but will inevitably slow the necessary rebalancing of expenditure that needs to occur and
entails the risk that leverage and excess industrial capacity might increase further. The
additional investment will moderate the trend reduction in the import intensity of
domestic demand, helping to underpin global trade growth. A range of other structural
policies could prove more effective for rebalancing overall, including services liberalisation
and expanding social expenditures to support household consumption growth. Measures
of this kind would help the transition in the Chinese economy, but would not offer as much
support for global trade, given the lower import intensity of consumption spending.
If Chinese domestic demand were to slow by more than currently anticipated, the
global repercussions could be sizeable (Gauvin and Rebillard, 2015) and more severe than
implied only by direct trade and financial linkages, given indirect confidence effects in
financial markets. Weaker global commodity prices and more accommodative monetary
policy could offset this in part, but a reduction of two percentage points in Chinese
domestic demand growth in 2016 and 2017, augmented by global financial stresses, could
still reduce global GDP growth by over ½ percentage point in both years (Box 1.2).
Fragilities in emerging market economies
The projected pick-up in other EMEs is conditional on a gentle growth slowdown and
rebalancing in China, stable commodity prices and exchange rates, and a recovery of
confidence that allows policy to become more accommodative. If any of these conditions fail
to hold, growth would be weaker than projected. Further currency depreciations would
exacerbate underlying inflationary pressures in some of these economies, requiring tighter
monetary policy, but providing more external stimulus. Failure to reduce political
uncertainty and restore confidence in several EMEs, including Brazil, Russia and Turkey,
would undermine growth. Commodity prices are a balanced risk. If recent conditions of
excess supply were to persist or intensify, lower commodity prices would reduce the
revenues of commodity producers, including Brazil, Chile, Mexico, Russia and other oil
producers, weigh on real activity and government revenues and weaken external positions.
Alternatively, if global demand were to strengthen more than projected, or if geopolitical
risks were to intensify, commodity prices could strengthen, raising the revenues of
commodity producers.
26
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Box 1.2. The global impact of weaker demand growth in China
The scenarios set out in this box provide an illustration of the possible economic effects that could result
from weaker growth outcomes in China, using simulations on the NiGEM macro-model. The simulations
consider the impact of a reduction of two percentage points in Chinese domestic demand growth that
persists for two years (2016 and 2017).
●
The negative spillovers via trade linkages alone would be only modest, with the decline in Chinese
domestic demand growth reducing OECD GDP growth by only between 0.1 and 0.2 percentage point per
annum. Overall, global GDP would decline by aroud ⅓ percentage point per year in 2016-17.1
●
The effects of slower demand growth in China would be stronger if they gave rise to corrections in global
financial markets, such as reductions in equity prices and higher uncertainty and risk premia, as
observed in the second half of August this year. Adding three adverse financial shocks to the initial
Chinese demand shock – a 15% decline in worldwide equity prices and a 50-basis point rise in the equity
and investment risk premia in all countries – would reduce global GDP growth by between ¾-1
percentage point per annum on average in 2016-17. The full impact of the combined shocks would be
relatively large in Japan, as well as India and Russia, reflecting comparatively strong linkages with China
or other emerging economies that trade heavily with China, and the impact of higher risk premia (see
figure, panel A).
A further decline in Chinese demand would also place additional downward pressure on commodity
prices, especially if it were driven by weaker fixed investment. In the main commodity-producing
economies this would have negative effects on incomes, but in commodity-importing economies it would
act to cushion the impact of the initial shocks on growth, whilst intensifying the disinflationary impact.
Monetary policy easing (or the expectation of future easing), given stronger disinflationary pressures, could
also affect the overall impact of the initial shocks and the effects on individual economies.
GDP growth impact of an adverse two-year domestic demand shock in China
Difference from baseline
A. Scenario 1¹
B. Scenario 2²
% pts
0.0
% pts
0.0
-0.5
-0.5
-1.0
-1.0
-1.5
-1.5
2016
2017
-2.0
CHN
IND
JPN
WORLD
RUS
2016
2017
EURO
BRA
CHN
USA
IND
JPN
WORLD
RUS
-2.0
EURO
BRA
USA
1. Panel A: Based on a decline of 2 percentage points in the growth rate of domestic demand in China for two years; a reduction
of 15% in global equity prices and a 50 basis point increase in the equity risk premium and investment risk premium in all
countries.
2. Panel B: Panel A simulation plus a 25 basis point reduction in long-term interest rates in all economies and a 15% decline in
global prices of oil and metals plus minerals.
Source: OECD Economic Outlook 98 database; and OECD calculations.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295946
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
27
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Box 1.2. The global impact of weaker demand growth in China (cont.)
●
To illustrate these effects, two additional shocks are added to the first scenario – a 15% decline in the
global prices of oil and metals and minerals, and a 25 basis point reduction in long-term interest rates in
all economies. In the advanced economies, these “shock absorbers” reduce the overall impact of the
initial demand and financial shocks by around ¼ percentage point in 2016 and 0.4 percentage point in
2017 (see figure, panel B). Nonetheless, OECD GDP growth would still be reduced by around ½ percentage
point in both 2016 and 2017. Amongst the EMEs, commodity producers such as Russia are hit by the
reduction in commodity prices, raising the impact of the initial shocks. For other EMEs, the direct
benefits from lower commodity prices and interest rates are largely offset, particularly in 2016, by the
income reductions in the EME commodity producers who are major trading partners. Overall, global GDP
growth is reduced by an average 0.7 percentage point per annum over 2016-17.
A sizeable depreciation of the renminbi would also have spillover effects for other countries, particularly
if it added to financial market volatility. It would help to support aggregate demand in China, but would
delay restructuring by making growth more export-driven. In practice, as in August this year, it would be
likely to induce currency depreciations in many other EMEs, especially close competitors with China and in
major commodity producing economies. The net result would be to limit the benefits to China.
1. Imports would fall sharply in China given the initial shock to domestic demand, reducing the overall impact of the shock on
China to a decline of around 1 percentage point per annum in GDP growth.
EMEs are also subject to possible risks associated with the eventual US monetary
policy normalisation. Along with weaker growth outcomes, the anticipation of tighter
monetary policy in the United States has contributed to greater portfolio rebalancing away
from EME assets in recent months, with gross capital inflows falling, sovereign bond
spreads widening and equity prices declining by between 10% and 15% since early May
(Figure 1.13). The eventual start of US monetary policy normalisation may heighten
volatility in financial markets and spread to EMEs, even if it would be predicated on a
Figure 1.13. Financial conditions in emerging market economies have tightened
A. MSCI Equity prices
Index 100 = 12 May 2015
115
110
Asia
Europe
B. EMBI spreads
Latin America
Asia
Europe
% pts
550
Latin America
500
105
450
100
400
95
350
90
300
85
250
80
200
75
70
2013
2014
2015
2013
2014
2015
150
Source: Thomson Reuters.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295879
28
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
healthy recovery and price stability in the United States.7 This could then trigger further
portfolio flows and asset price changes, exposing underlying vulnerabilities. The volatile
nature of investors’ sentiment, contagion and negative feedback loops make the size,
duration and economic effects of portfolio and price shifts hard to predict. Negative
spillovers to EMEs are more likely if investors reduce their risk tolerance (Box 1.3). However,
past experience indicates that over the entire US monetary policy tightening cycle overall
financial conditions in EMEs need not necessarily worsen.
EMEs have better fundamentals than before past crises, including higher foreign
exchange reserves, and some of them have arrangements to obtain emergency foreign
currency credit, but these do not necessarily insulate them from possible capital flow
reversals and financial market turbulence. 8 Some countries remain vulnerable
(Tables 1.A2.1 and 1.A2.2):
●
Foreign currency debt in several large EMEs is lower relative to GDP than before the Asian
crisis in the late 1990s (Ollivaud et al., 2015), although it has risen since 2007. The
structure of foreign gross liabilities has also improved in many EMEs, with an increasing
share of FDI and a corresponding decline in the share of debt liabilities (Obstfeld, 2015).
Nevertheless, several economies, including Chile, Mexico, Poland, Turkey and South
Africa, have attracted large bond portfolio inflows, with bond liabilities as a share of GDP
increasing in the aftermath of the global financial crisis. As past experience
demonstrates, this increases the risk of capital flow reversal when monetary policy
tightens in the advanced economies (Ahmed et al., 2015).
●
Recent currency depreciations have raised the cost of servicing debt denominated
in foreign currencies. This is especially the case in Brazil, Russia and Turkey given the
size of their exchange rate depreciations since mid-2014 and of foreign debt
denominated in foreign currencies – primarily in US dollars (Figure 1.14). The apparent
lack of widespread financial difficulties of businesses and households in these
economies so far suggests that exchange rate risks were hedged either via revenues in
foreign currencies or via financial instruments. Government interventions in some
countries have also eased the stress.9 A further possibility is that debt repayments have
not yet come due.
●
Leverage has risen substantially in many EMEs. In Brazil, China and Turkey, the debt of
non-financial corporations and households nearly doubled in relation to GDP between
7. At the end of October, expectations derived from the forward rates based on overnight index swaps
pointed to a delayed start of monetary policy tightening and a lower interest rate path than
expected by the US FOMC members in September. Thus, an alignment of financial market
expectations with the FOMC views could imply that 10-year US government bond yields increase
by around 1 percentage point, with a risk that similar increases occur in EMEs bond rates. Higher
increases may even occur because term premia – which have been at historic lows – will probably
rise as well. This would likely trigger global adjustments in corporate bond and equity prices.
8. Empirical evidence on the role of fundamentals in explaining capital flows is inconclusive (Ahmed
et al., 2015; Koepke, 2015). According to some studies, the role of macroeconomic fundamentals
has increased over time and played a role in insulating the EMEs from the 2013 taper tantrum
shock (Ahmed et al., 2015). However, Eichengreen and Gupta (2014) suggest that EMEs with larger
and more liquid markets are likely to be affected to a larger extent by US monetary policy
spillovers, irrespective of their fundamentals.
9. Companies in EMEs have increased borrowing in foreign currencies, but the lack of comprehensive
data makes difficult to assess the extent of hedging (Chui et al., 2014). Brazil’s central bank has
offered currency swaps which protect their holders from currency depreciations, with the losses
born by the fiscal authorities.
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
29
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Box 1.3. Rising US policy interest rates and spillovers to emerging market economies
This box looks at capital flows and financial market developments in selected EMEs during US monetary
policy tightening cycles in the 1990s and the 2000s, and assesses potential implications for the forthcoming
cycle.
Empirical evidence suggests that portfolio capital flows to EMEs, especially debt securities, are negatively
affected by an increase in US policy rates or expectations thereof (Koepke, 2015). For instance, Dahlhaus and
Vasishtha (2014) find that a 120-basis point increase in the spread between US 10-year Treasuries and the
federal funds rate reduces portfolio capital inflows to EMEs on aggregate by 1.7% of their GDP after six months.
Indeed, according to balance of payments data, during the US monetary policy tightening episodes from 199495 and 1999-2000, bond and equity capital flows to selected EMEs declined on aggregate, though with some
cross-country differences (figure below). This pattern is confirmed for capital flows from US residents only. In
contrast, in 2004-06, portfolio capital inflows into EMEs strengthened, suggesting other factors were at play.1
Portfolio capital flows to EMEs during past episodes of US monetary policy tightening
USD billions
Bonds¹ (BoP)
Equities (BoP)
60
60
60
40
40
40
20
20
20
0
-20
0
1993
1994
1995
Bonds (US)²
10
-20
1998
0
1999
2000
-20
2003
10
10
5
5
5
0
0
0
-5
-10
-5
1993
1994
1995
-10
1998
2004
2005
2006
Equities (US)²
-5
1999
2000
-10
2003
2004
2005
2006
Note: Due to data availability the EMEs include Argentina, Brazil, Hungary, Indonesia, India, Korea, Mexico, Russia, South Africa
and Turkey. The shaded areas correspond to US monetary policy tightening periods (February 1994-February 1995; June 1999-May
2000; and June 2004-June 2006).
1. Excluding India.
2. Net purchases of EMEs’ securities by US residents based on US Treasury International Capital System data.
Source: International Monetary Fund Balance of Payments BP5; and US Treasury International Capital System (TIC).
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295956
The negative impact of monetary policy tightening on portfolio capital inflows could be exacerbated by a
decline in investors’ risk tolerance (Koepke, 2015). As EMEs are viewed as higher-risk markets, they are
prone to a flight to safety by investors. Risk aversion, as measured by the implied volatility in equity prices
and the yield spread between US high-yield corporate bonds and US Treasuries, increased somewhat in the
1994-95 and 1999-2000, but not in the 2004-06 episode (figure below). Over recent years, these measures
were below historical averages, helped by extraordinary monetary policy stimulus, though they picked up
somewhat over recent months. The normalisation of US monetary policy may thus reduce risk tolerance,
with possible adverse effects on capital inflows into EMEs.
However, US monetary policy tightening has generally not led to tighter overall financial conditions in
EMEs over the entire cycle. Indeed, on average, nominal bilateral exchange rates against the dollar and
nominal effective exchange rates depreciated in 1994-05 and 1999-2000, and equity prices increased in
1999-2000 and 2004-06, though this masks considerable cross-country heterogeneity (second figure below).
30
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Box 1.3. Rising US policy interest rates and spillovers to emerging market economies
Measures of risk aversion
% pts
20
%
100
Bond yield spread ¹
VIX
18
90
16
80
14
70
12
60
10
50
8
40
6
30
4
20
2
10
0
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
0
Note: The dotted lines are the total sample average. The shaded areas correspond to US monetary policy tightening periods
(February 1994-February 1995; June 1999-May 2000; and June 2004-June 2006).
1. The spread between the US high-yield corporate bond yields (BoA ML with the average duration of 5 years) and the 5-year US
government bond yields.
Source: Thomson Reuters.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295965
Thus, whilst US monetary policy tightening may reduce portfolio capital flows to EMEs, especially if
investors become more risk averse, it does not have to necessarily result in tighter financial conditions in
EMEs over the entire policy tightening cycle.
Financial market conditions during past episodes of US monetary policy tightening
Unweighted average of percentage change for EMEs¹
B. Nominal effective
exchange rate²
A. US dollar
exchange rate²
%
%
C. Equity prices
%
5
5
0
0
70
60
50
-5
-5
-10
-10
40
30
20
-15
-20
-25
-15
Feb. 1994-Feb. 1995
June 1999-May 2000
June 2004-June 2006
10
0
-20
-10
-25
-20
1. The EMEs include Argentina, Brazil, Hungary, Indonesia, India, Korea, Mexico, Russia, South Africa and Turkey.
2. Negative changes correspond to a depreciation.
Source: Thomson Reuters; OECD Exchange rate database; and OECD calculations.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295978
1. This may reflect the fact that investors became less risk averse, with surging global equity prices and falling equity
price volatility.
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
31
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Figure 1.14. EMEs' external vulnerabilities increased due to exchange rate depreciations
A. Nominal exchange rate¹
B. External liabilities²
% change, June 2014 to Oct. 2015
USD
% of GDP, 2014 or latest available
Effective
Total
China
China
India
India
Indonesia
Indonesia
South Africa
South Africa
Mexico
Mexico
Turkey
Turkey
Brazil
Brazil
Russia
Russia
-50
-40
-30
-20
-10
0
10
20
0
Foreign-currency
25
50
75
100
125
150
1. Negative numbers imply a depreciation of the indicated country's currency against the US dollar (USD) and against a trade-weighted
basket of currencies effective exchange rate.
2. Foreign currency liabilities include bank loans, other investment liabilities and offshore external bond liabilities. The latter is
computed as the difference between debt securities by nationality of the issuer and by residence of the issuer and is set to zero when
the difference is negative.
Source: OECD Economic Outlook 98 database; Bank for International Settlements; International Monetary Funds; and OECD calculations.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295884
2007 and early 2015 (Figure 1.15). Based on past experience, such a rapid pace of debt
accumulation may foreshadow debt repayment problems as growth slows. However,
with the exception of Russia, officially reported non-performing loans in many EMEs
have been surprisingly low. This may, however, reflect supervisory leniency rather than
the lack of actual financial stress.
Figure 1.15. Credit has increased substantially in some EMEs
End-period stock, per cent of GDP
A. Non-financial corporations
B. Households
2007
2015Q1
China
China
Russia
Russia
Turkey
Turkey
India
India
Brazil
Brazil
South Africa
South Africa
Indonesia
Indonesia
Mexico
Mexico
0
50
100
150
200
0
10
20
30
40
50
Note: Credit from banks and non-banks adjusted for breaks. For South Africa 2008 instead of 2007.
Source: Bank for International Settlements.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295892
32
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Growth in the euro area and Japan is weaker than expected
Euro area and Japanese GDP growth in 2015 seems likely to be weaker than anticipated
in mid-2014, despite the boost provided by lower oil prices, weaker currencies and highly
stimulative monetary policy.10 Model simulations of these changes suggest that GDP
growth in the euro area and Japan this year could have been at least 1 percentage point
higher than projected currently (Box 1.4). This is offset to some extent, by a negative
impact on output from weaker-than-projected external demand growth.
In the euro area, subdued growth could reflect a continued impaired credit channel
due to an unfinished repair of banks’ balance sheets.
●
The functioning of the bank lending channel has improved, but has not fully healed in
the countries hit hardest by the crisis. Annual credit growth has just turned positive for
the euro area as a whole, but it remains negative in the countries hit hardest by the crisis
( Figure 1.16).
●
The cost of credit has come down from crisis levels, but in some countries remains high.
Intra-euro area spreads for bank lending rates and sovereign bond yields remain high
relative to the levels seen prior to the financial crisis. Asset purchases, including covered
bonds and asset-backed securities, and targeted longer-term refinancing operations by
the ECB have facilitated access of banks to funding and lowered its costs.
●
The recapitalisation of banks ahead of the comprehensive assessment at the end of 2014
and gradual adoption of more stringent bank regulation have resulted in stronger
balance sheets. Nevertheless, many banks in countries particularly strongly hit by the
crisis still have very high non-performing loans, which are lowering profits and thus
raising the cost of funding, and necessitate wider lending margins (IMF, 2015b;
Table 1.A2.1; and Figure 1.16).
The weak recovery may also reflect limited deleveraging in the non-financial private
sector. Although over recent years household net financial wealth in the euro area and
Japan increased in relation to GDP, the ratio of household gross debt to GDP has barely
changed (Figure 1.17). This is in contrast to the United States, where household gross debt
declined in relation to GDP. Favourable nominal GDP dynamics in the United States, as
opposed to the euro area and Japan, account for the different outcomes, with debt writeoffs playing an important role for the deleveraging in the United States as well.11 The euro
area aggregate masks important cross-country differences. While household debt in
relation to GDP declined strongly in Ireland and Portugal, and to a lesser extent in Spain
and Germany, it increased somewhat in Italy (although it remains comparatively low) and
France. There was also little deleveraging of non-financial corporations in Japan and the
euro area. In the latter, this is likely to be the counterpart of high levels of non-performing
loans in the banking system.
10. The October 2015 consensus forecasts for GDP growth in 2015 in the euro area and Japan were
1.5% and 0.6% respectively. The euro area consensus is little changed from the June 2014
consensus forecast of euro area GDP growth in 2015, but the current Japan consensus is ½
percentage point weaker than the June-2014 consensus forecast of Japanese GDP growth in 2015.
11. Write-offs are part of other changes in debt depicted in Figure 1.17 but cannot be identified exactly.
Looking beyond national accounts data, the role of debt write-offs in the United States is
contested, with some suggesting that it explained nearly two-thirds of deleveraging and others
pointing to only a marginal role (Bouis et al., 2013).
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
33
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Box 1.4. Growth shortfalls in the euro area and Japan
Macro-model simulations, using NiGEM, suggest that much stronger growth outcomes would have been
expected in both the euro area and Japan in 2015 than now looks likely. Projections for 2016 are also lower
than indicated by simulations for both economies. The decline in oil prices since mid-2014 is estimated to
boost GDP by around 0.3 and 0.7 percentage point per annum over 2015-16 in the euro area and Japan,
respectively. In addition, the effective exchange rate depreciations since mid-2014 could boost GDP growth
by 0.3-0.4 percentage point in the euro area in 2015 and by 0.5-0.6 percentage point in Japan. The observed
decline in long-term government bond rates and private sector borrowing rates since mid-2014 could also
be expected to boost euro area GDP growth by a further 0.4-0.5 percentage point this year, all else equal. The
additional public spending resulting from higher inflows of asylum seekers in Europe should also be
making a small positive contribution to euro area GDP growth in 2015-16.
Estimated impact on GDP growth in 2015 of changes in forces acting since June 2014
Difference from baseline
% pts
0.8
% pts
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
-0.0
-0.0
-0.2
-0.2
Euro area
Japan
-0.4
-0.6
-0.4
Oil prices
Exchanges rates
Lower interest rates
non-OECD demand
-0.6
Source: OECD calculations.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295980
These shocks are not fully independent, since the underlying softness of demand that prompted the
monetary authorities in Japan and the euro area to purchase assets last year contributed to the decline in
oil prices, and the anticipated easing of monetary policy contributed to the depreciation of the euro and the
yen. Nonetheless, they suggest that in isolation it would not have been surprising if GDP growth this year
would have been at least 1 percentage point higher than now appears likely in the euro area and Japan.
The positive stimulus has been offset, at least in part, by the greater-than-expected slowdown in China
and other EMEs, reducing external demand for both the euro area and Japan. The slowdown relative to
what was expected in mid-2014, has on average reduced GDP growth by a little under ½ percentage point
per annum over 2015-16 in the euro area and Japan.
Conventional macro-model simulations implicitly assume that all adjustment mechanisms in the
economy are working as they did on average over the period in which they were estimated. In this context,
the simulation results from NiGEM may be misleadingly strong. They could reflect specification errors and
may not incorporate ongoing structural changes, such as the limited impact that interest rates now appear
to have on business investment (OECD, 2015b), particularly at a time of heightened uncertainty. Downward
rigidities in nominal wages and prices may also generate asymmetric responses to large declines or rises in
oil prices, rather than the similar effects embodied in standard macro-models (Raciborski et al., 2015). In
the euro area, monetary policy stimulus could also be weakened by the still impaired credit channel.
34
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Box 1.4. Growth shortfalls in the euro area and Japan (cont.)
The declining sensitivity of trade volumes to changes in competitiveness (Ollivaud et al., 2015) may also
account for the lower than expected effects from past exchange rate depreciations. In the euro area, export
performance has improved in 2015, with export volumes rising twice as quickly as export market growth,
suggesting that the real exchange rate has had some impact. However, there is little evidence of such
effects on imports, with import growth accelerating this year relative to total final expenditure. For Japan,
the further exchange rate depreciation since mid-2014 came on top of a larger decline in the previous year.
The initial decline boosted export performance in 2014, but the further decline has had little observed
impact on performance this year.
Finally, it might also be the case that growth has been weaker than expected because the positive impact
of the economic shocks has been added to an overoptimistic baseline projection, as it frequently has been
for year-ahead forecasts in the aftermath of the crisis (OECD, 2014a). Relatedly, since the November 2014
Economic Outlook, the OECD estimate of euro area and Japanese potential output growth in 2015 has been
revised down by 0.2 and 0.5 percentage point, respectively.
Persistent uncertainty could also weigh on growth performance.
●
The August agreement between Greece and its creditors has relieved financial market
pressures and significantly reduced the chances of further disruption in the near term.
It remains to be seen whether these measures suffice to revive growth and make the
debt situation sustainable over the long term. Uncertainties over implementation may
weigh on investment in the short term.
●
In Japan, the government has set up a new fiscal strategy relying on stronger economic
growth to put government accounts on a sustainable footing. Additional measures will
be needed to put debt on a downward trend and maintain investors’ confidence in fiscal
sustainability.
Lower potential output growth and uncertainty
The OECD has revised its estimates of potential growth and output gaps (Box 1.5)
prompted by a further period of weak investment, with adverse consequences for
productivity growth. Potential growth rates have generally been marked down for the
recent past and near future, with a decline of ¼ percentage point in the main OECD areas
in 2016. This downward revision comes on top of sizeable past revisions in the aftermath
of the crisis. Even if the output gap estimates are little changed for the OECD area as a
whole following the new revisions, estimated slack is now noticeably smaller in some
economies than previously projected, including the United States. The implications of
these developments for macroeconomic policies are discussed further below.
Estimates of output gaps and potential growth rates are imprecisely measured, and
uncertainty is high.12 Uncertainties stem in part from the weakened relationship between
inflation and measured slack in recent years. A focus on national measures of economic
slack may also be less relevant for inflation developments in the context of more globallyintegrated output and factor markets. There is also uncertainty about the sources of
12. Many studies have highlighted the fact that the sign and the magnitude of the output gaps
estimated in real time are subject to large revisions as new information becomes available (Turner
et al., forthcoming; European Commission, 2015; Bundesbank, 2014; IMF, 2015a).
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
35
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Figure 1.16. Conditions in the banking sector across euro area countries continue to differ
A. Bank interest rate margin¹
B. Bank interest rate margin¹
%
%
3.5
Germany
France
3.0
Italy
Ireland
Portugal
4
Spain
3
2.5
2.0
2
1.5
1
1.0
0
0.5
0.0
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2004
C. Interest rate on loans
to non-financial corporations²
2006
2008
2010
2012
-1
2014
D. Interest rate for house purchase²
%
%
5
3.5
3.0
4
2.5
3
2.0
2
E. Growth in credit to
non-financial corporations³
LUX
SVK
ITA
ESP
EA
NLD
BEL
FIN
DEU
IRL
SVN
EST
FRA
AUT
PRT
GRC
IRL
PRT
AUT
SVK
BEL
GRC
FIN
EST
ESP
FRA
DEU
NLD
EA
LUX
ITA
SVN
1
1.5
1.0
F. Growth in credit to households³
%
%
BEL
SVK
LUX
EST
FIN
FRA
DEU
EA
AUT
ITA
SVN
NLD
ESP
GRC
IRL
PRT
LUX
FIN
EST
FRA
BEL
SVK
DEU
-5
EA
-20
AUT
0
ITA
-10
NLD
5
GRC
0
ESP
10
PRT
10
IRL
15
SVN
20
1. The interest rate margin is calculated as the difference between interest rates charged on bank loans for house purchases and paid
on households deposits.
2. The average for 3 months to September 2015 of the bank total cost of borrowing to non-financial corporations and of the bank interest
for house purchases.
3. The average for 3 months to September 2015 of annual growth in loans adjusted for sales and securitisation.
Source: European Central Bank; and OECD calculations.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295905
36
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Figure 1.17. Little progress with deleveraging in the euro area and Japan
A. Gross debt for households
% of GDP
100
B. Net financial wealth for households
United States
Japan
Euro area
95
% of GDP
350
United States
Japan
Euro area
300
90
85
250
80
75
200
70
65
150
60
55
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2006
C. Gross debt for non-financial
corporations
2008
2010
2012
2014
D. Net financial wealth for
non-financial corporations
% of GDP
170
% of GDP
-60
United States
Japan
Euro area
160
150
-80
-100
United States
Japan
Euro area
140
100
-120
130
-140
120
-160
110
-180
100
90
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
-200
E. Decomposition of changes in household debt-to-GDP ratio 2007-2014¹
% of GDP
30
GDP Growth
Net credit flows
Other changes
% of GDP
30
Change in debt
20
20
10
10
0
0
GRC
BEL
FRA
NLD
ITA
JPN
EURO
PRT
-30
DEU
-30
ESP
-20
IRL
-20
GBR
-10
USA
-10
1. The change in debt-to-GDP ratio is decomposed according the formula: d(debt[t]) = -g[t]/(1+g[t])*debt[t-1] + net credit flows[t] + other
changes[t], where g[t] is percentage nominal GDP growth (divided by 100), and the first term indicates the contribution of nominal GDP
growth to debt dynamics. Other changes reflect changes due to write-offs, reclassification and revaluation.
Source: OECD, National Accounts database; European Central Bank; and OECD calculations.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295911
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
37
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Box 1.5. Revisions to potential output growth
For the aggregate OECD, current potential growth projections have been revised down by ¼ of a
percentage point in 2016 relative to projections in June (OECD, 2015a), reflecting the disappointing recovery,
particularly of productivity. Downward revisions apply to most OECD countries and all of the G7 countries,
with the exception of Germany (figure below, Panel A). The changes mostly reflect revisions to the total
factor productivity (TFP) component of potential growth, although for Germany, downward revisions to TFP
are more than offset by larger upward revisions to labour input, reflecting higher net inward migration.
Revision to potential output growth for 2016
Current relative to previous published projections
A. Major OECD countries
% pts per annum
0.8
0.6
Capital stock
TFP
Labour
% pts per annum
0.8
Potential output growth
0.6
-0.0
-0.2
-0.2
-0.4
-0.4
-0.6
-0.6
EA15
OECD
FRA
GBR
DEU
-0.0
JPN
0.2
ITA
0.2
USA
0.4
CAN
0.4
B. BRIICS
% pts per annum
0.5
% pts per annum
0.5
0.0
0.0
-0.5
-0.5
-1.0
Capital stock
TFP
Labour
-1.0
Potential output growth
-1.5
-2.0
-1.5
RUS
ZAF
BRA
IDN
BRIICS
CHN
IND
-2.0
Note: Assuming potential output (Y*) can be represented by a Cobb-Douglas production function in terms of potential employment
(N*), the capital stock (K) and labour-augmenting technical progress (E*) then y* = a (n*+e*) + (1 - a) k, where lower case letters
denote logs, a is the wage share and total factor productivity (TFP) is given by TFP = a e*.
Source: OECD Economic Outlook 98 database; and OECD Economic Outlook 97 database.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295998
38
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Box 1.5. Revisions to potential output growth (cont.)
For the BRIICS, aggregate potential output growth projections have been revised down by 0.2 percentage
point in 2016, with much of the revision also due to lower TFP growth (figure above, panel B). There is,
however, much greater variation across the BRIICs than for the major OECD economies; the downward
revisions are particularly marked for Russia and South Africa, whereas potential growth has been revised
marginally upwards for India, anticipating the effect of structural reforms.
The concentration of revisions on TFP growth reflects the difficulty of projecting what is effectively the
residual GDP growth that is not explained by changes in factor inputs. Projecting TFP is also problematic
because it is difficult to distinguish whether TFP is temporarily weak for cyclical reasons. In the post-crisis
period, observed TFP growth was low, but was initially judged to be mostly cyclical; therefore estimates of
trend TFP growth remained relatively high. As additional TFP growth observations accumulated, however,
the cyclical weakness position gradually became more untenable and, given the filtering techniques used
to estimate trend TFP, more and more of the recent weakness became embedded into the trend. 1
Disappointments on TFP growth could reflect a number of factors including: poor diffusion of new
technology in frontier firms to the majority of firms (OECD, 2015f), partly because of weak investment
following the crisis that reduced embodied technical change (Oulton, 2007); a slowdown in structural
reform efforts; or a slowdown in the rate of improvement in the global productivity frontier (Gordon, 2012).
The downward revisions to potential growth leave the rate of improvement in projected OECD potential
GDP per capita (a proxy for living standards) at only about 1% per annum, compared with twice that rate
around the turn of the millennium, and just under 1½ per cent in the years immediately preceding the
crisis. For the BRIICS, the growth rate of potential GDP per capita has also fallen, by an average of 1¼
percentage points compared to the period 2005-10, driven by the slowdown of Brazil, China and Russia and
in contrast to a stabilisation for India and Indonesia. There is also great heterogeneity in the speed at which
living standards are improving: potential output per capita for China, although decelerating, is growing
about 6¼ per cent for 2016, while it barely increases for Brazil and Russia (between ½ and ¾ per cent).
1. To help with such end-point problems, a recent innovation (Turner et al, forthcoming) to the potential output methodology has
been to make use of survey measures of manufacturing capacity utilisation which - for some, but not all, countries - seem well
correlated with cyclical fluctuations in TFP.
economic slack. Traditional measures of labour-market slack may also be too narrow,
failing to capture the post-crisis rise in the number of involuntary part-time workers and
inactive persons wanting to work but not registered as job seekers.
There is also significant uncertainty about future potential growth rates, and in
particular about trend productivity growth rates. Since the beginning of the financial crisis
weak domestic and foreign demand, greater financial constraints and persistent
uncertainties have discouraged investment. In addition, public and infrastructure
investments have been held back in some countries by fiscal consolidation. Overall, the
sluggish recovery in investment is estimated to account for over half of the slowdown in
the growth rate of OECD potential output per capita in recent years compared to pre-crisis
averages (OECD, 2015a). The crisis may also have depressed the supply of labour in the
wake of the crisis, notably in the euro area. High skill mismatch and a slowing of the pace
at which new innovations spread out throughout the economy may have contributed to
lower labour productivity growth (Adalet McGowan et al., 2015). A slower pace of productmarket reforms may also have played a role. Some of the slowdown in trend productivity
that started in the 2000s could be long-lasting if policies fail to respond.
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
39
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Policy requirements
Macroeconomic policies in advanced and emerging market economies
The main advanced economies require continued policy support to stimulate
aggregate demand and strengthen potential growth.
●
Differences in expected growth and inflation developments call for increasingly
divergent monetary policy stances. The gradual disappearance of slack in the United
States, and the associated prospect of inflation moving towards its target, requires
gradually higher policy rates. In the euro area and Japan, very low inflation warrants
continued very supportive monetary policy, as planned. A persistent undershooting of
inflation in Japan and the euro area poses challenges for monetary policy, as there are
limits to what additional stimulus can achieve (OECD, 2015a; Rawdanowicz et al., 2013).
●
Public debt levels remain high by historical standards and a number of countries still
have large budget deficits (Table 1.4). Fiscal challenges remain particularly large in Japan,
where structural budget deficits should continue to be reduced. In all economies there is
scope to adjust the composition of public spending to strengthen near-term demand and
Table 1.4. Fiscal positions will continue to improve
Per cent of GDP / potential GDP
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
United States
Actual balance
Underlying balance
Underlying primary balance
Gross financial liabilities
-5.5
-3.8
-1.5
111.4
-5.1
-3.8
-1.1
111.6
-4.5
-3.7
-1.0
110.6
-4.2
-3.7
-0.8
111.4
-3.7
-3.6
-0.6
111.5
Euro area
Actual balance
Underlying balance
Underlying primary balance
Gross financial liabilities
-3.0
-0.9
1.4
104.9
-2.6
-0.6
1.6
111.7
-1.9
-0.5
1.6
111.2
-1.7
-0.4
1.5
110.2
-1.0
-0.4
1.4
108.5
Japan
Actual balance
Underlying balance
Underlying primary balance
Gross financial liabilities
-8.5
-8.6
-7.9
220.3
-7.7
-7.8
-6.9
226.1
-6.7
-7.0
-6.0
229.2
-5.7
-6.3
-5.5
232.4
-5.0
-5.6
-4.8
233.8
OECD1
Actual balance1
-4.1
-3.8
-3.3
-2.8
-2.3
Underlying balance2
-3.1
-2.9
-2.8
-2.7
-2.5
Underlying primary balance2
Gross financial liabilities2
-1.2
-0.9
-0.8
-0.7
-0.5
112.1
115.5
115.2
115.4
114.8
Note: Actual balances and liabilities are in per cent of nominal GDP. Underlying balances are in per cent of
potential GDP and they refer to fiscal balances adjusted for the cycle and for one-offs. Underlying primary
balance is the underlying balance excluding net debt interest payments.
1. Excludes Chile and Mexico.
2. Excludes Chile, Mexico and Turkey.
Source: OECD Economic Outlook 98 database.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933296683
40
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
long-term supply without raising deficits, in particular by reallocating public spending
towards investment (Cournède et al., 2014). In fact, collective action that focuses new
spending on high-multiplier investments can augment GDP growth sufficiently to
reduce debt-to-GDP ratios in the near term (Box 1.6) provided that it is accompanied by
supportive structural policy settings.
Box 1.6. The impact of an increase in public investment in OECD economies
The stylised scenarios set out in this box provide some illustrative estimates of the possible economic
and fiscal impacts of a temporary increase in public investment in the OECD economies, using simulations
on the NiGEM global macro model. The rationale for such investments is that they could help to push
economies onto a higher growth path than might otherwise be the case, at a time when private investment
growth remains modest. Two scenarios are considered: the first is with a collective increase in public
investment in the OECD economies; the second is with separate increases in public investment in one
economy at a time, with such investment remaining unchanged in the other OECD economies.
Public investment is assumed to be increased by ½ per cent of GDP for two years in each economy,
implying an increase in the volume of government investment of around 15% in the typical OECD member
state. In some countries this may be challenging to achieve immediately. The analysis nonetheless
assumes that the projects undertaken are economically worthwhile, with net benefits to the economy.
Collective action to increase public investment can be expected to boost the initial domestic multiplier
effects from the stimulus, since private investment and exports in each economy will benefit from stronger
demand in other economies (Barrell et al., 2012; OECD, 2015b). Monetary policy is assumed to be
accommodative, with policy interest rates held fixed. This is likely to further increase the short-term
positive effect on growth, all else equal, since real interest rates decline as inflation edges up following the
demand stimulus. Budget solvency rules are also switched off, so that the higher level of investment
spending initially raises the budget deficit; the implications of imposing budget solvency are discussed
below. Finally, the multiplier effects from an investment-led stimulus are likely to be a little larger than
from other forms of fiscal stimulus, since the former also has small, but positive, supply-side effects
(Coenen et al., 2012).
The first-year multiplier from the collective stimulus is above 1, with OECD GDP rising by over 0.6% (see
first figure below), and GDP rising by over 0.5% in each of the major economies. The impact is larger in Japan
and the United States than in the euro area, the United Kingdom and Canada, since the latter economies
are more open, so that a larger proportion of the stimulus is offset by higher imports. Stronger demand in
the OECD economies also boosts the major EMEs, with GDP in the BRIICS rising by around ¼ percentage
point. All told, global GDP rises by a little over 0.4%. Reflecting the comparatively high import content of
investment spending, global trade rises by over 1% in the first year. The growth effects could be even
stronger if the additional public investment was concentrated in network industries, particularly in the EU,
where there is a greater possibility of crowding in private investment (OECD, 2015b). The first-year effects
on GDP are lower by around 20-25% in the United States, Japan and the euro area if the investment shock is
conducted separately for each of these economies and around 40% lower in the United Kingdom and
Canada. Thus, there are clear benefits from undertaking collective action to boost public investment.
The initial increase of ½ per cent of GDP in the budget deficit from stronger expenditure is offset in part
by the favourable fiscal effects of stronger economic activity, so that the first-year increase in the budget
deficit is below ½ per cent of GDP (see second figure below, Panel A). The offset in the collective action
scenario is around one-quarter in the euro area, the United Kingdom and Canada, but one-third or more in
Japan and the United States, reflecting the comparatively stronger initial boost to activity. The budgetary
offsets are smaller in the go-it-alone scenario, reflecting the weaker activity effects that result.
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
41
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Box 1.6. The impact of an increase in public investment in OECD economies (cont.)
Government debt-to-GDP ratios decline in the first year in the collective action scenario, despite the
increase in the deficit-to-GDP ratio (see second figure below, Panel B). This is because the favourable impact
of the increase in (nominal) GDP on the debt-to-GDP ratio more than offsets the impact of the higher budget
deficit. The decline is largest in Japan, reflecting both the sizeable impact of the stimulus on activity and
the high initial government debt-to-GDP ratio. In the alternative scenario, with the shock conducted
separately for each economy, there are still first year declines in the debt-to-GDP ratio in Japan, the United
States and the euro area, but the declines in Canada and the United Kingdom are almost entirely
eliminated.
In the second year of the collective action scenario (not shown here), there is a small additional increase
in GDP growth in the OECD economies, reflecting second-round effects from increased global activity and
the impact of a decline in real interest rates. The level of OECD GDP is around 0.8% above baseline.
Government deficit-to-GDP ratios remain above their baseline values, by around ¼ per cent of GDP in most
major OECD economies (0.1% of GDP in Japan), but debt-to-GDP ratios are below their baseline levels. In
contrast, debt-to-GDP ratios are higher than in the baseline in the United Kingdom and Canada when the
government investment is shock conducted separately for each economy.
First-year GDP effects of a government investment stimulus in OECD economies
First-year change from baseline
%
%
1.0
1.0
Collective
Non-collective
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
Japan
Euro area
United States
United Kingdom
Canada
BRIICs
0.0
World
Note: Based on a two-year increase in the level of government investment equivalent to ½ per cent of GDP per annum in all OECD
countries (Collective) and separately in the United States, Japan, the euro area, the United Kingdom and Canada (Non-Collective).
Source: OECD calculations.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933296009
If the budget solvency rule in NiGEM is allowed to operate, the increase in expenditure is offset by an
increase in direct taxes on households to bring the budget balance back to its baseline level by the second
year in both of the scenarios considered. This has relatively little impact on the initial multiplier effect from
the boost to government investment, but starts to reduce GDP growth by the second year, reflecting the
impact of weaker disposable incomes on household consumption growth.
42
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Box 1.6. The impact of an increase in public investment in OECD economies (cont.)
The impact of a government investment stimulus on budget deficits and government debt
First-year change from baseline
A. First year budget balance effects
B. First year debt stock effects
% of GDP
-0.0
% of GDP
0.0
-0.1
-0.5
-0.2
-1.0
-0.3
-1.5
-0.4
-2.0
Collective
Non-collective
-0.5
Japan
Collective
Non-collective
Euro area
United States
United Kingdom
Canada
Japan
Euro area
United States
United Kingdom
-2.5
Canada
Note: Based on a two-year increase in the level of government investment equivalent to ½ per cent of GDP per annum in all OECD
countries (Collective) and separately in the United States, Japan, the euro area, the United Kingdom and Canada (Non-Collective).
The euro area debt stock figures are a weighted average of Germany, France and Italy.
Source: OECD calculations.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933296018
●
Structural policies with a positive impact on short-term demand, including a reduction
of barriers to entry in sectors with pent-up demand and a cut in administrative burdens
for firms, are needed (Caldera Sanchez et al., forthcoming). This would help to maximise
the returns from public infrastructure investment projects with favourable net social
benefits. Joint action to generate profitable investment opportunities by removing or
reducing border protection would also help to boost growth prospects. Co-ordinated
international action to combat climate change could also help underpin a surge in new
investments. As argued in Chapter 2, ambitious measures to help lower greenhouse gas
emissions can fit well with the need to stimulate investment and technical progress. In
Europe, legislation has been passed to make the European Fund for Strategic Investment
operational in Autumn 2015 and some energy initiatives have been announced as part of
the Juncker Plan. Further progress in this direction is required.
In the euro area, there is a need to speed up the restructuring of non-performing loans
in order to unblock the bank lending channel and help shift economic resources to more
productive uses. To this end, a strengthening of bank supervision, debt enforcement and
insolvency frameworks is needed. Also, the resolution of the large amount of distressed
debt on banks’ balance sheet would be facilitated by the development of a market for such
assets. Banks’ losses need to be recognised swiftly, even if this requires injections of public
money to recapitalise banks or an orderly wind-down of insolvent institutions. In the
longer term, banking and capital market union is needed to ensure a well-functioning
banking system.
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
43
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
If financial market tensions were to occur and result in significantly tighter financial
conditions and thus weaker economic growth, an offset from macroeconomic policies
would be needed. It should involve either postponing planned tightening or adding
additional stimulus, from both fiscal and monetary policies, with the appropriate policy
mix depending on country-specific situations and the room available for policy action. The
ensuing, even more protracted, environment of very low interest rates would raise
financial stability risks.
The scope for policy to respond to flagging economic growth varies across EMEs,
reflecting existing economic imbalances and vulnerabilities. China still has further room
for monetary and fiscal stimulus, even after recent stimulus measures, but may have to
accept a slower rate of growth as the economy rebalances. Policy stimulus should be
designed to avoid aggravating current financial vulnerabilities. In many EMEs, including
Brazil, the rapidly deteriorating fiscal situation means that there is little room for stimulus
beyond automatic stabilisers. The prospective normalisation of policy interest rates in the
United States poses challenges for EMEs. With globally integrated financial markets, it may
be difficult for them to respond to any interest rate increases in the United States and to
any associated depreciation of their currencies or capital outflows. Such developments
could prompt monetary authorities in EMEs to raise interest rates to address threats to
price and financial stability, especially if inflation expectations are poorly anchored. This
could damp economic activity if not offset by fiscal stimulus.
In EMEs, trade-offs stemming from the need to ensure simultaneously price, financial
and growth stability, at a time of increasing international spillovers, require the use of
multiple instruments and ensuring that there is sufficient room for policy response. Some
spillovers via gross credit flows and leverage, leading to excessive debt build-up and
international exposure, could be addressed by macro-prudential policies. Many EMEs are
already using such policies to strengthen the resilience of the financial sector (Box 1.5 in
OECD (2013a)). They should be accompanied by close monitoring of non-performing loans
and bank capitalisation by bank regulators, with regular stress tests. Proper bankruptcy
and loan restructuring rules should also be in place.
Financial market stability in EMEs could be strengthened by structural reforms. A
higher share of FDI liabilities in total foreign liabilities reduces the risks of volatile capital
flows. Such a safer structure of liabilities could be promoted by reducing regulatory
burdens on foreign direct investment and product markets, and removing tax incentives
for debt over equity financing (Ahrend and Goujard, 2012). Re-starting growth-enhancing
structural reforms would also help improve economic prospects more generally and boost
investors’ confidence.
Implications of weaker and uncertain potential growth for macroeconomic policies in
advanced economies
Weaker potential growth (Box 1.5) and heightened uncertainties have implications for
fiscal assessments:
●
44
In the short term, smaller output gaps and weaker growth make fiscal targets more
difficult to achieve, because there will be less “bonus” from a cyclical recovery (or the
structural deficit is closer to the actual deficit than assumed). For instance, fiscal targets
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
in France and Italy will be harder to reach if the cyclical strengthening of budget
positions is lower than expected (Figure 1.18).13
●
The concept of a “prudent” debt target, and the corresponding fiscal deficit trajectory in
a medium-term framework, could be a way to account for uncertainty in potential
output without increasing the complexity of fiscal rules (Fall and Fournier, 2015).14 In
such a framework, larger uncertainties about future growth and associated fiscal
outcomes in a given country are associated with a lower prudent debt target. However,
the objective of reducing the risk of near-term recession implies higher prudent debt
targets. Collective action on high-multiplier fiscal strategies could achieve both
objectives.
While slower potential growth and high uncertainties call for measures to reduce
public debt ratios, fiscal measures need to be designed with care to attain that goal. Indeed,
if multipliers are sufficiently high, fiscal consolidation could worsen debt-to-GDP ratios, as
the reduction in the level of debt would be more than offset by the negative impact on GDP,
especially in economies where the debt ratio is high and automatic stabilisers are large.
One reason for weak potential output growth at present is weak investment growth,
both public and private. This has implications for the composition of fiscal packages. In
particular, cutting public investment, whose multiplier is estimated to be higher than
Figure 1.18. The cyclical component of budget deficits
Per cent of GDP
%
%
1.0
0.5
1.0
2015
2016
2017
0.5
0.0
0.0
-0.5
-0.5
-1.0
-1.0
-1.5
-1.5
-2.0
-2.0
-2.5
United States
Germany
Japan
Italy
France
Canada
-2.5
United Kingdom
Note: The calculation uses the semi-elasticity to the output gap derived in Price et al. (2015). Semi-elasticities vary from 0.41 in Japan to
0.61 in France. Observed differences in the impact mostly reflect differences in the currently estimated output gaps.
Source: OECD Economic Outlook 98 database.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933295924
13. Over the medium term, the extent to which lower potential output growth will affect public
finances depends on the adjustment speed of public spending to productivity and growth. In the
longer term, lower potential growth need not have any implication for debt sustainability provided
neutral interest rates decline in line with lower growth.
14. Such targets are computed so that there is less than a 25% risk of the debt-to-GDP ratio going
beyond 85% for non-euro area OECD countries and 65% for euro area countries, accounting for
uncertainties surrounding the development of the main macroeconomic variables. Using a
stochastic framework to quantify those uncertainties, the prudent debt target is estimated to be on
average 50% of GDP for euro area countries and 70% of GDP for the rest of the OECD, with some
heterogeneity among countries.
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
45
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
those of other spending components (Auerbach and Gorodnichenko, 2012; Gechert et al.,
2015) could result in higher debt ratios, and harm both actual and potential output growth.
Conversely, collective action to raise good-quality public investment, particularly at a time
of low long-term financing costs, might boost growth and reduce debt ratios, notably in
highly indebted countries (Box 1.6).
More broadly, strategies to reduce debt should focus on measures that do not have a
large negative short-term effect on growth. In economies where the recovery is still fragile,
it may be appropriate to reverse consolidation, if the right policies can be implemented, to
allow a period of more robust GDP growth after which adjustment measures can be taken
when normal economic conditions prevail and fiscal multipliers are lower.
Weaker potential growth and high uncertainty also matter for monetary policy.
Although the link between the estimated output gap and inflation has been weak, reduced
spare capacity would imply stronger inflationary pressures and possibly the need to
tighten policy rates faster. However, a permanent reduction in potential growth would also
imply a lower neutral interest rate and thus weaker stimulus from the current level of
policy rates, slowing output dynamics. Greater reliance on current inflation developments
and expectations and survey-based measures of economic slack could be a particularly
useful guide for policymakers at present, given the extensive uncertainty around the
extent of current slack and of future productivity growth (Orphanides, 2003; Pain and
Röhn, 2011).
Overall, even if there is a risk that potential growth may be weaker than predicted,
tightening policies at present is generally unwarranted. It will be important to resist the
pressure to implement pro-cyclical policy, especially in the euro area where demand is still
depressed. Rigidity in labour markets and inertia in fixed investment decisions strengthen
the case for such a strategy.
46
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Bibliography
Aaronson, D., L. Hu, A. Seifoddini and D. Sullivan (2014), “Declining Labor Force Participation and its
Implications for Unemployment and Employment Growth”, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Economic
Perspectives, No. 38.
Adalet McGowan M., D. Andrews, C. Criscuolo and G. Nicoletti (2015), The Future of Productivity, OECD
Publishing, Paris.
Ahmed, S., B. Coulibaly and A. Zlate (2015), “International Financial Spillovers to Emerging Market
Economies: How Important Are Economic Fundamentals?,” International Finance Discussion Papers,
No. 1135, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Ahrend, R. and A. Goujard (2012), “International Capital Mobility and Financial Fragility - Part 3. How
Do Structural Policies Affect Financial Crisis Risk?: Evidence from Past Crises Across OECD and
Emerging Economies”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 966, OECD Publishing, Paris.
Auerbach A.J. and Y. Gorodnichenko (2012), “Fiscal Multipliers in Recession and Expansion”, in A.
Alesina and F. Giavazzi (eds), Fiscal Policy after the Financial Crisis, University of Chicago Press.
Barrell, R., D. Holland and I. Hurst (2012), “Fiscal Multipliers and Prospects for Consolidation”, OECD
Economic Studies, Vol. 2012.
Bouis, R., A. K. Christensen and B. Cournède (2013), “Deleveraging: Challenges, Progress and Policies”,
OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1077, OECD Publishing, Paris. DOI: http://dx.doi.org/
10.1787/5k4221459fjc-en
Bundesbank (2014), “On the Reliability of International Organisations' Estimates of the Output Gap”,
Deutsche Bundesbank Monthly Report, April.
Caldera Sanchez, A., A. De Serres and N. Yashiro (forthcoming), “Reforming in a Difficult Macro
Context: What Should be the Priorities?”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, OECD
Publishing, Paris.
Chui, M., I. Fender and V. Sushko (2014), “Risks Related to EME Corporate Balance Sheets: The Role of
Leverage and Currency Mismatch”, BIS Quarterly Review, September.
Coenen G., C. J. Erceg, C. Freedman, D. Furceri, M. Kumhof, R. Lalonde, D. Laxton, J. Lindé, A.
Mourougane, D. Muir, S. Mursula, C. de Resende, J. Roberts, W. Roeger, S. Snudden, M. Trabandt and
J. in't Veld (2012), “Effects of Fiscal Stimulus in Structural Models”, American Economic Journal:
Macroeconomics, Vol. 4(1).
Constantinescu, C., A. Mattoo and M. Ruta (2015), “The Global Trade Slowdown – Cyclical or
Structural?”, IMF Working Papers, No. WP/15/6.
Cournède, B., A. Pina and A. Goujard (2014), “Reconciling Fiscal Consolidation with Growth and
Equity”, OECD Journal: Economic Studies, Vol. 2013, Issue 1, OECD Publishing, Paris.
Dahlhaus, T. and G. Vasishtha (2014), “The Impact of U.S. Monetary Policy Normalization on Capital
Flows to Emerging-Market Economies”, Bank of Canada Working Papers, No. 2014-53, December.
Del Carpio, X. and M. Wagner (2015), “The Impact of Syrian Refugees on the Turkish Labour Market”,
World Bank Policy Research Papers, No. WPS7402.
Dustman, C. and T. Frattini (2014), “The Fiscal Effects of Immigration to the UK”, Economic Journal,
Vol. 124.
Eichengreen, B. and P. Gupta (2014), “Tapering Talk: The Impact of Expectations of Reduced Federal
Reserve Security Purchases on Emerging Markets”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series,
No. 6754.
European Commission (2015), “An Assessment of the Relative Quality of EU Gap Estimates”, Quarterly
Report on the Euro Area, Vol. 14.
Eurostat (2015), “Migrant Integration Statistics – Employment”, Statistics Explained, Eurostat. http://
ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/index.php/Migrant_integration_statistics_-_employment
Fall, F. and J-M. Fournier (2015), “Macroeconomic Uncertainties, Prudent Debt Targets and Fiscal Rules”,
OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1230, OECD Publishing, Paris.
Gauvin, L. and C. Rebillard (2015), “Towards Recoupling? Assessing the Global Impact of a Chinese Hard
Landing through Trade and Commodity Price Channels”, Banque de France Working Paper, No. 562.
Gechert, S., A. Hughes Hallett and A. Rannenberg (2015), “Fiscal Multipliers in Downturns and the
Effects of Eurozone Consolidation”, CEPR Policy Insight, No. 79, February.
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
47
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Gordon, R. (2012), “Is U.S. Economic Growth Over? Faltering Innovation Confronts the Six Headwinds”,
NBER Working Papers, No. 18315.
Guichard, S., D. Haugh and D. Turner (2009), “Quantifying the Effect of Financial Conditions in the Euro
Area, Japan, United Kingdom and the United States”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers,
No. 677, OECD Publishing, Paris.
IMF (2015a), “Where Are We Headed? Perspectives on Potential Output”, Chapter 3 in World Economic
Outlook, April.
IMF (2015b), “A Strategy for Resolving Europe’s Problem Loans”, IMF Staff Discussion Notes, No. 15/19,
September 24.
Jean, S. and M. Jimenez (2007), “The Unemployment Impact of Immigration in OECD Countries”, OECD
Economics Department Working Papers, No. 563, OECD Publishing, Paris.
Koepke, R. (2015), “What Drives Capital Flows to Emerging Markets? A Survey of the Empirical
Literature”, IIF Working Paper, Institute of International Finance.
Mitchell, J., N. Pain and R. Riley (2011), “The Drivers of International Migration to the UK: A Bayesian
Model Averaging Approach”, Economic Journal, Vol. 121.
Newhouse, C. (2015), “Germany, Safe Haven for Asylum Seekers”, BNP Paribas Flash Research, No. 15-33.
Obstfeld, M. (2015), “Trilemmas and Trade-offs: Living with Financial Globalisation”, BIS Working Papers,
No. 480, Bank for International Settlements, January.
OECD (2012), Jobs for Immigrants (Vol. 3): Labour Market Integration in Austria, Norway and
Switzerland, OECD Publishing, Paris.
OECD (2013a) OECD Economic Outlook, Vol. 2013/1, OECD Publishing, Paris.
OECD (2013b), International Migration Outlook 2013, OECD Publishing, Paris.
OECD (2014a), “OECD Forecasts During and After the Financial Crisis: A Post Mortem”, OECD Economics
Department Policy Note, No. 23, OECD Publishing, Paris.
OECD (2014b), “Labour Market Integration of Immigrants and Their Children: Developing, Activating
and Using Skills”, Chapter 2 in International Migration Outlook 2014, OECD Publishing, Paris.
OECD (2015a), OECD Economic Outlook, Vol. 2015/1, OECD Publishing, Paris.
OECD (2015b), “Lifting Investment for Higher Sustainable Growth”, Chapter 3 in OECD Economic Outlook,
Vol. 2015/1, OECD Publishing, Paris.
OECD (2015c), OECD Economic Surveys: China, March 2015, OECD Publishing, Paris.
OECD (2015d), “Is this humanitarian crisis different?”, Migration Policy Debates, September 2015, No. 7.
OECD (2015e), International Migration Outlook 2015, OECD Publishing, Paris.
OECD (2015f), The Future of Productivity, OECD Publishing, Paris.
OECD/European Union (2015), Indicators of Immigrant Integration 2015: Settling In, OECD Publishing, Paris.
OECD/WTO/UNCTAD (2015), Reports on G-20 Trade and Investment Measures (Mid-Nov 2014 to MidMay 2015), 13th report to the G-20.
Ollivaud, P., E. Rusticelli and C. Schwellnus (2015), “The Changing Role of the Exchange Rate for
Macroeconomic Adjustment”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1190, OECD
Publishing, Paris.
Ollivaud, P. and C. Schwellnus (2015), “Does the Post-Crisis Weakness of Global Trade Solely Reflect
Weak Demand?” in Hoekman, B. (ed.), The Global Trade Slowdown: A New Normal?, Centre for
Economic Policy Research.
Orphanides, A. (2003), “Historical Monetary Policy Analysis and the Taylor Rule”, Journal of Monetary
Economics, Vol. 50.
Oulton, N (2007), “Investment, Specific Technological Change and Growth Accounting”, Journal of
Monetary Economics, Vol. 54, Issue 4, pp. 1290-1299.
Pain, N. and O. Röhn (2011), “Policy Frameworks in the Post-Crisis Environment”, OECD Economics
Department Working Papers, No. 857, OECD Publishing, Paris.
Petri, P. and M. Plummer (2012), “The Trans-Pacific Partnership and Asia-Pacific Integration: Policy
Implications”, Peterson Institute for International Economics Policy Brief, PB12-16.
48
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Price R., T-T. Dang and J. Botev (forthcoming), “Adjusting Fiscal Balances for the Business Cycle: New
Tax and Expenditure Elasticity Estimates for OECD Countries”, OECD Economics Department Working
Paper, OECD Publishing, Paris.
Raciborski, R., A. Theofilakou and L. Vogel (2015), “Revisiting the Macroeconomic Effects of Oil Price
Changes”. Quarterly Report on the Euro Area, Vol. 14, No. 2, European Commission.
Rawdanowicz, Ł., R. Bouis and S. Watanabe (2013), “The Benefits and Costs of Highly Expansionary
Monetary Policy”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1082, OECD Publishing, Paris.
Turner D., M.C. Cavalleri, Y. Guillemette, A. Kopoin, P. Ollivaud and E. Rusticelli (forthcoming), “RealTime Reliability of OECD Output Gap Estimates and Some Investigations into Improving It”, OECD
Economics Department Working Papers.
World Bank (2015), Commodity Markets Outlook, July 2015.
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
49
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
ANNEX 1.1
Policy and other Assumptions Underlying the Projections
Fiscal policy settings for 2015, 2016 and 2017 are based as closely as possible on
legislated tax and spending provisions. Fiscal account projections are consistent with
growth, inflation and wage projections. Where government plans have been announced
but not legislated, they are incorporated if it is deemed clear that they will be implemented
in a shape close to that announced. Where there is insufficient information to determine
the allocation of budget cuts, the presumption is that they apply equally to the spending
and revenue sides, and are spread proportionally across components.
●
In the United States, the general government underlying primary balance is assumed to
decline over the projection period to reach 0.6% of GDP in 2017, roughly as implied by
current legislation, including the Bipartisan Budget Act and the Budget Control Act.
●
In Japan, the projections incorporate a 2 percentage point increase in the consumption
tax rate from 8% to 10% in the second quarter of 2017. Overall, the underlying primary
balance is assumed to improve over the projection period to reach 4.8% of GDP in 2017.
●
In euro area countries, fiscal stances over the projection period are based on draft budget
laws or, if these are not available, the stated targets in Stability Programmes.
●
In China, unspent reserves are being re-allocated and spending accelerated and new
sources of revenue are being tapped. Based on measures that have been announced,
fiscal stimulus is assumed to amount to around 1½ per cent of GDP in 2015, ½ per cent
of GDP in 2016 and ¼ per cent of GDP in 2017.
●
In India, the projections incorporate an increase in public investment, public pensions
and pay, as well in various recently launched social infrastructure programmes. They
also reflect on-going efforts to reduce tax evasion.
●
In Brazil, fiscal stance assumptions follow current policy announcements by the
government, implying a primary budget surplus of 0.15% of GDP in 2015, 0.7% in 2016 and
1.3% in 2017.
Regarding monetary policy, the assumed path of policy interest rates represents the
most likely outcome, conditional upon the OECD projections of activity and inflation,
which may differ from those of the monetary authorities.
50
●
In the United States, the upper bound of the target federal funds rate is assumed to be
raised gradually between December 2015 and December 2017 from the current level of
0.25% to 2%.
●
In Japan, the overnight interest rate is assumed to be kept at 0.1% for the entire
projection period.
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
●
In the euro area, the main refinancing rate is assumed to be kept at 0.05% until the
second quarter of 2017, and is subsequently raised to 0.25% by the end of 2017.
●
In the United Kingdom, the Bank rate is assumed to be increased gradually between
February 2016 and December 2017, from the current level of 0.5% to 2.25%.
●
In China, it is assumed that monetary easing will continue to reduce financing costs to
provide adequate liquidity and offset capital outflows. The base lending rate for loans up
to one year will be cut from 4.35% to 3.6% in 2017 and the reserve requirement ratio from
17.5% to 15%. Liquidity provision will also take place through short-term facilities such
as the Pledged Supplementary Lending or the Medium-Term Lending facilities.
●
In India, the repo rate is assumed to be kept at 6.75% up to the end of 2016 and be
subsequently cut to 6.25%.
●
In Brazil, the policy rate is assumed to stay at its current level of 14.25% until the fourth
quarter of 2016, and subsequently decline to 12% by the end of 2017.
Although their impact is difficult to assess, the following quantitative easing
measures are assumed to be taken over the projection period, implicitly affecting the speed
of convergence of long-term interest rates to their reference rates. In the United States and
the United Kingdom, the stocks are assumed to be maintained unchanged until the end of
projection. In Japan, asset purchases are assumed to continue through the projection;
thereby, the long-term interest rate is assumed to remain constant until the end of 2017. In
the euro area, current programmes of Targeted Longer-Term Refinancing Operations and
purchases of private securities and sovereign bonds are assumed to last until the end of
2016. Consequently, long-term interest rates are assumed to remain constant until the end
of 2016 and then gradually to converge to their reference values.
In the United States and the United Kingdom, 10-year government bond yields are
assumed to converge slowly toward a reference rate (reached only well after the end of the
projection), determined by future projected short-term interest rates (including after 2017),
a term premium and an additional fiscal premium. The latter premium is assumed to be 2
basis points per each percentage point of the gross government debt-to-GDP ratio in excess
of 75% and an additional two basis points (four basis points in total) per percentage point
of the debt ratio in excess of 125%.
Structural reforms that have been implemented or announced for the projection period
are taken into account, but no further reforms are assumed to take place.
The projections assume unchanged exchange rates from those prevailing on 22
October 2015: one US dollar equals JPY 119.69, EUR 0.90 (or equivalently one euro equals
USD 1.11) and 6.36 renminbi.
The price of a barrel of Brent crude oil is assumed to remain constant at USD 50
throughout the projection period. Non-oil commodity prices are assumed to be constant
over the projection period at their average levels of September 2015.
The cut-off date for information used in the projections is 30 October 2015.
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
51
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
ANNEX 1.2
Indicators of Potential Financial Vulnerabilities
The following tables show the position of OECD and selected non-OECD countries on
a number of indicators that could reveal potential exposure to financial turbulence. The
main focus of Table 1.A2.1 is on domestic vulnerabilities of the OECD and BRIICS countries,
that of Table 1.A2.2 on financial account vulnerabilities of the OECD and non-OECD G-20
countries. The presented variables are a subset of over 70 vulnerability indicators
identified as useful in monitoring risks of a costly crisis in OECD economies (Röhn et
al., 2015).
Table 1.A2.1 presents indicators typically associated with financial vulnerabilities
arising primarily from the domestic economy, in four broad categories: the real economy,
the non-financial sector, the financial sector and public finances (International Monetary
Fund, 2012; European Commission, 2012; Hermansen and Röhn, 2015). Possible weaknesses
in the real economy are captured by the difference between the potential and the actual
GDP growth rate, the difference between the actual unemployment rate and the natural
rate of unemployment (or NAIRU), the current account deficit and the evolution of relative
unit labour costs. Indicators of financial market excesses related to the non-financial
sector are the debt of households and non-financial corporations and real house price
growth. An aggregated ratio of core Tier-1 capital to total assets (i.e. the leverage ratio) for
selected banks in each country,15 non-performing loans, and financial corporations’ debt
are included to account for the direct risk exposure of the financial sector. Vulnerabilities
stemming from the public sector are quantified along three dimensions: government net
borrowing, gross government debt and the difference between 10-year real sovereign bond
yields and the potential real GDP growth rate. Higher values, with the exception of the
leverage ratio, indicate a larger vulnerability. Table 1.A2.1 also includes the current
sovereign credit ratings issued by Standards and Poor’s.
Table 1.A2.2 displays financial-accounts-related risk factors for financial stability in
the OECD and non-OECD G-20 countries based on previous OECD empirical analysis
(Ahrend and Goujard, 2012a, 2012b). The analysis shows that:
●
Greater (short-term) borrowing from external banks, or a skew in external liabilities
towards debt, increases the risk of a financial crisis substantially (external bank debt
being defined as debt to a foreign bank).
15. The calculations of the country leverage ratios are based on over 1200 commercial banks, including
915 in the United States, 197 in the OECD euro area countries, 23 in the United Kingdom, 11 in
Canada and 7 in Japan.
52
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
●
A larger share of foreign direct investment (FDI) in gross external liabilities decreases the
chances of a financial crisis.
●
Shorter maturity of banks’ debt raises the crisis risk, mainly by increasing exposure to
financial contagion.
●
The size of foreign reserve holdings reduces the probability of a crisis.
●
Total external assets (excluding reserves) or liabilities are found not to affect the crisis
risk for countries with small and moderate levels of assets and liabilities. However,
external assets reduce, and external liabilities increase, the crisis risk when they are
large.
Table 1.A2.2 shows for each of the 8 selected indicators: i) the position of each country
in 2015Q1 (or the latest available) along various dimensions of its financial account
structure, and ii) the country-specific change, from 2007 to 2015Q1 (or the latest available).
For some of the variables, the numbers need to be interpreted with care, since the
relevance of the variable may differ across countries. For example, the foreign currency
reserves of the United States are the lowest relative to GDP in the OECD area, but this does
not signify a weakness as the US dollar is a reserve currency; the same applies to low
currency reserves in individual euro area countries.
Bibliography
Ahrend, R., and A. Goujard (2012a), “International Capital Mobility and Financial Fragility – Part 1:
Drivers of Systemic Banking Crises: The Role of Bank-Balance-Sheet Contagion and Financial
Account Structure”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 902, OECD Publishing, Paris.
Ahrend, R., and A. Goujard (2012b), “International Capital Mobility and Financial Fragility – Part 3: How
Do Structural Policies Affect Financial Crisis Risk? Evidence from Past Crises across OECD and
Emerging Economies”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 966, OECD Publishing, Paris.
European Commission (2012), Alert Mechanism Report 2013, Brussels.
Hermansen, M. and O. Röhn (2015), “Economic Resilience: The Usefulness of Early Warning Indicators
in OECD Countries”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1250, OECD Publishing, Paris.
DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jrxhgfqx3mv-en
International Monetary Fund (2012), Global Financial Stability Report October 2012, Washington, DC.
Röhn, O., et al. (2015), “Economic Resilience: A New Set of Vulnerability Indicators for OECD Countries”,
OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1249, OECD Publishing, Paris. DOI: http://dx.doi.org/
10.1787/5jrxhgjw54r8-en
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
53
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Table 1.A2.1. Indicators of potential financial vulnerabilities
Real economy
Non-financial sector
Potential GDP
growth rateactual GDP
growth rate
differential
Actual
unemployment
rate-NAIRU
differential
% change
2014
2014
% change
2015
2015Q3
2015
2000Q1-15Q2
or latest
available
or latest
available
2000Q1-15Q2
Current
account
1
deficit
Relative unit
labour cost
Household
gross
debt2,3
Non-financial
corporation
1,3
gross debt
Real house
prices
United States
Japan
Germany
France
Italy
United Kingdom
Canada
Australia
Austria
Belgium
Chile
Czech Republic
Denmark
Estonia
Finland
Greece
Hungary
Iceland
Ireland
Israel
Korea
Luxembourg
Mexico
Netherlands
New Zealand
Norway7
Poland
Portugal
Slovak Republic
Slovenia
Spain
Sweden
Switzerland
Turkey
-0.8
-0.2
-0.3
0.0
-0.8
-0.5
0.3
0.4
0.1
0.0
0.9
-2.5
-1.0
0.3
0.7
0.9
-1.2
-2.3
-3.5
0.7
0.6
-0.5
0.5
-1.1
0.2
-0.3
-0.5
-0.4
0.8
3.2
-0.3
0.4
0.4
1.6
0.7
-0.3
-0.8
0.0
-1.8
2.2
7.7
-1.5
-0.5
-1.5
-0.7
0.3
0.4
0.2
1.0
0.3
2.5
-3.3
-8.3
-0.2
-1.5
4.0
3.3
4.7
-2.3
-0.1
-0.2
-0.7
-7.0
-3.3
1.0
0.3
-4.3
-3.5
-3.6
-3.5
-7.3
-3.6
2.0
-11.0
4.3
-12.8
-51.4
-14.1
0.4
9.4
-11.4
29.0
36.9
-2.6
2.5
24.3
30.3
9.7
35.2
-2.7
5.1
22.0
-22.0
-8.5
-10.6
10.2
26.0
-8.8
-4.0
61.0
109.7
132.6
93.6
104.9
77.2
155.7
170.1
211.2
89.1
110.0
..
68.8
315.2
81.1
126.6
117.4
53.3
..
197.4
..
164.2
157.8
..
270.0
..
113.2
160.9
71.2
101.5
89.8
113.6
140.6
87.3
91.1
137.0
..
63.0
126.9
97.0
94.0
73.6
80.2
271.0
236.9
69.3
166.5
315.0
63.3
128.8
..
20.8
-20.2
6.3
70.6
9.7
79.3
97.1
103.6
25.8
..
..
..
38.8
..
25.6
-12.0
..
..
10.6
41.9
29.3
..
..
0.3
108.9
1.1
-0.4
-1.4
-0.4
-1.4
-2.7
-1.2
0.8
1.2
1.0
0.1
0.4
0.4
1.6
3.0
0.5
0.3
1.1
-7.1
0.2
-0.6
0.4
-7.5
-1.5
-6.0
-9.8
5.3
42.3
-7.1
-3.8
26.1
-6.4
2.8
-6.8
37.9
-36.3
223.8
60.5
138.5
62.3
57.6
128.0
173.1
197.4
..
108.2
58.6
145.6
76.9
92.3
104.5
131.4
..
2.6
90.6
..
-26.2
..
..
25.6
133.3
51.4
..
Brazil
China
Colombia
Costa Rica
India
Indonesia
Latvia
Lithuania
Russia
South Africa
4.2
0.4
1.2
1.2
-0.3
0.8
-0.2
1.0
4.7
0.8
..
..
-0.9
..
..
..
-0.3
-1.9
..
..
3.4
-3.0
6.1
4.0
0.7
1.6
2.0
3.4
-6.6
4.2
11.0
101.2
12.1
..
-42.2
-12.9
9.2
8.7
209.9
-0.6
..
..
..
..
..
..
60.1
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
93.9
..
..
..
..
..
80.1
..
..
..
..
..
..
113.0
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
In per cent of GDP.
In per cent of gross household disposable income.
Gross debt is defined as liabilities less financial derivatives and shares and other equity. Based on consolidated data for most countries.
In per cent of total (unweighted) assets.
OECD Economic Outlook 98 database.
Rating for sovereign debt in foreign currency.
7. Mainland (potential) GDP is used instead of total (potential) GDP where applicable.
Source: OECD National Accounts database; IMF Financial Soundness Indicators database; European Central Bank; European Commission; OECD Analytical
Housing Prices database; Standards & Poors; OECD calculations; and OECD Economic Outlook 98 database.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933296695
54
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Table 1.A2.1. Indicators of potential financial vulnerabilities (cont.)
Financial sector
Public finance
Nonperforming
loans to
total loans
Financial
corporation
gross
Latest
available
2014
or latest
available
6.4
4.4
4.1
3.6
5.6
4.4
3.8
..
1.6
2.3
4.5
17.3
1.8
0.5
3.8
6.2
4.9
..
..
4.4
..
3.7
7.6
..
..
6.7
..
..
..
..
4.2
..
6.4
..
6.1
..
..
5.7
3.6
4.4
..
1.1
3.6
4.0
1.9
5.6
4.4
1.3
..
34.4
12.7
..
18.9
2.1
..
0.2
2.9
2.9
..
1.1
4.7
12.3
5.3
11.5
7.0
1.2
0.7
2.8
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
3.1
1.2
3.1
1.7
4.6
2.3
4.6
6.7
7.4
3.2
Core Tier-1
leverage
ratio4
Latest
available
1,3
debt
Headline
government
budget
1,5
deficit
Gross
government
1,5
debt
Real 10-year
sovereign bond
yield-potential
GDP growth rate
differential
Sovereign
credit rating
S&P
6
2015
2015Q2
or latest
available
Latest
2015
347.3
582.8
296.6
304.0
207.2
675.9
340.0
4.5
6.7
-0.9
3.8
2.6
3.9
1.9
110.6
229.2
78.5
120.1
160.7
116.4
94.8
-1.0
-1.2
-2.7
-1.0
1.0
-1.8
-1.0
AA+
A+
AAA
AA
BBBAAA
AAA
United States
Japan
Germany
France
Italy
United Kingdom
Canada
278.7
227.3
339.5
..
130.5
412.0
123.4
230.2
193.5
123.6
969.2
910.2
206.8
349.9
6233.6
71.6
743.6
..
215.9
98.5
278.3
120.4
127.3
224.6
322.5
..
2.6
1.9
1.8
2.6
..
1.9
2.7
-0.2
3.3
4.3
2.3
-0.3
2.1
3.3
..
-0.9
0.3
2.0
-1.4
-6.9
2.8
3.0
2.7
2.9
4.2
1.1
0.2
..
44.2
107.3
130.5
..
56.1
57.1
12.7
73.3
190.0
99.6
81.6
120.0
66.1
..
35.6
..
80.8
41.1
34.1
66.9
148.9
59.6
99.8
118.9
53.9
46.4
..
-0.1
-1.8
-1.2
-2.7
-3.1
-1.2
..
-1.4
14.2
-0.6
1.1
-1.8
-3.1
-2.1
-4.3
-0.2
-1.3
-1.1
-1.6
-0.6
0.4
-1.8
-0.2
1.1
-2.5
-0.9
-0.7
AAA
AA+
AA
AAAAAAA
..
AA+
..
..
..
A+
A+
AAAAA
BBB+
AA+
AA
AAA
..
BB+
A+
ABBB+
AAA
..
..
Australia
Austria
Belgium
Chile
Czech Republic
Denmark
Estonia
Finland
Greece
Hungary
Iceland
Ireland
Israel
Korea
Luxembourg
Mexico
Netherlands
New Zealand
Norway7
Poland
Portugal
Slovak Republic
Slovenia
Spain
Sweden
Switzerland
Turkey
7.4
1.0
..
..
6.1
2.0
1.6
1.5
4.0
4.3
..
..
..
..
..
..
44.9
53.7
..
..
9.7
-3.3
1.4
..
0.7
1.2
-2.5
..
8.7
4.8
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
..
Brazil
China
Colombia
Costa Rica
India
Indonesia
Latvia
Lithuania
Russia
South Africa
1. In per cent of GDP.
2. In per cent of gross household disposable income.
3. Gross debt is defined as liabilities less financial derivatives and shares and other equity. Based on consolidated data for most countries.
4. In per cent of total (unweighted) assets.
5. OECD Economic Outlook 98 database.
6. Rating for sovereign debt in foreign currency.
7. Mainland (potential) GDP is used instead of total (potential) GDP where applicable.
Source: OECD National Accounts database; IMF Financial Soundness Indicators database; European Central Bank; European Commission; OECD Analytical
Housing Prices database; Standards & Poors; OECD calculations; and OECD Economic Outlook 98 database.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933296695
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
55
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Table 1.A2.2. Financial-accounts-related risk factors to financial stability
Latest available (in per cent)
External
1
debt
External
bank
2
debt
Short-term
external
bank
2
debt
Short-term
external
bank
External
2
liabilities
3
debt
External
2
Foreign
exchange
2
assets
reserves
FDI
1
liabilities
Higher values indicate
lower financial stability risk
Higher values indicate higher financial stability risk
United States
Japan
Germany
France
Italy
United Kingdom
Canada
48.9
55.8
58.6
59.3
69.3
50.4
51.0
15.2
20.9
33.9
58.5
26.8
65.4
26.4
5.8
17.3
16.5
32.0
10.4
42.8
15.0
38.4
82.9
48.8
54.6
38.8
65.4
56.6
182.0
119.8
224.6
334.0
168.2
574.6
169.8
143.4
189.0
265.6
312.8
139.7
556.4
180.7
0.7
29.0
2.0
2.2
2.7
3.8
4.9
19.9
3.9
17.1
12.1
14.8
12.2
32.5
Australia
Austria
Belgium
Chile
Czech Republic
Denmark
Estonia
Finland
Greece
Hungary
Iceland
Ireland
Israel
Korea
Luxembourg
Mexico
Netherlands
New Zealand
Norway
Poland
Portugal
Slovak Republic
Slovenia
Spain
Sweden
Switzerland
Turkey
Argentina
Brazil
China
Colombia
Costa Rica
India
Indonesia
Latvia
Lithuania
Russia
Saudi Arabia
South Africa
51.2
63.3
45.3
28.6
37.5
59.9
42.7
53.9
92.9
26.7
82.9
29.4
29.8
39.6
21.5
50.0
35.9
56.1
63.4
47.7
70.2
51.5
76.3
60.0
51.8
34.7
67.2
53.2
34.5
29.6
41.2
36.8
53.3
40.1
69.1
63.9
48.6
17.0
28.0
23.0
44.8
48.3
17.6
19.1
64.7
9.4
51.9
17.2
28.2
37.6
140.4
6.1
13.2
891.8
11.8
107.9
18.0
28.6
22.9
32.2
33.6
22.9
33.6
53.8
67.2
21.6
2.6
12.5
8.9
8.1
19.8
10.5
12.5
9.6
10.3
8.4
9.0
10.0
7.6
12.2
21.7
7.7
4.9
39.9
4.0
19.6
4.7
9.8
10.6
57.7
3.2
8.1
336.5
4.7
41.9
6.8
10.3
6.8
9.3
13.7
6.4
13.8
27.5
46.8
12.5
1.6
6.4
6.7
3.4
5.9
5.7
6.2
4.5
3.0
3.3
5.3
4.2
33.0
27.3
44.9
43.8
25.8
61.7
42.8
37.8
27.3
34.6
28.3
41.1
52.6
61.8
37.7
40.2
38.8
37.9
36.0
29.7
28.9
40.7
27.9
41.2
51.0
69.5
57.8
62.3
50.7
75.7
41.6
29.8
54.8
49.5
46.9
28.8
38.6
58.9
41.7
182.3
265.6
430.2
145.0
123.6
262.9
170.5
372.9
247.7
314.2
619.9
2089.8
96.6
73.1
16408.6
81.6
1017.3
148.4
171.7
111.2
289.9
134.7
143.0
239.9
305.6
533.9
82.0
36.4
71.2
46.9
85.3
84.9
42.8
71.5
182.4
106.5
50.4
36.9
121.8
127.6
269.2
489.9
129.8
95.0
309.8
132.5
371.7
127.4
244.3
257.2
2002.7
119.0
78.9
16439.1
46.9
1090.7
83.7
315.5
46.9
180.3
67.8
103.1
147.3
300.5
636.7
30.3
50.0
38.7
60.2
47.3
40.9
25.1
24.1
124.1
60.2
66.9
142.6
114.2
4.2
3.6
3.6
15.5
28.8
35.7
1.9
3.7
1.2
32.9
26.6
0.7
29.5
25.6
1.2
16.4
2.4
8.5
12.9
19.7
3.6
3.1
2.0
3.7
11.3
80.6
13.5
5.4
17.9
35.3
14.6
16.2
15.7
12.3
11.1
2.2
18.2
97.4
12.7
24.9
29.9
48.1
62.9
57.6
16.4
54.7
14.6
4.6
69.9
16.3
17.3
35.3
17.9
38.9
34.4
50.6
30.9
26.7
43.2
23.1
47.7
21.5
22.3
25.2
31.0
24.4
41.5
47.2
55.3
53.4
63.2
29.9
43.8
29.6
35.1
37.4
77.7
32.6
1. As per cent of external liabilities.
2. As per cent of GDP.
3. As per cent of external bank debt.
Source : BIS; IMF; World Bank; and OECD calculations.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933296702
56
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
1.
GENERAL ASSESSMENT OF THE MACROECONOMIC SITUATION
Table 1.A2.2. Financial-accounts-related risk factors to financial stability (cont.)
External
1
debt
External
bank
2
debt
Short-term
external
bank
2
debt
Short-term
external
bank
External
2
liabilities
3
debt
External
2
assets
Foreign
exchange
2
reserves
FDI
1
liabilities
Positive values indicate a
decrease in the financial stability risk
Positive values indicate an increase in the financial stability risk
-6.3
0.9
-10.5
-0.6
-2.3
-12.5
16.3
-5.2
7.8
-16.2
-8.8
-24.5
-50.5
3.0
-2.9
8.2
-11.3
-11.6
-8.0
-43.8
0.2
-4.5
13.2
-6.7
-10.1
3.0
-9.3
-6.3
27.5
46.2
10.0
31.6
9.2
4.1
0.1
-2.0
64.4
29.7
20.0
7.7
-1.5
24.2
0.2
6.8
0.4
0.2
1.2
2.0
1.7
1.1
-0.4
-0.8
-1.0
-0.1
2.6
-14.0
United States
Japan
Germany
France
Italy
United Kingdom
Canada
2.4
-0.2
-16.6
-3.9
3.9
-7.9
-6.5
14.6
17.5
-4.8
3.7
-24.1
-15.0
-3.2
-8.2
16.4
-4.6
-2.3
-0.5
2.1
0.2
10.4
4.6
-4.0
2.1
-15.7
12.5
-1.0
10.4
-2.7
-3.2
-10.1
3.7
-13.1
-5.6
1.3
13.0
-19.5
8.2
-8.9
-27.3
-66.7
-0.6
-3.5
-6.5
-96.1
11.9
-41.8
-36.0
-254.7
-129.4
-2.4
-3.7
-249.3
3.9
-27.4
-7.5
-32.8
-1.6
-42.8
1.8
-25.4
-25.9
-0.3
-105.4
2.6
-4.2
4.8
2.9
0.9
-5.4
-0.9
1.8
-70.9
-33.2
-5.6
0.0
-1.5
-4.6
-14.5
-67.1
-1.9
-3.9
3.1
-20.2
7.0
-12.2
-8.2
-115.9
-93.2
-0.7
-2.3
-164.3
2.3
-25.4
-6.1
-30.2
0.7
-18.5
1.4
-6.7
-5.1
-4.9
-78.6
4.1
-1.8
2.7
3.4
-0.9
-5.5
-0.2
0.5
-28.9
-9.0
-3.4
-0.3
-1.0
-5.1
-9.8
-32.3
-8.8
-13.3
9.9
19.9
6.2
-1.4
6.7
-15.0
-14.8
6.5
0.1
-6.2
9.9
-10.9
-12.9
-29.8
4.8
-8.2
2.1
0.9
9.4
-8.8
-3.1
13.6
12.1
3.6
20.5
-17.8
-15.5
2.8
-3.6
5.5
1.2
-9.1
-3.4
-3.4
8.3
-58.2
-87.1
43.5
12.5
10.8
-39.2
90.1
47.7
0.0
-113.8
661.5
-21.4
0.5
3090.0
13.5
44.6
-31.9
-53.2
5.3
-14.9
15.1
0.1
4.1
23.6
-56.9
-1.2
-21.0
-0.5
8.4
29.0
17.1
2.2
10.2
3.3
-17.0
-59.2
6.3
8.1
18.3
-43.4
-59.3
27.9
28.5
64.1
7.1
120.1
33.4
30.5
-356.6
595.2
1.7
23.6
3141.8
15.8
135.4
-11.1
28.3
3.2
-23.4
8.5
-14.6
-0.9
20.2
-97.4
1.0
-18.8
6.9
-15.6
16.8
-9.3
-8.1
0.7
29.7
2.2
-29.5
11.5
34.0
1.4
0.5
1.1
5.1
9.1
24.9
-14.2
0.7
0.9
14.5
12.9
0.4
12.5
1.2
0.9
7.7
1.0
-5.5
-3.8
3.4
2.7
-23.1
-0.2
2.9
5.4
70.4
0.9
-9.6
3.5
-12.7
3.5
-0.6
-10.7
-0.1
-9.3
-19.0
-23.1
16.5
2.1
-0.7
3.3
14.1
2.3
0.1
-4.9
9.9
-4.3
-4.3
5.9
1.3
2.8
10.1
2.3
14.6
-9.4
2.6
-1.5
6.9
-2.6
4.1
-9.7
-3.6
2.0
-6.7
10.4
-7.7
2.3
12.5
-2.0
-0.5
10.1
4.2
12.1
5.4
-0.5
-2.1
14.2
-8.8
Australia
Austria
Belgium
Chile
Czech Republic
Denmark
Estonia
Finland
Greece
Hungary
Iceland
Ireland
Israel
Korea
Luxembourg
Mexico
Netherlands
New Zealand
Norway
Poland
Portugal
Slovak Republic
Slovenia
Spain
Sweden
Switzerland
Turkey
Argentina
Brazil
China
Colombia
Costa Rica
India
Indonesia
Latvia
Lithuania
Russia
Saudi Arabia
South Africa
1. As per cent of external liabilities.
2. As per cent of GDP.
3. As per cent of external bank debt.
Source : BIS; IMF; World Bank; and OECD calculations.
1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933296702
OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK, VOLUME 2015 ISSUE 2 © OECD 2015 – PRELIMINARY VERSION
57